Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
R. Gallotti, A. Bazzani, S. Rambaldi, M. Barthelemy (2015)
A stochastic model of randomly accelerated walkers for human mobilityNature Communications, 7
J. Peach, T. Warnecke, J. Watkins (2017)
The Great Divide: Unequal Societies and What We Can Do About ThemThe Social Science Journal, 54
Elena Martinez, Maria Rubio, R. Maestre-Martínez, Juan Arias, Dario Patane, Amanda Zerbe, R. Kirkpatrick, M. Luengo-Oroz (2016)
Measuring Economic Resilience to Natural Disasters with Big Economic Transaction DataArXiv, abs/1609.09340
Lijun Sun, K. Axhausen, Der-Horng Lee, Xianfeng Huang (2013)
Understanding metropolitan patterns of daily encountersProceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 110
(2016)
National Institute for Statistics) Available: http://www.ine.es
A. McDaniel, W. Goldsmith, E. Blakely (1992)
Separate Societies: Poverty and Inequality in U.S. Cities.Contemporary Sociology, 22
(1972)
Across 110th street
J. Vallée, E. Cadot, F. Grillo, I. Parizot, P. Chauvin (2010)
The combined effects of activity space and neighbourhood of residence on participation in preventive health-care activities: The case of cervical screening in the Paris metropolitan area (France).Health & place, 16 5
K. Miciukiewicz, G. Vigar (2012)
Mobility and Social Cohesion in the Splintered City: Challenging Technocentric Transport Research and Policy-making PracticesUrban Studies, 49
Marta González, César Hidalgo, A. Barabási (2008)
Understanding individual human mobility patternsNature, 453
Y. Montjoye, Laura Radaelli, V. Singh, A. Pentland (2015)
Unique in the shopping mall: On the reidentifiability of credit card metadataScience, 347
D. Satterthwaite, D. Mitlin (2013)
Reducing Urban Poverty in the Global South
Raj Chetty, Nathaniel Hendren (2015)
The Impacts of Neighborhoods on Intergenerational Mobility: Childhood Exposure Effects and County-Level Estimates
J. Friedrichs, G. Galster, S. Musterd (2003)
Neighbourhood effects on social opportunities: the European and American research and policy contextHousing Studies, 18
J. Brooks-Gunn, G. Duncan, J. Aber (1997)
Neighborhood poverty I: Context and consequences for children
J. Pinol, X. Lafon, M. Sartre, J. Marc (2011)
Histoire de l'Europe urbaine
Raj Chetty, Nathaniel Hendren (2016)
The Impacts of Neighborhoods on Intergenerational Mobility I: Childhood Exposure EffectsNBER Working Paper Series
H. Doughty (2014)
Capital in the Twenty-First CenturyThe Innovation Journal, 19
N. Eagle, Michael Macy, R. Claxton (2010)
Network Diversity and Economic DevelopmentScience, 328
J. Brooks-Gunn, G. Duncan, J. Aber (2000)
Neighborhood Poverty, Volume 1: Context and Consequences for Children
J. Onnela, J. Saramäki, J. Hyvönen, G. Szabó, D. Lazer, K. Kaski, János Kertész, A. Barabási (2006)
Structure and tie strengths in mobile communication networksProceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 104
J. Blau, P. Blau (1982)
The Cost of Inequality: Metropolitan Structure and Violent CrimeAmerican Sociological Review, 47
JE Stiglitz (2015)
The Great Divide: Unequal Societies and What We Can Do About Them, 1 edition
Kevin Lewis (2015)
Three fallacies of digital footprintsBig Data & Society, 2
Yuji Yoshimura, Stanislav Sobolevsky, Juan Hobin, C. Ratti, J. Blat (2016)
Urban association rules: Uncovering linked trips for shopping behaviorEnvironment and Planning B: Urban Analytics and City Science, 45
Ian Cole (2011)
Separate Societies: Poverty and Inequality in US Cities (2nd edition)Housing Studies, 26
G. Robinson, A. Read (2005)
Recycling behaviour in a London Borough: Results from large-scale household surveysResources Conservation and Recycling, 45
The American Association of State Highways and Transportation Officials (AASHTO) Commuting in America 2013, the national report on commuting patterns and trends
John Berg (2017)
Sharing Cities: A Case for Truly Smart and Sustainable CitiesNew Political Science, 39
Xin Lu, Linus Bengtsson, Petter Holme (2012)
Predictability of population displacement after the 2010 Haiti earthquakeProceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 109
A. Venables, R. Kanbur (2005)
Spatial Inequality and Development
Jean-François Ruault (2014)
L’effet de la consommation de passage sur le développement et l’intégration métropolitaine des territoires en Ile-de-France
Maxime Lenormand, Thomas Louail, Oliva Cantu-Ros, M. Picornell, R. Herranz, Juan Arias, M. Barthelemy, M. Miguel, J. Ramasco (2014)
Influence of sociodemographics on human mobilityScientific Reports, 5
(2009)
Computational Social ScienceScience, 323
C. Schneider, V. Belik, T. Couronné, Z. Smoreda, Marta González (2013)
Unravelling daily human mobility motifsJournal of The Royal Society Interface, 10
Jennifer Dill, Theresa Carr (2003)
Bicycle Commuting and Facilities in Major U.S. Cities: If You Build Them, Commuters Will Use ThemTransportation Research Record, 1828
T. Cassiers, C. Kesteloot (2012)
Socio-spatial Inequalities and Social Cohesion in European CitiesUrban Studies, 49
W. Ostendorf, S. Musterd, Sjoerd Vos (2001)
Social Mix and the Neighbourhood Effect. Policy Ambitions and Empirical EvidenceHousing Studies, 16
L. Sehgal, J. Leusen (2004)
Γ and B
D McLaren, J Agyeman (2015)
Sharing cities: a case for truly smart and sustainable cities. Urban and Industrial Environments
José Vergara (2018)
Sharing cities. A Case for Truly Smart and Sustainable CitiesInternational and Multidisciplinary Journal of Social Sciences
(2014)
State of African Cities Re-imagining sustainable urban transitions. State of Cities -Regional Reports
W. Recker, L. Kostyniuk (1978)
Factors influencing destination choice for the urban grocery shopping tripTransportation, 7
