Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
(2009)
ÔQuantitative easingÕ
Harry Markowitz (1971)
Portfolio Selection
Daniel Waggoner, T. Zha (1998)
Conditional Forecasts in Dynamic Multivariate ModelsReview of Economics and Statistics, 81
Athanasios Orphanides (2011)
Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Great Recession
James Hamilton, Jing Wu (2011)
The Effectiveness of Alternative Monetary Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound EnvironmentERN: Econometric Modeling in Financial Economics (Topic)
Gauti Eggertsson, M. Woodford (2003)
Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal Monetary PolicyBrookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2003
F. Modigliani, R. Sutch (1967)
Debt Management and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: An Empirical Analysis of Recent ExperienceJournal of Political Economy, 75
Luca Benati, Paolo Surico (2008)
VAR Analysis and the Great ModerationMacroeconomics eJournal
J. Tobin (1969)
A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary TheoryJournal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1
Lars Svensson (2004)
Comments on Bernanke, Reinhart, and Sack, "An Empirical Assessment of Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero Bound" ∗
C. Bean, Matthias Paustian, Adrian Penalver, Tim Taylor (2010)
Monetary policy after the fall
M. Lenza, H. Pill, L. Reichlin (2010)
Monetary Policy in Exceptional TimesWiley-Blackwell: Economic Policy
Jonathan Bridges, Ryland Thomas (2012)
The Impact of QE on the UK Economy – Some Supportive Monetarist ArithmeticBank of England Research Paper Series
Takeshi Kimura, David Small (2004)
Quantitative Monetary Easing and Risk in Financial Asset MarketsTopics in Macroeconomics, 6
Eric Jacquier, Nicholas Polson, Peter Rossi (1994)
Bayesian Analysis of Stochastic Volatility ModelsJournal of Business & Economic Statistics, 20
Ben Bernanke, Vincent Reinhart, B. Sack (2004)
Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero Bound: An Empirical AssessmentBrookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2004
C. Bean, Matthias Paustian, Adrian Penalver, Tim Taylor, J. Hole, Wyoming. (2010)
Monetary Policy after the Fall Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Annual Conference
Robert Litterman (1984)
Forecasting with Bayesian Vector Autoregressions-Five Years of ExperienceJournal of Business & Economic Statistics, 4
Javier Andrés, J. López-Salido, Edward Nelson (2004)
Tobin's Imperfect Asset Substitution in Optimizing General EquilibriumJournal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 36
Lawrence Christiano (2011)
Commentary: Remarks on Unconventional Monetary PolicyInternational Journal of Central Banking, 7
UK exchange rate index BofE 12 10-year gilt -T-bill spread BofE 34 US dollar-sterling exchange rate BofE 13 UK consumer confidence EC 35
M. Pesaran, Ron Smith (2012)
Counterfactual Analysis in Macroeconometrics: An Empirical Investigation into the Effects of Quantitative EasingEconometric Modeling: Macroeconomics eJournal
Hess Chung, Jean-Philippe Laforte, D. Reifschneider, John Williams (2011)
Have We Underestimated the Likelihood and Severity of Zero Lower Bound EventsJournal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44
Michael Joyce, Ana Lasaosa, I. Stevens, Matthew Tong (2010)
The Financial Market Impact of Quantitative EasingERN: Banking & Monetary Policy (Topic)
James Mitchell, Richard Smith, M. Weale, S. Wright, Eduardo Salazar (2005)
An Indicator of Monthly GDP and an Early Estimate of Quarterly GDP GrowthEconomic Growth
Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, A. Krishnamurthy (2011)
The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest RatesAmerican Finance Association Meetings (AFA)
André Meier (2009)
Panacea, Curse, or Nonevent? Unconventional Monetary Policy in the United KingdomInternational Monetary Fund (IMF) Research Paper Series
(2011)
Lessons on unconventional monetary policy from the United Kingdom , speech given at the US Monetary Policy Forum , NewYork on 25 February 2011
(2010)
ÔThe large scale asset purchases had large international effectsÕ
Felix Schläpfer (2007)
Working Paper No
R. Harrison (2012)
Asset Purchase Policy at the Effective Lower Bound for Interest RatesEconometrics: Applied Econometric Modeling in Financial Economics eJournal
S. Chib (1998)
Estimation and comparison of multiple change-point modelsJournal of Econometrics, 86
K. Kadiyala, Sune Karlsson (1997)
Numerical Methods for Estimation and Inference in Bayesian VAR-modelsJournal of Applied Econometrics, 12
Office for National Statistics (ONS) and Halifax (HF). Data transformation: We use log-levels for the variables
Vasco Cúrdia, M. Woodford (2009)
Conventional and Unconventional Monetary PolicyERN: Other European Economics: Macroeconomics & Monetary Economics (Topic)
A. Krishnamurthy, Annette Vissing-Jorgensen (2011)
The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for PolicyBrookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2011
J. Trichet (2009)
The ECB's Enhanced Credit SupportERN: Other European Economics: Macroeconomics & Monetary Economics (Topic)
G. Evans, S. Honkapohja (2001)
Learning and expectations in macroeconomics
(1966)
ÔInnovations in interest rate policyÕ
Lawrence Christiano, Daisuke Ikeda (2011)
Government Policy, Credit Markets and Economic ActivityERN: Monetary Policy Objectives; Policy Designs; Policy Coordination (Topic)
R. Greenwood, Dimitri Vayanos (2008)
Bond Supply and Excess Bond ReturnsMacroeconomics eJournal
Charles Nelson, Chang‐Jin Kim (1999)
State Space Models with Regime Switching
ÔA preferred-habitat model of the term structure of interest ratesÕ
Eric Swanson (2011)
Let’s Twist Again: A High-Frequency Event-Study Analysis of Operation Twist and Its Implications for QE2Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2011
Chris Carter, R. Kohn (1994)
On Gibbs sampling for state space modelsBiometrika, 81
Andrea Carriero, G. Kapetanios, Massimiliano Marcellino (2010)
Forecasting Government Bond Yields with Large Bayesian VarsEconometrics: Single Equation Models eJournal
H. Ugai (2007)
Effects of the Quantitative Easing Policy: A Survey of Empirical AnalysesMonetary and and Economic Studies, 25
Giorgio Primiceri (2002)
Time Varying Structural Vector Autoregressions and Monetary PolicyMonetary Economics
Spencer Dale, J. Chadha, S. Holly (2011)
QE – one year on
Jochen Andritzky, Andreas Jobst, Sylwia Nowak, Yacine Ait-Sahalia, Natalia Tamirisa (2009)
How to Stop a Herd of Running Bears? Market Response to Policy Initiatives During the Global Financial CrisisCorporate Governance: Comparative eJournal
C. Baumeister, Luca Benati (2010)
Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Great Recession - Estimating the Impact of a Compression in the Yield Spread at the Zero Lower BoundEconometrics: Econometric & Statistical Methods - General eJournal
A. Estrella (2005)
Why Does the Yield Curve Predict Output and Inflation?Monetary Economics
Timothy Cogley, T. Sargent (2003)
Drifts and Volatilities: Monetary Policies and Outcomes in the Post WWII U.S.ERN: Monetary Policy (Topic)
D. Giannone, Martha Banbura, L. Reichlin (2010)
Large Bayesian vector auto regressionsULB Institutional Repository
Joseph Gagnon, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, B. Sack (2012)
The Financial Market Effects of the Federal Reserve's Large-Scale Asset Purchases
Tae-Yong Doh (2010)
The Efficacy of Large-Scale Asset Purchases at the Zero Lower BoundEconometric Reviews, 95
L. Bauwens, M. Lubrano, J. Richard (2000)
Bayesian Inference in Dynamic Econometric Models
Stefania D’Amico, T. King (2010)