[email protected]; [email protected] Socioeconomic inequalities in cities are embedded in space and result in Equal contributors neighborhood effects, whose harmful consequences have proved very hard to CNRS, UMR Géographie-cités, 13 rue du four, FR-75006 Paris, France counterbalance efficiently by planning policies alone. Considering redistribution of Irstea, UMR TETIS, 500 rue JF Breton, money flows as a first step toward improved spatial equity, we study a bottom-up FR-34093 Montpellier, France Full list of author information is approach that would rely on a slight evolution of shopping mobility practices. Building available at the end of the article on a database of anonymized card transactions in Madrid and Barcelona, we quantify the mobility effort required to reach a reference situation where commercial income is evenly shared among neighborhoods. The redirections of shopping trips preserve key properties of human mobility, including travel distances. Surprisingly, for both cities only a small fraction (∼ 5%) of trips need to be modified to reach equality situations, improving even other sustainability indicators. The method could be implemented in mobile applications that would assist individuals in reshaping their shopping practices, to promote the spatial redistribution of opportunities in the city. Keywords: Human mobility, Shopping mobility, Wealth inequality, Spatial networks, Graph rewiring Introduction The growth of economic inequality has raised concern and attention in recent years (Piketty 2014; Stiglitz 2015). In cities these inequalities are embedded in space, as a result of entangled processes which include location choices of households and businesses, daily mobility, segregation and closure attitudes, central planning, or global economic restruc- turing. Over the course of several decades their joint actions have given rise to segregated cities, characterized by uneven distributions of capital among their neighborhoods. While the intensity of socioeconomic inequalities vary from one city to another, the general observation that “some neighborhoods are poorer than others” has been made for cities with different age, in every continent, and for different periods in urban history (Pinol 2003; Goldsmith et al. 2010; Cassiers and Kesteloot 2012; UN-HABITAT 2014). An abun- dant literature has long depicted the neighborhood effect (Friedrichs et al. 2003) – the neighbourhood impacts the life trajectories of the residents, even when controlling for their individual characteristics –, and highlighted its societal costs and enduring conse- quences (Blau and Blau 1982; Brooks-Gunn et al. 1997; Vallée et al. 2010; Womack 1972; Chetty and Hendren 2015). Over the last decade, increasing volumes of digital geographic footprints have been produced by individuals using mobile ICT devices, and these footprints have © The Author(s). 2017 Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 2 of 13 been increasingly analyzed by scientists as well. These data are not free of biases (Lewis 2015) or privacy concerns (de Montjoye et al. 2015), but they undeniably constitute an important asset for understanding social phenomena in detailed spatio-temporal con- texts (Lazer et al. 2009; Eagle et al. 2010; Onnela et al. 2007; Lu et al. 2012; Sun et al. 2013; González et al. 2008). They also have the potential to reveal the information required to coordinate individuals’ actions, so that large groups of people can tackle issues which are distributed and spatial by nature. This is particularly true in the case of mobility networks, which already integrate such footprints in feedback mechanisms: people produce data when moving, and their travel decisions are partly guided by the data produced by others. Examples include GPS navigation using real-time traffic data, local search and discovery of new places, or location-based dating applications. So far, these footprints have been mainly used in applications intended to enhance individual satisfaction (time savings, dis- covery of a location, encounter of a partner), but they have also fostered spontaneous and large-scale solidarity movements during disasters (e.g. Facebook’s safety check, or the use of dedicated Twitter hashtags). An important question is thus whether we can scale up, and address complex issues through distributed and coordinated approaches rely- ing on such data. Here we refer to complex social issues for which improvements would necessarily occur on longer timescales. There is a need to relate smart technology with sustainability and spatial justice in cities (McLaren and Agyeman 2015), and this implies building upon the existing practices of individuals. In this work, we develop further this idea by focusing on a complex problem: the reduction of spatial inequality in large cities. The “Robin-Hood effect” refers to a process through which capital is redistributed to reduce inequality. A spatial and city-scale implementation would then consist in taking from the rich neighborhoods to give to the poor. This role is normally played by the city’s governance, and is essential to mitigate spatial inequality. However, studies in cities world- wide have demonstrated that top-down planning and fiscal policies alone seem inefficient in significantly counterbalancing the numerous consequences of the neighborhood effect (Ostendorf et al. 2001; Satterthwaite and Mitlin 2013). It has also been long emphasized that developing economic activity in disadvantaged regions indirectly benefits the sur- rounding populations, by fostering job opportunities, transport facilities and increased safety (Kanbur and Venables 2005). Here, we study an original approach to rebalance economic activity among a city’s neighborhoods. The scenarios we explore would not incur any additional environmental or monetary costs, but would instead require slight modifications of daily shopping mobility practices. According to surveys, shopping and leisure trips account for 15 to 20% of the individu- als’ daily travels (AASHTO 2013). Such trips virtually move money from one part of the city to another, and directly contribute to shape the spatial distribution of wealth across neighborhoods. By connecting areas, shopping trips also foster metropolitan integration and “social cohesion” (Miciukiewicz and Vigar 2012), whilst the resulting money flows are a key component of the development of territories (Ruault 2014). Large metropoli- tan areas are characterized by mixed land use in many of their neighborhoods. Every time a resident has to buy usual products such as food, gas or clothes, he/she can actu- ally indeed choose among several stores and neighborhoods to do so, sometimes without even increasing his/her travel time. In the following we focus on the two largest Spanish cities, Madrid and Barcelona. Performing exploratory experiments, we demonstrate that they could be more evenly (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 3 of 13 balanced thanks to the cumulative addition of small and reasonable changes in a lim- ited fraction of their residents’ shopping destinations. While there exists various spatial indicators for quantifying territorial inequalities, static indicators fail to provide a clear picture of the collective effort that would be required to reach a certain level of redistri- bution. With this in mind, we quantify the proportion of individual shopping trips that should be redirected in order to evenly share the commercial income between neighbour- hoods, the first step of a conceivable path toward a spatial redistribution of opportunities in the city. We show that alternative mobility scenarios not only allow to distribute money more evenly in space, but also to enhance the spatial mixing of residents through their shopping mobility, without increasing the total distance traveled, nor changing the individuals’ effective purchases and mobility routines. The following of this paper is an exploration on how money flows in cities could be more evenly distributed, if shopping spatial behavior was slightly restructured. In the following of this paper, we use zipcodes delimitations as proxies for neighbourhoods. While zipcodes correspond to administra- tive units which are very coarse-grained proxies for effective neighbourhoods, this choice was imposed by the spatial resolution of the available data. Material and Methods Data We use a dataset containing the metadata of one year of bank card payments from more than 150,000 anonymous users in over 95,000 businesses of Barcelona and Madrid. Each transaction is time-stamped and contains the information collected by the bank on both the cardholder and the business. It also includes the customer’s age and residence’s zip- code, the business category and its geographical coordinates (see Additional file 1 for details and (Martinez et al. 2016; Yoshimura et al. 2016) for other recent examples of research relying on similar data). From these data there are two obvious ways to esti- mate inequality among neighborhoods: first, in measuring the income of their residents – indirectly estimated through the amount of money spent during the year; second, in measuring the income resulting from the commercial activity of businesses located in these neighborhoods. The latter is particularly interesting because it results from the spa- tial organization of shopping trips, which may be much easier to alter than any other type of daily trips, notably commuting. The average commercial income of businesses in Barcelona’s neighbourhoods, resulting from shopping trips, is mapped on Fig. 1a. This map reveals that according to this measure, some neighborhoods are indeed five times richer than others. Rewiring the shopping trips networks From the data for both cities we construct the bipartite spatial network whose nodes are individuals and businesses, and whose edges stand for transactions (see Additional file 1: Figure S2). We then perform rewiring experiments, in which randomly selected trans- actions are redirected toward alternative businesses of the same category, but located elsewhere in the city (Fig. 1b). The rewiring methods we implemented operate directly at the level of individual transactions (see Additional file 1: Figure S2). A rewiring operation then consists in randomly selecting a transaction t (made by user r in business b), and an r,b alternative business b = b,suchthan b and b are of the same category (see in Additional file 1 the details of the 16 business categories), but located in different neighborhoods. (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 4 of 13 ab Fig. 1 Rewiring urban shopping trips. a Average income per business in the neighborhoods of Barcelona resulting from individual transactions. The average income has been normalized by the maximum value among neighborhoods. The data correspond to 2011 and is displayed by zip code in the metropolitan area. From this perspective, some neighborhoods are five times richer than others. b The general principle common to the iterative rewiring methods. At each step a transaction is randomly selected, along with the possible alternative businesses (highlighted in bold). If rewiring the transaction to one of them (randomly selected) decreases inequality between neighborhoods and matches the other constraints, then rewiring is performed The rewiring occurs only if the change fulfills a number of constraints which are expressed at the city level. The calculation of these constraints are based on the candidate config- uration of the shopping trips network (i.e. after k + 1 rewiring operations), the current configuration (after k rewiring operations) and the original shopping trips network. Four dimensions to assess the likelihood of the network’s configuration We consider four dimensions to assess the different network configurations from an economic, social and environmental point of view. Since our main objective is to rebal- ance the distribution of commercial income among the neighborhoods, we first focus on the economic dimension. We denote by W the wealth inequality among the city’s neighborhoods after k rewiring operations. It is defined as the distance to a reference homogeneous situation, where the commercial income resulting from purchases would be equally shared among all neighborhoods. We have: i ∗ W = w − w,(1) i=1 where N is the number of neighborhoods, w is the average income of the businesses located in the neighborhood i after k rewiring operations, and w represents the wealth per neighborhood in the reference configuration where commercial income is evenly distributed across neighborhoods, such that ∗ i w = w.