Flow and Stock Effects of Large-Scale Treasury PurchasesBoard of Governors: Finance & Economics Discussion Series (Topic)
C. Sims (1980)
MACROECONOMICS AND REALITYEconometrica, 48
Patrick Robinson, A. Zellner (1974)
An Introduction to Bayesian Inference in Econometrics., 137
Abstract This article examines the macroeconomic impact of the first round of quantitative easing (QE) by the Bank of England. We attempt to quantify the effects of these purchases by focusing on the impact of lower long‐term interest rates on the wider economy. We use three different models to estimate the impact of QE on output and inflation: a large Bayesian vector autoregression (VAR), a change‐point structural VAR and a time‐varying parameter VAR. Our estimates suggest that QE may have had a peak effect on the level of real GDP of around and a peak effect on annual CPI inflation of about % points. The sharp deterioration of the global financial crisis in late 2008 led to the increased risk of a severe downturn on a scale not seen since the Great Depression of the 1930s. In many countries, the fiscal and monetary authorities responded with a variety of conventional and less conventional measures aimed at mitigating the effects on financial stability and the real economy. In the UK, the Bank of England introduced a number of innovative policy measures. As Bean (2011) describes, these measures included enhanced liquidity support, actions to deal with dysfunctional financial markets and large‐scale asset purchases. In this article, we focus on assessing the macroeconomic effects of the Bank's programme of large‐scale asset purchases (LSAPs), commonly referred to as quantitative easing (QE). The Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) of the Bank of England announced that it would begin a large programme of asset purchases, mainly of UK government bonds or gilts, on 5 March 2009, at the same time as it reduced Bank Rate, the official UK policy rate, to 0.5%. Despite lowering policy rates close to the zero lower bound (ZLB), the MPC felt that additional measures were necessary to achieve the 2% CPI inflation target in the medium term. The aim of the programme of asset purchases financed by the issuance of central bank money was to inject a large monetary stimulus into the economy, to boost nominal expenditure and thereby increase domestic inflation sufficiently to meet the inflation target. Between March 2009 and the end of January 2010 the Bank purchased a total of £200 billion assets, representing about 14% of UK GDP. Most of the previous work on this topic has focused on the effects of QE on financial markets (Joyce et al., 2011). Our work by contrast focuses on measuring the wider economic effects of the Bank's asset purchases on output and inflation. Understanding the effects of QE on the wider economy is of course necessary to appreciate the effectiveness of QE as a policy option during times of financial crisis. It is also useful for understanding the transmission mechanism of unconventional monetary policy. The approach we take involves conducting counterfactual analysis, to assess what would have happened had QE not been undertaken, which we then compare with a baseline prediction which includes QE. Our analysis is based on three models. We use a large BVAR, estimated over rolling windows, to allow for structural change; an MS‐SVAR, where parameters are allowed to change at a particular time to capture regime changes; and a TVP‐SVAR, which allows us to assess general time variation in parameters. The BVAR places more weight on past patterns in the data, by incorporating a large data set and the minimum amount of economic structure. Such models have been found to be useful because they allow the analysis of complex interrelationships between a large set of economic data, which in our case involves the interconnections between interest rate spreads and the real economy. The MS‐SVAR and the TVP‐SVAR employ a small data set but they allow us to incorporate a more sophisticated treatment of structural change. The underlying economic or structural shocks in these models are identified through restrictions on the impulse responses (Baumeister and Benati, 2010). We use each of the models to conduct counterfactual analysis of the effects of QE. This exercise relies on the empirical evidence in Joyce et al. (2011), which suggests that QE reduced medium to long‐term government bond yields by about 100 basis points. To produce counterfactual forecasts, we therefore assume that without QE gilt yields would have been 100 basis points higher, ceteris paribus. For the purpose of the counterfactual, we also assume that the effects of QE come solely through lower long‐term government bond yield spreads. We implement this effect on yields by adjusting the spread between the relevant long‐maturity gilt yield in each model and the three‐month Treasury bill rate (henceforth the government bond spread). The link between government bond spreads and macroeconomic variables is given a structural interpretation in, for example, Estrella (2005). One caveat here is that our models do not allow us to discriminate between the effects of movements in bond spreads that come through term premia and those that come through expected future policy rates. So to the extent that QE effects on spreads come mainly through term premia (as much of the literature suggests – see Section 2), and this has different macroeconomic effects to spread movements caused by future policy rate expectations, this will not be captured in our analysis. Our multiple models strategy is similar in spirit to the approach adopted by Chung et al. (2012) in their analysis of the incidence of the ZLB interest rate policy environment (though their article only uses one model in its analysis of the Federal Reserve's LSAP programmes). Bridges and Thomas (2012) also use a number of monetary models to estimate the effect of the Bank of England asset purchases on the level of GDP and CPI inflation. The use of different models that vary in their emphasis on data versus economic structure increases our faith in the likely robustness of our conclusions. Our analysis encompasses existing time‐series models in the literature on the effects of unconventional monetary policy (Baumeister and Benati, 2010; Lenza et al., 2010; Joyce et al., 2011) and extends this literature by including models that account for structural change. Results from the counterfactual analysis of the effects of QE using the large BVAR model suggests that without QE there would have been larger declines in real GDP during 2009 and CPI inflation would have been low or even negative. The QE policy was therefore effective in helping the UK economy avoid a deeper recession and deflation. The MS‐SVAR and TVP‐SVAR models provide similar evidence, if anything suggesting that QE had even larger effects on output and inflation. The rest of this article is structured as follows. Section 1 discusses the UK's experience with QE and Section 2 reviews some of the related literature on the effects of QE and other large‐scale asset purchases on financial and macro variables. Our econometric framework is described in Section 3, the data are described in Section 4, and the counterfactual assumptions we use in our analysis are discussed in Section 5.Section 6 presents empirical results for each of the models. Section 7 provides a summary of the key results and Section 8 notes the caveats to our analysis and Section 9 concludes. 