(2) i=1 Another important aspect is related to the social nature of mobility in the city that might prevent some neighborhoods from ghettoization. To measure to what extent individuals residing in various neighborhoods mix in the city space as a result of their travels, for each (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 5 of 13 i1 iN neighborhood i we count the number of times s , ..., s the residents of i traveled to k k each of the N neighborhoods (i included), after k rewiring operations. Then, by averaging the vector of trips over all the neighborhoods, we compute a geographical diversity index S (after k rewiring operations), N N ij S = s − s,(3) i=1 j=1 where s represents the homogeneous distribution of visits originating from i and in direction to all neighborhoods, ij s = s.(4) j=1 The third considered dimension is the distance traveled by individuals. Summing the distances traveled by individuals for all their shopping trips, we can compute D the total distance traveled, as measured after rewiring k transactions. Details about the method used to estimate the shopping trips distances are available in Additional file 1. Finally, we are also interested in individual mobility routines and the tendency of indi- viduals to return to already visited places. For each individual we calculate an exploration rate ρ . It is defined as the number of unique businesses he/she has visited divided by his/her total number of transactions, after k rewiring operations. Considering the empir- ical peaked distribution of ρ among the population of customers (see Fig. 3b), in the following we only consider the average value ρ¯ . Rewiring constraints As mentioned above, a candidate reconfiguration of the shopping trips network (k + 1 rewiring operations) will occur if and only if the proposed change respects a number of constraints regarding the current configuration (k rewiring operations) and the original shopping trips network. We consider four constraints, each of them concerns one of the four economic, social and environmental dimensions described in the previous section, A first constraint applies on the wealth distribution; it ensures that each destination change contributes to iteratively homogenize the distribution of commercial income across neighborhoods. A constraint on the spatial mixing of individuals resulting from their shopping travels. In order to be accepted, a rewiring operation has to preserve the diversity of neighborhoods visited, hence the degree of spatial mixing of individuals residing in different neighborhoods. A third constraint on the total distance traveled, to guarantee that each destination change does not result in increasing the total distance traveled. The distance associated to each individual transaction is calculated with regard to the individual’s main activity place at this moment of the day. Finally, a constraint on the spatial exploration rate of individuals, to preserve the behavioral mobility routines measured in the population. All constrains have the same form and are satisfied if the following condition holds X if X ≥ αX , k k+1 0 X ≤ (5) k+1 αX otherwise, 0 (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 6 of 13 where k denotes the number of rewiring operation, and α is a parameter positive or equal to zero. The general form of Eq. 5 allows us to fix an objective upper bound for each dimension X with respect to its original value X .Thenaslongas X is greater k 0 k than αX , each rewiring operation must decrease X.Once X is smaller than αX ,then 0 k 0 rule 5 ensures that none of the following rewiring operations will increase X above αX . k 0 An experiment is then defined by a set of four values (α , α , α , α ) that specify the W S D ρ¯ maximal value desired for each variable of interest. Algorithm The process is unambiguously specified by Algorithm 1. One should note that the prod- ucts purchased and the amount of expenses of each individual are preserved. This iterative process is run until the rewiring rate falls below a given threshold (see the Additional file 1 for more details). Since the rewiring process is stochastic, all the results we discuss in the following sections have been averaged over hundreds of replications. Numerous rewiring methods fulfilling the aforementionned conditions could be pro- posed. However, we favored a numerical approach because of the large number of transactions (∼ 10 ) and also because of the constraints we impose to guarantee realistic and interesting properties. Besides, the random selection of (i) the transaction to rewire and (ii) of the candidate business (step 1. of the algorithm) can be uniform (denoted “Uniform” sampling hereafter) or proportional to their amount in the case of transactions and/or inversely propor- tional to the average income of the targeted neighborhood for the businesses (denoted “Weighted” sampling hereafter). Even more informed methods might be proposed, but for the sake of simplicity only simple random procedures are tested in the following. Algorithm 1 Rewiring the shopping trips network Input: Shopping trips network obtained after k operations th 1. Pick at random a candidate (k + 1) rewiring operation: Pick at random a transaction t (made by user r in business b) r,b Pick at random a business b (same category but another neighborhood) 2. Compute (W , S , D , ρ¯ ) k+1 k+1 k+1 k+1 3. if for each dimension X ∈{W, S, D, ρ¯} we have X if X ≥ αX , k k+1 0 X ≤ k+1 αX otherwise, 3. then Accept the rewiring operation 3. else Return to step 1. Results Reachability of even spatial distributions We first investigate the reachability of an even spatial distribution of the commercial income resulting from individual purchases, while the variables S, D and ρ¯ remain in the range of their empirical values. To address this question, we apply the rewiring method previously described with the four constraints of Eq. 5 such as α = 0, α = 1, α = 1 W S D (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 7 of 13 and α = 1. This constitutes our Reference scenario. Figure 2a shows the evolution of inequality in the urban area of Barcelona as a function of the fraction of rewired trans- actions, according to various sampling methods. Surprisingly, even with basic random sampling methods, it is possible to reduce spatial inequality between neighbourhoods by more than 80% while reassigning only 20% of individual transactions. All the methods produce the same qualitative behavior – an early regime of very fast decay, followed by a regime of slower decay. Weighted methods are naturally more efficient, and allow to reach spatial equity by redirecting a smaller fraction of transactions. In particular, a reduction of wealth inequality of 80% (W /W ) can be obtained by rewiring only 5% of the transactions k 0 if the sampling method is double weighted. The state of the other variables S, D and ρ is also monitored along the process, as shown in Fig. 2b for a Uniform-Uniform sampling method. What makes the previous results remarkable is in fact that income redistribution is achieved without increas- ing the distance traveled by individuals (D), nor changing their mobility routines (ρ¯). Moreover, a positive side-effect is to increase the frequency of encounters of individ- uals living in different parts of the city – as indicated by the decrease of S /S –, an k 0 effect that could not be anticipated from the rewiring constraints alone (α = 1). The increase of spatial mixing is the consequence of individual shopping trips more evenly distributed in the city space, required to homogenize the income among neighbor- hoods. The behavior of S is non trivial, notably because one could imagine unrealistic solutions that would simultaneously even the spatial distribution of business income and decrease the total distance traveled, by rewiring most of the shopping trips to the closest neighborhood containing businesses of the relevant category. In this case the spatial mixing of individuals would decrease dramatically, and S the distance to an homogeneous mixing would increase. Here the decay of S/S guarantees that it is not the case. ab Fig. 2 Decreasing spatial inequality in the city by adapting daily shopping destinations. a Decrease of wealth inequality among neighborhoods as a function of the fraction of transactions rewired, for various rewiring methods. Four combinations of choice heuristics are considered, “Uniform-Uniform”, “Uniform-Weighted”, “Weighted-Uniform” and “Weighted-Weighted”. b Decrease of wealth inequality (W /W ) while preserving k 0 the spatial mixing index (S /S ), the total distance traveled (D /D ) and the exploration rate (ρ¯ /ρ¯ ), as a k 0 k 0 k 0 function of the number of rewiring operations. Values have been averaged over hundreds of replications. The bars represent the minimum and the maximum values obtained but in most cases are too close to the average to be seen (see Additional file 1: Figure S10-S11 for Madrid) (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 8 of 13 Preservation of human mobility properties We wish to control further the likelihood of the rewired shopping mobility networks, and ensure that they preserve the spatial properties of individual human mobility. A small set of indicators have proved to be useful to describe the statistical and spatial properties of human mobility (González et al. 2008). These include the jump length between con- ∗ 2 secutive locations , the radius of gyration r (with r (i) = (x (i) − x (i)) , r g g j N j=1 r (i) is the characteristic travel distance of individual i with center of mass x (i) after N displacements), and the tendency to return to already visited places ρ.Inourcase,for each individual ρ is simply defined as the ratio between the number of unique businesses visited and the total number of transactions. Figure 3 shows their empirical and simulated values, plus the average distance d trav- eled by each individual for each shopping trip (see the Additional file 1 for details on the calculation of shopping trips distances). On each panel both curves overlap almost per- fectly, indicating that the rewiring has no significant effect on the key mobility properties. The simulated distributions of d and r are slightly more peaked than the empirical ones. We showed in a previous study that young adults tend to spend their money further from their neighborhood of residence (Lenormand et al. 2015). Coherently their shop- ping trips are those that are the most affected in the simulated scenarios (see Additional file 1: Figure S6). But the simulated scenarios also contain some questionnable aspects. a b c d Fig. 3 Observed and simulated distributions of human mobility indicators. The distribution of jump lengths (c), the radius of gyration r (d), the tendency to return to already visited places (ρ)(b) and the individual r g average distance traveled (d)(a) are considered. Values measured on the empirical data are in blue, while those obtained after rewiring are in red. The calculation of and r is based on the business’ exact r g geographical coordinates. The simulated distributions plotted here correspond to one particular replication, see Additional file 1: Figure S4 for the robustness of the results and Additional file 1: Figure S12 for the same curves for Madrid (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 9 of 13 For example, elderly people are those whose displacements would increase the most (with regard to their current shopping travel distances – see Additional file 1: Figure S5). Multi-objective improvement We now perform multi-criteria rewiring experiments in order to