1. Quantitative Easing in the UK Large‐scale asset purchases in the UK were a culmination of a package of measures designed to address the consequences of the financial crisis.1 These measures included the provision of enhanced liquidity support, measures to enhance market functioning and QE or large‐scale asset purchases (Bean, 2011). The provision of liquidity support was centred on the £185 billion Special Liquidity Scheme introduced in April 2008, which allowed banks to swap mortgage‐backed securities and other illiquid assets for Treasury bills. A Discount Window Facility was also introduced to meet the short‐term liquidity needs of financial institutions requiring assistance. In addition, there was the assurance that the Bank of England was ready to offer emergency liquidity support at a penalty rate and against a broader range of collateral to otherwise solvent financial institutions that were experiencing liquidity problems. To address market functioning, an Asset Purchase Facility was created to allow the Bank of England to purchase high‐quality commercial article and sterling investment‐grade corporate bonds. Before the QE policy was introduced, these purchases were financed by the issuance of Treasury bills and the cash management operations of the Debt Management Office. Like the offer of emergency liquidity support, the knowledge that the central bank was wishing to purchase these assets may have improved overall market functioning. The QE policy was first announced in March 2009 and it involved the Bank of England buying assets, mainly UK government bonds (gilts), financed by the issuance of central bank reserves. The effect of these purchases was to reduce gilt yields and to stimulate demand through a number of channels. In normal times, reducing Bank Rate would be the policy chosen to address demand shocks. However, with Bank Rate close to the ZLB and given the risk of undershooting the inflation target, the Bank of England's MPC had to use unconventional methods to ease monetary conditions further. The initial MPC decision was for the Bank to make £75 billion of asset purchases. This was extended subsequently to a total of £125 billion in May 2009, to a total of £175 billion in August 2009 and to a total of £200 billion in November 2009, with the purchases completed at the end of January 2010.2 This represented about 14% of annual UK GDP. Although there are a number of possible channels through which QE may affect the wider economy (see discussion in Benford et al., 2009), most analysis has emphasised the so‐called portfolio balance channel. This mechanism operates through QE purchases bidding up the prices of gilts and other assets that are more substitutable for gilts than money, and this in turn stimulates demand through lower borrowing costs and wealth effects. Portfolio balance models as described by Tobin (1969), among others, were used by Joyce et al. (2011) to determine the financial market impact of QE. They find that the predictions of these models are broadly consistent with the event study evidence for the UK. We discuss this and other empirical evidence in the next Section. 2. Related Literature Most of the literature on the effects of QE and the use of other unconventional monetary instruments has focused on financial market variables, as opposed to the effects on real activity or inflation. This is primarily due to the difficulty of identifying the appropriate counterfactual. In this Section, we summarise the literature on the effects of QE or LSAPs on financial and real variables, both in the UK and in other countries. The assessment of the effects of non‐standard monetary policies on financial variables has mainly relied on event study methods. Bernanke et al. (2004), for example, provide a comprehensive analysis of financial market reactions to various non‐standard Fed policy announcements that altered the relative supply of US Treasury securities. They conclude that both changes in relative asset quantities and the expectation of such changes have had an impact on yields or asset returns. These results are supported by vector autoregressions (VAR)‐based term structure models. Bernanke et al. (2004) also provide some evidence that QE as implemented by the Bank of Japan (providing excess reserves to maintain the interest rate at zero and open market purchases of government bonds) may have generated lower yields over the QE period, although there is weaker support from event studies compared with those for the US.3 Gagnon et al. (2011) provide an assessment of the first round of LSAPs conducted by the Fed in the wake of the great financial crisis (commonly referred to as LSAP1). On the basis of event studies of LSAP announcements, they suggest there was a contraction in Treasury yields and yields on mortgage‐backed securities (MBS) of about 90 and 110 basis points respectively. They suggest that the decline in long‐term interest rates largely reflected the fall in risk premia generated by these purchases, mainly through the reduction of duration risk. They also use a time‐series econometric model of asset quantities estimated on the basis of pre‐crisis data to determine the impact of LSAPs, which suggests slightly smaller effects. Using a different approach based on panel data analysis of individual bonds, D'Amico and King (2010) find that LSAP1 had an effect on longer term Treasury yields of about 30 basis points for the 5 to 15‐year sector. Krishnamurthy and Vissing‐Jorgensen (2011) examine both LSAP1 and the second round of Fed purchases (LSAP2) using an event study approach. They find evidence of a large decline in interest rates in the first episode but not the second (though this may reflect the fact that the markets had already priced in much of the expected impact before the second programme was announced). They identify a number of different channels through which QE may work, such as duration, liquidity and the long‐term safety channel. Swanson (2011) revisits the Operation Twist experiment of the 1960s using event study techniques and argues that it was broadly comparable in scale to LSAP2. He finds that both policies reduced longer term Treasury yields by around 15 basis points.4 The UK's experience with QE in the recent financial crisis has been documented in a number of studies. Meier (2009), Bean et al. (2010), Dale (2010) and Joyce et al. (2011), among others, have discussed the operational details of large‐scale asset purchases by the Bank of England and analysed various aspects of the impact of these unconventional monetary measures. Meier (2009) used an event studies approach to assess the impact of QE announcements and suggests long‐term government bond yields declined between 40 and 100 basis points following the initial QE announcement by the Bank of England in March 2009. Joyce et al. (2011) provide a more comprehensive assessment using event studies and portfolio balance models. In this framework, it is assumed that gilts and money are imperfectly substitutable assets and a multiplier calculated from a Markowitz–Tobin portfolio choice‐type model (Markowitz, 1952) determines the effects of changes in the quantity of gilts on excess asset returns in a portfolio with money, equities, corporate bonds and gilts.5 They suggest that QE lowered long‐term gilt yields by about 100 basis points and that most of the decline was generated by portfolio balance effects. There are far fewer studies that try to estimate the macroeconomic effects of unconventional monetary policy measures. One of the first in the current crisis was by Lenza et al. (2010), who conduct a comprehensive review of the European Central Bank's use of non‐standard monetary instruments in response to the crisis. The ECB embarked on an ‘enhanced credit support’ programme (Trichet, 2009), focused on market liquidity, from mid‐2009 to mid‐2010 in addition to a multitude of other measures intended to enhance market functioning introduced at the onset of the crisis. Lenza et al. (2010) provide evidence, based on a counterfactual analysis using a large BVAR model, that these measures were successful in reducing financial market dysfunction given the noticeable contraction in money market spreads. They also find that these measures had a positive effect on output and inflation but with a lag. Another VAR‐based study by Baumeister and Benati (2010) provides evidence of a significant macroeconomic impact in the US, UK and the euro area due to the observed decrease in long‐term bond spreads following asset purchases. The impact of the Fed's LSAPs on the US macroeconomy is also covered in Chung et al. (2012), who find that the LSAPs were successful. In particular, simulations from the Fed's FRB/US macroeconomic model suggest that asset purchases prevented deflation in the US and reduced the rate of unemployment. The authors suggest that the boost to the level of real GDP was about 3%, inflation was 1% higher and that the unemployment rate was reduced by 1.5% points compared with what it would otherwise have been. The theoretical underpinnings for expecting changes in asset quantities to affect yields are provided in Vayanos and Vila (2009), who develop a model based on investors with preferred habitats (Greenwood and Vayanos, 2008, offer empirical evidence in support of the model's predictions).6 However, in most conventional New Keynesian models, QE has no wider economic effects, unless it changes agents’ expectations about the future path of interest rates through the signalling channel. Eggertsson and Woodford (2003) argue that there are no portfolio balance effects in these models because the reduction in private sector portfolio risks resulting from central bank asset purchases is offset by a corresponding increase in the riskiness of public sector portfolio due to the inherent uncertainty of future taxes and spending, making QE purchases irrelevant through this channel. However, the literature incorporating the use of unconventional monetary policies into theoretical macroeconomic models is steadily evolving. In more recent work, Curdia and Woodford (2009) suggest that there can be some role for credit easing, which involves changing the composition of assets on a central bank's balance sheet but not for QE, which would still be ineffective at the ZLB.7 But when financial frictions or incomplete markets are coupled with imperfect asset substitutability, changing the maturity structure of assets can also affect asset prices. A useful starting point is the inclusion of Tobin's idea of imperfect asset substitutability in standard New Keynesian models. For example, Andrés et al. (2004) and Harrison (2012) develop microfoundations for preferred‐habitats and portfolio balance effects which is supportive of a role for QE within a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) framework. In general, to explain the macroeconomic effects of QE and other unconventional monetary policies fully, the (modified) DSGE model must capture the frictions that generate interest rate spreads and linkages between interest rate spreads and the real economy. An insightful overview of related issues in this emerging literature is found in, for example, Christiano (2011). 3. Econometric Framework In this Section, we describe the econometric models used in this article. 3.1. Bayesian VAR (BVAR) The seminal work by Sims (1980) introduced the use of VAR into macroeconometric modelling and VAR models continue to occupy centre stage. In this article, we use Bayesian methods to estimate them. Specifically, we estimate a large BVAR model similar to the model employed by Lenza et al. (2010) As our analysis involves a large data set, BVAR models are useful to overcome parametrisation problems which would otherwise be encountered when a standard VAR is estimated in large dimensions. The BVAR model allows us to use a priori information to restrict the parameter space. Our approach of applying prior information to a standard VAR model can be motivated from both a Bayesian and a classical perspective. We view the use of Bayesian technology as desirable mainly on pragmatic rather than philosophical grounds. 3.1.1. Notation and preliminaries The model belongs to the general class of BVAR models for large data sets.8 Assuming that all the variables in the large data set are in the vector Yt, we can write the model as follows: (1) where et is a vector white‐noise error term, Θ0 is a vector of constants and Θ1 to Θp are parameter matrices. 3.1.2. A normal‐inverted Wishart AR(1) prior As will be discussed later, our large data set comprises macroeconomic and financial market variables. A good prior for BVAR models of the macroeconomy is a simple random walk forecast; see, for example, Litterman (1986). Many macroeconomic and financial market variables are characterised by persistent processes. In general, simple autoregressive (AR) or random walk (RW) models are known to produce reasonable forecasts for macroeconomic and financial variables (over short horizons). We therefore choose a univariate AR(1) process with high persistence as our prior for each of the variables in the BVAR model. With this prior, the ‘own’ first lag is considered to be the most important in every equation in the BVAR. Specifically, the expected value of the matrix Θ1 is E(Θ1) = 0.99 × I. We assume that Θ1 is conditionally (on Σ) normal, with first and second moments given by (2) where denotes the element in position (i,j) in the matrix Θ1, and where the covariances among the coefficients in Θ1 are zero. The shrinkage parameter φ determines the tightness of the prior or the extent to which the data influence the estimates. With a tight prior, the data have little or no influence on the estimates as φ → 0. For a loose prior, where φ → ∞ there is an increasing role for the data and the estimates then converge to the standard OLS estimates. To complete the specification of our BVAR prior, we assume that the constant, Θ0, has a diffuse normal prior and the matrix of disturbances has an inverted Wishart prior, . v0 and S0 are the prior scale and shape parameters with the expectation of Σ equal to a fixed diagonal residual variance . This is a conjugate prior with a normal‐inverted Wishart posterior distribution. The BVAR model is estimated using rolling windows to account for structural change. Additional technical information on model estimation and prior tightness is provided in Appendix A. 3.2. Change‐point SVAR (MS‐SVAR) Our consideration of regime changes is motivated by the fact that since the early 1970s, the UK monetary policy regime has changed a number of times. Since how agents form their expectations will have changed under different monetary policy reaction functions, macroeconomic dynamics over this period cannot be easily described by deep parameters of a single structural model. Since the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in the early 1970s, we might loosely identify four successive monetary policy regimes in the UK. These are monetary targeting (not explicitly introduced until 1979 but monetary aggregates were monitored from the mid‐1970s), an informal exchange rate targeting regime in the late‐1980s and membership of the exchange rate mechanism (ERM) from 1990–2, inflation targeting after 1992 and more recently inflation targeting in a ZLB environment with the use of unconventional monetary policy instruments.9 The use of four different structural models might help us to understand agents’ actions inside these regimes but it would not be able to capture agents’ expectations that the policy regime might change in the future. The