measure to what extent redistribution can be achieved while improving simultaneously other important aspects of urban mobility. To this end, we perform the series of experiments summarized in Table 1. The objective is to even the wealth distribution among neighborhoods (α = 0) and also improve either S, D or ρ¯ without worsening the other two. Figure 4 gives the rela- tive gains and losses upon the four indicators, and the last two columns of Table 1 contain the asymptotic values obtained for the reduction rate of wealth inequality, for Barcelona (B) and Madrid (M). These experiments proove that it is not always possible to combine significant improve- ments on several dimensions simultaneously. This is not an issue with the method, but rather with the set of objectives which are somewhat opposite. Most individuals perform their shopping trips near their residence – as highlighted by the empirical distributions in Fig. 3 – and consequently it is not feasible to diversify the neighborhoods where an individual regularly travels to – in order to improve spatial mixing S –andat thesame time decrease the total travel distance D. More surprisingly, experiment (b) indicates that it is also not possible to simultaneously improve the wealth redistribution and the spa- tial mixing of individuals. The two indicators are based on different metrics (the amount of money spent per business for W and the number of trips for S), which imply dif- ferent reference egalitarian situations (see Additional file 1: Figure S7 for more details). Optimization is thus a trade-off between the various consequences of shopping mobility at the city scale. However, experiments (c) and (d) prove that it is possible to signifi- cantly decrease the total distance traveled and in the same time to strongly reduce wealth inequality among neighborhoods, but not as much as in the reference experiment. Still, it is remarkable that experiment (d) results in an alternative mobility network such that the spatial inequality of the average business income is reduced by 95%, while the total distance associated to shopping mobility is reduced by 25%, the level of spatial mix- ing is preserved, as well as the individual mobility routines. Finally, experiments (e) and (f) show that even if residents deeply restructured their mobility routines, and typically started going to a new business each time they perform a new shopping trip, keep- ing control of the total distance traveled in the city would prevent from increasing the mixing of individuals coming from different neighborhoods beyond 25%. The gains in terms of wealth redistribution would not be significant when compared to the reference experiment (a). Table 1 Experiments performed. Column W indicates the relative gain of (W − W )/W . The first 0 k 0 value is for Barcelona (B) and the second for Madrid (M) Experiment α α α α W(B/M) W S D ρ¯ (a) Reference 0 1 1 1 96.4%/99.5% (b) Spatial mixing ↑ 0 0.75 1 1 85.9%/78.1% (c) 50% energy savings 0 1 0.5 1 87.4%/84.8% (d) 25% energy savings 0 1 0.75 1 94.7%/98.8% (e) Exploration rate ↑ 0 1 1 1.25 96.8%/99.9% (f) Exploration rate ↑↑ 0 1 1 1.5 97.3%/100% (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 10 of 13 Fig. 4 Multi-criteria improvement of shopping mobility. Each group of bars gives the relative gains or losses for the four indicators W, S, D and ρ¯. Experiments are described in Table 1. See Additional file 1: Figure S13 for Madrid Discussion Reducing urban segregation and increasing spatial justice are some of the major chal- lenges faced by cities worldwide, and the digital footprints passively produced by their residents constitute a promising resource to help addressing these issues from the bot- tom. This study is a first attempt to quantify the relation between shopping mobility and the spatial distribution of economic activity in the city. The alternative shopping trips resulting from our experiments offer an interesting trade-off between the preservation of essential aspects – the effective purchases of individuals and households, and their mobility properties – and some reasonable changes in the places where they spend their money. The addition of small changes in the shopping destinations of individuals can dra- matically impact the spatial distribution of money flows in the city, and the frequency of encounters between residents of different neighborhoods, even if the total number of changes remains relatively small. These results have important consequences, and they lead in particular to the decisive question of the effective implementation of alternative shopping travels, like those drawn by our experiments. While the decision process behind each individual redirection may appear intricate for a single person, one could easily imag- ine dedicated mobile applications, querying databases similar to the one we used in this paper. Their purpose would be to assist their users in a transition toward a more socially and spatially concerned shopping mobility. Limitations of the study However, one should keep in mind that individuals do not guide most of their travel decisions by philanthropy, but instead by balancing accessibility, price and business characteristics. Individuals first choose their casual shopping destinations with regard of transport facilities and travel time budget (Recker and Kostyniuk 1978). Here as accessibility information we considered the Euclidean distance between neighborhoods. However, in urban environments the Euclidean distance is rarely a direct proxy for travel time (Gallotti et al. 2016), and some of the rewired shopping trips are unlikely to be (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 11 of 13 performed in the real world. more accurate measures of travel time. In future studies transport APIs and road network data could be used instead to calculate more realistic travel distances between points in the city. Also, from a choice point of view, distance is not the only one determinant of shopping