following MS‐SVAR model allows us to model (in a reduced‐form manner) changes in the policymaker's reaction function and to study how aggregate dynamics have been affected. (3) where the data vector Yt contains monthly data on the three‐month Treasury bill (Rt), the 10‐year government bond yield spread (St) (defined as the 10‐year government bond yield minus the three‐month Treasury bill rate), annual GDP growth (yt), annual CPI inflation (πt), annual M4 growth (Mt) and the annual change in stock prices (SPt); Bj,S and A0,S are regime‐dependent autoregressive coefficients and structural shock loading matrices respectively. As explained in Chib (1998), the dates of (say, M) regime breaks in the model are unknown and they are modelled via the latent state variable S, which is assumed to follow an (M‐state) Markov chain process with restricted transition probabilities given by (4) For example, if M = 4 the transition matrix is defined as Equations (3) and (4) define a Markov‐switching VAR with non‐recurrent states where transitions are allowed in a sequential manner. For example, to move from Regime 1 to Regime 3, the process has to visit Regime 2. Similarly, transitions to past regimes are not allowed. This imposed structure (which is not necessarily more restrictive than a standard Markov‐switching model) implies that any new regimes are given a new label (rather than being explicitly linked to past states as in a standard Markov‐switching model) and this allows us to isolate periods of interest (such as the current period) and tailor our shock identification scheme accordingly. 3.2.1. Identification of structural shocks In this model, we identify four structural shocks: a monetary policy shock, a demand shock, a supply shock and a shock to the yield spread. Following Baumeister and Benati (2010), these shocks are identified using a combination of sign and zero type restrictions; see Table 1. Table 1 Sign Restrictions – MS‐SVAR Model Shocks∖Variables . Rt . St . Yt . πt . Mt . SPt . Monetary policy ≥ ≤ ≤ ≤ ? ? Spread 0 ≥ ≤ ≤ ? ? Demand ≥ ? ≥ ≥ ≥ ≥ Supply ? ? ≤ ≥ ? ? Shocks∖Variables . Rt . St . Yt . πt . Mt . SPt . Monetary policy ≥ ≤ ≤ ≤ ? ? Spread 0 ≥ ≤ ≤ ? ? Demand ≥ ? ≥ ≥ ≥ ≥ Supply ? ? ≤ ≥ ? ? Notes. For variable definitions see discussion of (3). Open in new tab Table 1 Sign Restrictions – MS‐SVAR Model Shocks∖Variables . Rt . St . Yt . πt . Mt . SPt . Monetary policy ≥ ≤ ≤ ≤ ? ? Spread 0 ≥ ≤ ≤ ? ? Demand ≥ ? ≥ ≥ ≥ ≥ Supply ? ? ≤ ≥ ? ? Shocks∖Variables . Rt . St . Yt . πt . Mt . SPt . Monetary policy ≥ ≤ ≤ ≤ ? ? Spread 0 ≥ ≤ ≤ ? ? Demand ≥ ? ≥ ≥ ≥ ≥ Supply ? ? ≤ ≥ ? ? Notes. For variable definitions see discussion of (3). Open in new tab We impose standard sign restrictions for the monetary policy, demand and supply shocks. A positive monetary policy shock, which increases the short‐term rate, will lead to a compression in the yield spread, lower GDP growth rate and lower inflation. A positive demand shock will lead to higher inflation and output, short‐term interest rates, money growth and stock prices, whereas a negative supply shock will lead to higher inflation and lower output growth. On the other hand, a negative shock to the yield spread is assumed to have zero contemporaneous impact on the short‐term interest rate but leads to lower inflation and output growth. The MS‐SVAR not only accounts for different policy regimes but we are also able to examine the effects of the policymaker's inability to change the interest rates to stimulate demand, as under the ZLB. We only do this in the most recent regime by imposing the prior assumption that the policy rate does not depend on other lagged endogenous variables. We show below that our benchmark model estimate of Regime 4 roughly coincides with the 2007–9 financial crisis (Figure 1). Fig. 1. Open in new tabDownload slide Regime Estimation for the MS‐SVAR Model Fig. 1. Open in new tabDownload slide Regime Estimation for the MS‐SVAR Model 3.3. Time‐varying Parameter SVAR (TVP‐SVAR) Another model that captures policy regime changes is the following TVP‐SVAR: (5) where Yt contains quarterly data on the three‐month Treasury bill (Rt), the 10‐year government bond yield spread (St) (defined as the 10‐year government bond yield minus the three‐month Treasury bill rate), annual GDP growth (yt) and annual CPI inflation (πt). The law of motion for the coefficients is given by (6) where . As in Cogley and Sargent (2005), the covariance matrix of the innovations vt is factored as (7) The time‐varying matrices Ht and At are defined as (8) with the hi,t evolving as geometric random walks, Following Primiceri (2005), we postulate the non‐zero and non‐one elements of the matrix At to evolve as driftless random walks, (9) We assume the vector to be distributed as (10) The TVP‐SVAR model can be written compactly as (11) where , , , where P is an orthonormal matrix (PP′ = I) that satisfies the zero‐sign restrictions shown in Table 2. Table 2 Sign Restrictions – TVP‐SVAR Model Shocks∖Variables . Rt . St . Yt . πt . Monetary policy shock ≥ ≤ ≤ ≤ Spread shock 0 ≥ ≤ ≤ Demand shock ≥ ? ≥ ≥ Supply shock ? ? ≤ ≥ Shocks∖Variables . Rt . St . Yt . πt . Monetary policy shock ≥ ≤ ≤ ≤ Spread shock 0 ≥ ≤ ≤ Demand shock ≥ ? ≥ ≥ Supply shock ? ? ≤ ≥ Notes. For variable definitions, see discussion of (5). Open in new tab Table 2 Sign Restrictions – TVP‐SVAR Model Shocks∖Variables . Rt . St . Yt . πt . Monetary policy shock ≥ ≤ ≤ ≤ Spread shock 0 ≥ ≤ ≤ Demand shock ≥ ? ≥ ≥ Supply shock ? ? ≤ ≥ Shocks∖Variables . Rt . St . Yt . πt . Monetary policy shock ≥ ≤ ≤ ≤ Spread shock 0 ≥ ≤ ≤ Demand shock ≥ ? ≥ ≥ Supply shock ? ? ≤ ≥ Notes. For variable definitions, see discussion of (5). Open in new tab This model is substantially more flexible than the one discussed in the previous Section. It is not only consistent with variation in the policy rule but also consistent with deviations from the rational expectations hypothesis. In this framework, agents do not know the structural parameters and they use simple forecasting models to form their projections about future variables and, consequently, learn about the structure of the economy. This model seems very plausible during crisis periods where agents have no idea how shocks have changed the structure of the economy and they use simple ‘rules of thumb’ to learn about the new state. During the financial crisis, policy makers had to employ non‐standard policy tools and, arguably, it makes sense for agents to ‘abandon’ the rational expectation hypothesis and use simple forecasting rules to learn about the structure of the economy, at least for a short period. If agents behave this way, we need to allow the parameters to vary over time as in the TVP‐SVAR model to assess the effects of QE. 3.3.1. Identification of structural shocks The shock identification scheme used for this model is identical to the one discussed in Section 3.2.1. The only difference is that two sets of restrictions have been dropped (those associated with the M4 and Stock Prices series) because the dimension of the VAR in this case has been reduced from six to four variables for reasons of tractability. Table 2 reports these restrictions. 4. Data Our data set for the large BVAR comprises 43 variables, with monthly observations covering April 1993 to September 2010. UK variables include those capturing real activity, prices, money, the yield curve and financial markets.10 Given that QE is expected to affect monetary aggregates and interest rates directly, the bulk of the domestic variables are interest rates, interest rate spreads and monetary aggregates. To incorporate potential international financial and economic linkages, we also include data for real activity, prices and the policy rates for the US and the euro area. We use log‐levels for the variables except those which are already in growth rates. The list of variables are provided in Appendix Table A.1. The SVAR models were estimated using monthly and quarterly data on a smaller set of variables covering a longer period, from 1963–2011. The MS‐SVAR uses monthly data, from February 1963 to March 2011, for the three‐month Treasury bill rate, the 10‐year government bond yield spread (defined as the 10‐year government bond yield minus the three‐month Treasury bill), annualised GDP growth, annualised CPI inflation, annualised M4 growth and the annual change in the FTSE All‐Share index (stock prices). For the TVP‐SVAR model, we use quarterly data, from 1968 Q1–2011 Q1,11 for the three‐month Treasury bill rate, the 10‐year government bond yield spread (defined as the 10‐year government bond yield minus the three‐month Treasury bill rate), annualised GDP growth and annualised CPI inflation. 5. Counterfactual Assumptions Our counterfactual analysis is based on the empirical findings in Joyce et al. (2011), which suggest that QE may have depressed medium to long‐term government bond yields (average 5 to 25‐year spot rates) by about 100 basis points. We implement this impact on yields by changing the government bond spread, the spread between the relevant long‐maturity bond yield in each model and the three‐month Treasury bill rate. The resulting counterfactual simulations are conditional forecasts for real GDP and CPI inflation. We examine two scenarios: a policy scenario and a no policy scenario. Under the policy scenario, which we describe as our baseline model prediction, we produce a counterfactual forecast taking the actual levels of long‐term government bond spreads and Bank Rate that were observed from March 2009 to the end of our forecast horizon as our conditioning assumptions. We do not take the outturns for real GDP and CPI inflation as our baseline because the changes in these variables may also be due to changes in other factors that are not captured in the model. This means that we are only identifying the assumed impact of QE on the growth and inflation profiles, and disregarding all the other forces pushing up on demand. Consequently, the actual recovery may be higher than our model prediction, which does not capture these shocks. For the no policy scenario, we assume that long‐term government bond spreads would have been 100 basis points higher over the period from March 2009 onwards had QE not been implemented.12 We also consider an alternative no policy scenario, where we adjust government bond spreads by 100 basis points and fix Bank Rate at 0.5%. We describe the two no policy scenarios as Bank Rate endogenous and Bank Rate exogenous. To approximate the macroeconomic impact of QE, we compare the conditional forecasts for real GDP and CPI inflation under the policy scenario with those for the no policy scenario and take the difference between the two as our estimate. We are therefore using the change in the slope of the yield curve as our sole metric to determine the effects of QE on the macroeconomy. Lenza et al. (2010) and Baumeister and Benati (2010) use a similar approach to examine the effects of unconventional monetary policy on the macroeconomy. We do not examine the effects of other QE transmission channels. Implicit in our approach is the assumption that QE operates through expectations and that markets price in the total amount of asset purchases expected by the MPC. As noted, £75 billion of asset purchases were announced in March 2009, and this was extended to a total of £125 billion in May 2009, to a total of £175 billion in August 2009 and to a total of £200 billion in November 2009. However, evidence from event study analysis suggests that by far the largest reaction in gilt yields occured around March 2009 (Joyce et al., 2011). In the BVAR model, we focus on the 5 and 10‐year government bond yield spreads to assess the potential macroeconomic effects of QE, so the adjustments for the no QE counterfactual are applied to these spreads. For the smaller SVAR models, we apply the spread adjustment to the 10‐year government bond spread. 6. Empirical Results 6.1. Results from BVAR Model We set the lag order for our large BVAR model equal to one. For a model of this size, standard information criteria are difficult to use, so we rely on serial correlation tests on the residuals to arrive at the lag order. The residuals seemed to be well behaved, with little evidence of residual serial correlation. We set the tightness parameter following the approach used in Lenza et al. (2010). So the tightness parameter for the reported results ensures that the standard deviation of the residuals of the Bank Rate equation in the large BVAR is equivalent to those for the Bank Rate equation in a ‘small’ VAR. We choose 12 variables for the ‘small’ VAR, including both UK variables and foreign variables, to mimic the dynamics of a central bank monetary policy rule. The ‘small VAR’ is therefore used to pin down the prior for the BVAR. We estimate the model using a rolling estimation approach and only use data from August 2007 to September 2010 to conduct our counterfactual analysis. For these simulations, we assume that under the two no policy scenarios, the 100‐basis‐point increase in long‐term government bond yields (which is implemented through a rise in the 5 and 10‐year gilt yield spread to the three‐month Treasury bill rate) occurs in the initial period and yields remain at 100 basis points higher over the forecast horizon. We also conduct some sensitivity analysis by looking at the effects of a 80‐basis‐point and a 120‐basis‐point increase in spreads under the no policy scenario. We also vary the persistence of the QE shock by allowing the size of the adjustment on government bond spreads to vary over the forecast horizon. Figure 2 illustrates the estimated effects of QE on real GDP and inflation using the Bank Rate endogenous scenario (a) and the Bank Rate exogenous scenario (b). As with any VAR model, the forecasts become less informative as the forecast horizon lengthens, as our focus is on the effects of QE, the counterfactual forecasts for GDP and CPI inflation are shown for the period that they lie below the baseline forecast which is typically around a year. Fig. 2. Open in new tabDownload slide BVAR Counterfactual Analysis Fig. 2. Open in new tabDownload slide BVAR Counterfactual Analysis From the results, it appears that the decrease in long‐term government bond spreads supported the level of real GDP during 2009 and prevented CPI inflation from becoming very low or negative. From Figure 2 (a), the Bank Rate endogenous scenario, leads to a maximum decrease of real GDP of about 0.7% in September 2009. In the Bank Rate exogenous scenario (Figure 2b), we observe a maximum fall of about 0.3% in the level real GDP in November 2009. The effects of QE on output are therefore more pronounced in the Bank Rate endogenous scenario compared with the Bank Rate exogenous scenario. This result is somewhat puzzling, as we would expect to see a larger effect in the case where the Bank Rate is fixed. This is perhaps a consequence of the fact that BVAR imposes little economic structure on the data. The effects on inflation are very similar across the two scenarios, however, with QE having a maximum effect of about 1% point on CPI inflation. The peak impact occurs in March 2010 for both scenarios. So our evidence for the effects of QE on real GDP would suggest that the maximum effect occurs after about six to nine months, while the maximum effect on inflation occurs after about a year. These