destination choices. The inequality might be also due to the inequality between businesses of the same category, which may differ sub- stantially in terms of the price, product quality, etc. The reader should also remind that prices of retail goods are not uniform across a city’s neighborhoods, they may display strong spatial variation, affecting consumer choices and spatial behavior in complex ways. We also assumed that every shopping trip follows the simple pattern A → B → A, and we did not consider the more complicated case of chained trips (e.g. A → B → C → A) during which individuals join several trips associated with different purposes (Schneider et al. 2013). Destination choices for certain types of shopping travels are also motivated by reasons that are not only related to the sole proximity (e.g. the local market is a place where residents can build a sense of community, discuss the problems of the neighbourhood, make social contacts useful in everyday life). People also tend to choose the places where they spend money according to several other key factors, the price of products in the first place, but also according to some more personal appreciations, such as the "atmosphere" of neighborhoods and the feeling of well-being they provide. In large cities, the neighborhoods strongly differ in the quality of their planning and architecture, in their public spaces, in their amenities and leisure opportunities, commercial fabric, in their safety. Additionally, the changes might be considered as problematic, since a pro- found spatial reorganization of shopping mobility in the city could have consequences on the spatial structure of employment in the first place (see Additional file 1: Figures S8 and S9 showing the evolution of the number of clients and transactions per business), then on residences, finally on their commercial offer and ambience. This questions the likelihood and desirability of the objective configuration we chose, in which the average commercial income per business is evenly balanced across neighbourhoods. Still it has the advantage to be unambiguously defined, and constitutes an immediate, easy-to-think-with reference situation For the sake of simplicity, we considered none of the aforementionned factors but they could be implemented in more involved frameworks derived from our work. A num- ber of additional constraints, aiming at making the rewiring schemes more realistic from a spatial economy perspective, could be introduced in future scenarios. These include the preservation of the number of transactions and income per business (or at least a certain fraction of them); the restriction of the rewiring operations to certain business categories; limiting changes for certain socio-demographic categories of population (such as elderly people); or ensuring the temporal likelihood of the simulated scenarios (so that the rerouted shopping travels are homogeneously distributed through time). Concluding remarks There are recent, encouraging examples of fast and wide adoptions of new daily prac- tices, whose benefits are essentially collective. Examples include garbage differentiation (Robinson and Read 2005), the increasing role of bicycle in urban transport and the devel- opment of bicycle sharing systems (Dill and Carr 2003), or the open-source movement and the dedication of a growing number of individuals to collectively build free knowl- edge databases (e.g. Wikipedia, StackExchange, the free software movement). In these (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 12 of 13 cases, the remuneration of participants, if any, is essentially symbolic. The success of a spatial counterpart to these altruistic behaviors could rejuvenate the very meaning of the so-called sharing economy (McLaren and Agyeman 2015). As citizens produce the data that document their location and activity patterns, in return these data could serve not only the specific interest of the institution collecting them, but also support fair socio- economic initiatives. Our study brings evidence that these geographical footprints we passively produce can support bottom-up responses to big societal issues, an expected feature of truly smart cities. Additional file Additional file 1: Supplementary Information for Crowdsourcing the Robin Hood effect in cities. (PDF 782 kb) Acknowledgements We wish to thank Julie Vallée and Suma Desu for providing feedback on an early version of the manuscript. Partial financial support has been received from the Spanish Ministry of Economy (MINECO) and FEDER (EU) under the project INTENSE@COSYP (FIS2012-30634), and from the EU Commission through projects EUNOIA and INSIGHT. The work of TL has been funded under the PD/004/2015, from the Conselleria de Educación, Cultura y Universidades of the Government of the Balearic Islands and from the European Social Fund through the Balearic Islands ESF operational program for 2013-2017. JJR acknowledges funding from the Ramón y Cajal program of MINECO. Authors’ contributions TL and ML designed research, analyzed the data, performed the experiments and drafted the manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript. Competing interests The authors declare no competing interests. Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. Author details 1 2 CNRS, UMR Géographie-cités, 13 rue du four, FR-75006 Paris, France. Irstea, UMR TETIS, 500 rue JF Breton, FR-34093 3 4 Montpellier, France. BBVA Data & Analytics, Avenida de Burgos 16D, E-28036 Madrid, Spain. Instituto de Física Interdisciplinar y Sistemas Complejos IFISC (CSIC-UIB), Campus UIB, 07122 Palma de Mallorca, Spain. Received: 30 September 2016 Accepted: 4 April 2017 References (AASHTO) The American Association of State Highways and Transportation Officials (2013) Commuting in America 2013, the national report on commuting patterns and trends. Technical report Blau JR, Blau PM (1982) Cost of Inequality - Metropolitan Structure and Violent Crime. Am Sociol Rev 47:114–129 Brooks-Gunn J, Duncan G, Aber J (1997) Neighborhood Poverty, Volume 1: Context and Consequences for Children. Russell Sage Foundation, New York Cassiers T, Kesteloot C (2012) Socio-spatial Inequalities and Social Cohesion in European Cities. Urban Studies 49(9):1909–1924 Chetty R, Hendren N (2015) The impacts of neighborhoods on intergenerational mobility: childhood exposure effects and county-level estimates. Technical report. Harvard Univ. Dept. of Economics de Montjoye Y-A, Radaelli L, Singh VK, Pentland A (2015) Unique in the shopping mall: On the reidentifiability of credit card metadata. Science 347(6221):536–539 Dill J, Carr T (2003) Bicycle commuting and facilities in major U.S. cities: if you build them, commuters will use them. Transp Res Rec J Transp Res Board 1828:116–123 Eagle N, Macy M, Claxton R (2010) Network Diversity and Economic Development. Science 328(5981):1029–1031 Friedrichs J, Galster G, Musterd S (2003) Neighbourhood effects on social opportunities: the European and American research and policy context. Hous Stud 18(6):797–806 Gallotti R, Bazzani A, Rambaldi S, Barthelemy M (2016) A stochastic model of randomly accelerated walkers for human mobility. Nat Commun 7:12600 Goldsmith W, Blakely EJ, Clinton B (2010) Separate societies: poverty and inequality in U.S. Cities. 2nd Edition. Temple University Press, Philadelphia González MC, Hidalgo CA, Barabási A-L (2008) Understanding individual human mobility patterns. Nature 453(7196):779–782 Kanbur R, Venables AJ (2005) Spatial Inequality and Development. Oxford University Press Lazer D, Pentland A, Adamic L, Aral S, Barabási A-L, Brewer D, Christakis N, Contractor N, Fowler J, Gutmann M, Jebara T, King G, Macy M, Roy D, Alstyne MV (2009) Computational Social Science. Science 323(5915):721–723 (2017) 2:11 Louail et al. Applied Network Science Page 13 of 13 Lenormand M, Louail T, Cantú-Ros OG, Picornell M, Herranz R, Murillo Arias J, Barthelemy M, San Miguel M, Ramasco JJ (2015) Influence of sociodemographics on human mobility. Sci Rep 5:10075 Lu X, Bengtsson L, Holme P (2012) Predictability of population displacement after the 2010 Haiti earthquake. Proc Natl Acad Sci 109(29):11576–11581 Martinez EA, Rubio MH, Martinez RM, Arias JM, Patane D, Zerbe A, Kirkpatrick R, Luengo-Oroz M, Zerbe A (2016) Measuring economic resilience to natural disasters with big economic transaction data. arXiv preprint arXiv:1609.09340 McLaren D, Agyeman J (2015) Sharing cities: a case for truly smart and sustainable cities. Urban and Industrial Environments. MIT Press, Cambridge Miciukiewicz K, Vigar G (2012) Mobility and social cohesion in the splintered city: challenging technocentric transport research and policy-making practices. Urban Studies 49(9):1941–1957 Lewis K (2015) Three fallacies of digital footprints. Big Data Soc 2(2):2053951715602496 Onnela J-P, Saramäki J, Hyvönen J, Szabó G, Lazer D, Kaski K, Kertész J, Barabási A-L (2007) Structure and tie strengths in mobile communication networks. Proc Natl Acad Sci 104(18):7332–7336 Ostendorf W, Musterd S, De Vos S (2001) Social mix and the neighbourhood effect. policy ambitions and empirical evidence. Hous Stud 16(3):371–380 Piketty T (2014) Capital in the twenty-first century. Harvard University Press, Cambridge Pinol J-L (2003) Histoire de l’Europe urbaine, Seuil, Paris, France Recker WW, Kostyniuk LP (1978) Factors influencing destination choice for the urban grocery shopping trip. Transportation 7(1):19–33 Robinson GM, Read AD (2005) Recycling behaviour in a London Borough: Results from large-scale household surveys. Resour Conserv Recycl 45(1):70–83 Ruault J-F (2014) L’effet de la consommation de passage sur le développement et l’intégration métropolitaine des territoires en Ile-de-France. Paris Est Satterthwaite D, Mitlin D (2013) Reducing Urban Poverty in the Global South. Routledge, London, New York Schneider CM, Belik V, Couronné T, Smoreda Z, González MC (2013) Unravelling daily human mobility motifs. J R Soc Interface 10(84):20130246 Sun L, Axhausen KW, Lee D-H, Huang X (2013) Understanding metropolitan patterns of daily encounters. Proc Natl Acad Sci 110(34):13774–13779 Stiglitz JE (2015) The Great Divide: Unequal Societies and What We Can Do About Them, 1 edition. W. W Norton & Company, New York UN-HABITAT (2014) State of African Cities Re-imagining sustainable urban transitions. State of Cities - Regional Reports. UN-Habitat Vallée J, Cadot E, Grillo F, Parizot I, Chauvin P (2010) The combined effects of activity space and neighbourhood of residence on participation in preventive health-care activities: The case of cervical screening in the Paris metropolitan area (France). Health Place 16(5):838–852 Womack B (1972) Across 110th street. United Artists Yoshimura Y, Sobolevsky S, Hobin JNB, Ratti C, Blat J (2016) Urban association rules: uncovering linked trips for shopping behavior. preprint arXiv:1610.00187 Submit your manuscript to a journal and benefi t from: 7 Convenient online submission 7 Rigorous peer review 7 Immediate publication on acceptance 7 Open access: articles freely available online 7 High visibility within the fi eld 7 Retaining the copyright to your article Submit your next manuscript at 7 springeropen.com
Applied Network Science – Springer Journals
Published: Jun 8, 2017
You can share this free article with as many people as you like with the url below! We hope you enjoy this feature!
Read and print from thousands of top scholarly journals.
Already have an account? Log in
Bookmark this article. You can see your Bookmarks on your DeepDyve Library.
To save an article, log in first, or sign up for a DeepDyve account if you don’t already have one.
Copy and paste the desired citation format or use the link below to download a file formatted for EndNote
Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
All DeepDyve websites use cookies to improve your online experience. They were placed on your computer when you launched this website. You can change your cookie settings through your browser.