are the maximum effects of QE. As noted previously, these are estimated by comparing the no policy scenario with the policy scenario which is a forecast conditional on the actual paths of the relevant interest rate spreads and the actual path for Bank Rate over the forecast horizon. The effects would be larger if the counterfactual were defined as the no policy scenario relative to the actual data, as the model underpredicts output and inflation over the period. We also considered a number of other adjustments for the no policy scenario, as shown in Table 3. This included examining the effects of larger and smaller changes in spreads but, as the shock is linear in the spreads, the effects are simply proportional to the 100‐basis‐point adjustment. To assess the persistence of the shock, we considered an alternative adjustment profile for sensitivity analysis, which we call less persistence in Figure 2. In this case, instead of assuming the effects on the government bond spread are constant, we assume that without QE there would have been a 60‐basis‐point increase in spreads in the first three months, a 100‐basis‐point increase for the next seven months and then a gradual decline of about 11‐basis‐points each month over the rest of the horizon.13 Unsurprisingly this resulted in slightly smaller effects. But, overall, the results under these various alternative spread adjustment profiles were broadly similar to our central case.14 Table 3 Maximum Effects of QE: Large BVAR Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . Real GDP level . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 0.82pp 0.85pp 0.61% 0.23% 100bp 1.03pp 1.07pp 0.72% 0.28% 120bp 1.24pp 1.28pp 0.83% 0.34% Less persistence 0.96pp 0.94pp 0.65% 0.26% Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . Real GDP level . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 0.82pp 0.85pp 0.61% 0.23% 100bp 1.03pp 1.07pp 0.72% 0.28% 120bp 1.24pp 1.28pp 0.83% 0.34% Less persistence 0.96pp 0.94pp 0.65% 0.26% Notes. BR is abbreviation for Bank Rate. The BR endogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on only the adjusted government bond spreads. The BR exogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on the adjusted government bond spreads and Bank Rate. Open in new tab Table 3 Maximum Effects of QE: Large BVAR Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . Real GDP level . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 0.82pp 0.85pp 0.61% 0.23% 100bp 1.03pp 1.07pp 0.72% 0.28% 120bp 1.24pp 1.28pp 0.83% 0.34% Less persistence 0.96pp 0.94pp 0.65% 0.26% Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . Real GDP level . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 0.82pp 0.85pp 0.61% 0.23% 100bp 1.03pp 1.07pp 0.72% 0.28% 120bp 1.24pp 1.28pp 0.83% 0.34% Less persistence 0.96pp 0.94pp 0.65% 0.26% Notes. BR is abbreviation for Bank Rate. The BR endogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on only the adjusted government bond spreads. The BR exogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on the adjusted government bond spreads and Bank Rate. Open in new tab 6.2. Results from MS‐SVAR Model For this model, the number of the regimes is decided before the model is estimated. This selection can be based on data‐driven techniques – such as the marginal likelihood criterion (Chib, 1998) – or, as in this case, by prior knowledge. As noted previously, Figure 1 shows the estimated regime pattern. We listed four monetary policy regimes in the post‐Bretton Woods era in Section 3.2. The first regime identified by the model ended in the early 1980s, which, although covering a period when different regimes may have operated, roughly coincides with the end of monetary targeting in the UK. The second regime ended in the early 1990s, a period when the UK left the Exchange Rate Mechanism and started inflation targeting. The end of the third regime is around the outset of the recent financial crisis. 6.2.1. Counterfactual scenario by imposing alternative spread paths This exercise is identical to the exercise in Section 6.1.Figure 3 plots the results from this experiment, where we focus on the effects of QE over the period until the no policy conditional forecasts return to the baseline. Similarly, the outcomes are grouped into two categories: Bank Rate endogenous and Bank Rate exogenous. The Bank Rate endogenous estimate (Figure 3a) is the forecast for output growth and CPI inflation conditional on the adjusted government bond spread, under the no policy scenario. For the Bank Rate exogenous estimate, the forecast is conditional on the adjusted government bond spread and three‐month Treasury bill rate (the proxy for Bank Rate in this model) fixed at 0.5% over the entire forecast period (Figure 3b). Fig. 3. Open in new tabDownload slide Conditional Forecasts, MS‐SVAR: GDP Growth and Inflation Fig. 3. Open in new tabDownload slide Conditional Forecasts, MS‐SVAR: GDP Growth and Inflation Table 4 reports the peak effects on GDP growth and CPI inflation from these simulations. For a 100‐basis‐point contraction in spreads, the maximum impact on inflation and GDP growth occurs in April 2009 using the Bank Rate endogenous estimate and in March 2010 for the Bank Rate exogenous estimate. The large initial impact of the stimulus, using the Bank Rate endogenous estimate, occurs because in subsequent periods the unconstrained policy rate declines in response to lower inflation and output. The results for the less persistent case suggest that a staggered impact on spreads produces smaller effects compared with the standard case, where we assume there is a 100‐basis‐point increase in every period over the forecast horizon, especially for the case where Bank Rate is treated as endogenous. The MS‐SVAR suggests that if we assumed the effects of QE on spreads were less persistent, the impact on output growth and CPI inflation would be smaller. These effects are more marked than in the case of the BVAR. Table 4 Maximum Effects of QE: MS‐SVAR Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP growth . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 1.03pp 3.01pp 2.14pp 3.68pp 100bp 1.31pp 3.38pp 2.72pp 4.08pp 120bp 1.59pp 3.79pp 3.29pp 4.45pp Less persistence 0.75pp 3.11pp 1.57pp 3.96pp Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP growth . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 1.03pp 3.01pp 2.14pp 3.68pp 100bp 1.31pp 3.38pp 2.72pp 4.08pp 120bp 1.59pp 3.79pp 3.29pp 4.45pp Less persistence 0.75pp 3.11pp 1.57pp 3.96pp Notes. BR is abbreviation for Bank Rate. The BR endogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on only the adjusted government bond spreads. The BR exogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on the adjusted government bond spreads and Bank Rate. Open in new tab Table 4 Maximum Effects of QE: MS‐SVAR Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP growth . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 1.03pp 3.01pp 2.14pp 3.68pp 100bp 1.31pp 3.38pp 2.72pp 4.08pp 120bp 1.59pp 3.79pp 3.29pp 4.45pp Less persistence 0.75pp 3.11pp 1.57pp 3.96pp Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP growth . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 1.03pp 3.01pp 2.14pp 3.68pp 100bp 1.31pp 3.38pp 2.72pp 4.08pp 120bp 1.59pp 3.79pp 3.29pp 4.45pp Less persistence 0.75pp 3.11pp 1.57pp 3.96pp Notes. BR is abbreviation for Bank Rate. The BR endogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on only the adjusted government bond spreads. The BR exogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on the adjusted government bond spreads and Bank Rate. Open in new tab In the scenario where Bank Rate is exogenous, the effects on output and inflation are larger and inflation would have gone into negative territory. This means that without an additional policy instrument to affect expectations about demand, the economy would suffer from deflation and positive real interest rates which would depress demand even further (people expect inflation to fall, meaning consumption and investment goods are going to be cheaper in the future and, therefore, they postpone consumption and investment into the future). Uncertainty about states of the world is another mechanism that can squeeze demand. For instance, in periods of major financial crises, agents are particularly uncertain about the future, and to offset high‐consumption variations (due to, say, the possibility of being unemployed) or/and to avoid big capital losses (from firms going bust), they increase their precautionary saving, which squeezes current demand. 6.2.2. Impulse responses from MS‐SVAR model The structural identification scheme allows us to examine the evolution of the variables in the different regimes following a particular shock. Focusing on the responses after a shock to government bond spreads (the ‘spread’ shock), Figure 4 shows that this shock has significantly larger effects in the recent regime. For example, the effect of the shock (a 100‐basis‐point decrease in spreads) on GDP growth increases from about 0.6% in Regime 3 to about 2% in Regime 4.15 Fig. 4. Open in new tabDownload slide Responses After a Spread Shock in MS‐SVAR Fig. 4. Open in new tabDownload slide Responses After a Spread Shock in MS‐SVAR 6.3. Results from TVP‐SVAR Model 6.3.1. Counterfactual scenario by imposing alternative spread paths Figure 5 and Table 5 show the results from the TVP‐SVAR model. We focus on the effects of QE over the period until the no policy conditional forecasts return to the baseline. For a 100‐basis‐point contraction in spreads, the maximum effects on inflation and output growth occur in 2009 Q4 for the Bank Rate endogenous scenario and in 2010 Q1 for the Bank Rate exogenous scenario, i.e. three to four quarters after the start of QE. However, the model prediction is hugely pessimistic relative to the data outturns. The poor forecasting power of the TVP‐SVAR may be due to how agents learn about the evolution or structure of the economy. For example, if we consider the TVP‐SVAR as the reduced‐form version of a structural model where agents use simple forecasting rules to learn about the structure of the economy, then the results from these conditional forecasts would suggest that the agents in this model learn very slowly.16 As the initial point of the forecast is in a downturn, agents seem to remain pessimistic for a long period despite the stimulus from QE. Fig. 5. Open in new tabDownload slide Conditional Forecasts, TVP‐SVAR: GDP Growth and Inflation Fig. 5. Open in new tabDownload slide Conditional Forecasts, TVP‐SVAR: GDP Growth and Inflation Table 5 Maximum Effects of QE: TVP‐SVAR Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP growth . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 0.87pp 3.20pp 0.56pp 2.64pp 100bp 1.30pp 3.63pp 0.86pp 2.98pp 120bp 1.71pp 4.09pp 1.15pp 3.29pp Less persistence 0.87pp 3.42pp 0.56pp 2.82pp Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP growth . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 0.87pp 3.20pp 0.56pp 2.64pp 100bp 1.30pp 3.63pp 0.86pp 2.98pp 120bp 1.71pp 4.09pp 1.15pp 3.29pp Less persistence 0.87pp 3.42pp 0.56pp 2.82pp Notes. BR is abbreviation for Bank Rate. The BR endogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on only the adjusted government bond spreads. The BR exogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on the adjusted government bond spreads and Bank Rate. Open in new tab Table 5 Maximum Effects of QE: TVP‐SVAR Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP growth . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 0.87pp 3.20pp 0.56pp 2.64pp 100bp 1.30pp 3.63pp 0.86pp 2.98pp 120bp 1.71pp 4.09pp 1.15pp 3.29pp Less persistence 0.87pp 3.42pp 0.56pp 2.82pp Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP growth . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . 80bp 0.87pp 3.20pp 0.56pp 2.64pp 100bp 1.30pp 3.63pp 0.86pp 2.98pp 120bp 1.71pp 4.09pp 1.15pp 3.29pp Less persistence 0.87pp 3.42pp 0.56pp 2.82pp Notes. BR is abbreviation for Bank Rate. The BR endogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on only the adjusted government bond spreads. The BR exogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on the adjusted government bond spreads and Bank Rate. Open in new tab The forecast performance not withstanding, we can still evaluate the effects of QE using the TVP‐SVAR model. Using the Bank Rate endogenous scenario, the effects of QE are large and persistent reflecting agents’ pessimism about the economic outlook. For the Bank Rate exogenous scenario, the effects of QE are much larger. This is similar to the MS‐SVAR and may be due to the fact that when the policy rate is exogenised, recovery can only be achieved by lowering spreads. In the case with less persistence of the QE shock, the TVP‐SVAR suggests that the effects on output and CPI inflation would be commensurately smaller, broadly in line with findings for the MS‐SVAR. 7. Summary of Empirical Results Table 6 provides a summary of the key results from all three models employed in this article, showing the peak effects of a 100‐basis‐point QE shock from the counterfactual simulations. However, these effects occur at different times across the three models. Although the models are strictly not directly comparable due to their different dynamic structures and their informational content,17 they jointly illustrate the range of potential macroeconomic impacts of QE. Table 6 Summary Table: Maximum Effect of QE (100‐Basis‐Point Contraction in Spreads) Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP level . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BVAR 1.03pp 1.07pp 0.72% 0.28% MS‐SVAR 1.31pp 3.38pp 2.75% 5.13% TVP‐SVAR 1.30pp 3.63pp 0.86% 5.36% Model average* 1.21pp 2.60pp 1.42% 3.59% Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP level . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BVAR 1.03pp 1.07pp 0.72% 0.28% MS‐SVAR 1.31pp 3.38pp 2.75% 5.13% TVP‐SVAR 1.30pp 3.63pp 0.86% 5.36% Model average* 1.21pp 2.60pp 1.42% 3.59% Notes. Model averaging done with an equally weighted probability. BR is abbreviation for Bank Rate. The BR endogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on only the adjusted government bond spreads. The BR exogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on the adjusted government bond spreads and Bank Rate. Open in new tab Table 6 Summary Table: Maximum Effect of QE (100‐Basis‐Point Contraction in Spreads) Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP level . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BVAR 1.03pp 1.07pp 0.72% 0.28% MS‐SVAR 1.31pp 3.38pp 2.75% 5.13% TVP‐SVAR 1.30pp 3.63pp 0.86% 5.36% Model average* 1.21pp 2.60pp 1.42% 3.59% Adjustment∖Estimate . CPI inflation . GDP level . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BR endogenous . BR exogenous . BVAR 1.03pp 1.07pp 0.72% 0.28% MS‐SVAR 1.31pp 3.38pp 2.75% 5.13% TVP‐SVAR 1.30pp 3.63pp 0.86% 5.36% Model average* 1.21pp 2.60pp 1.42% 3.59% Notes. Model averaging done with an equally weighted probability. BR is abbreviation for Bank Rate. The BR endogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on only the adjusted government bond spreads. The BR exogenous scenario is the forecast conditional on the adjusted government bond spreads and Bank Rate. Open in new tab The final row of the Table illustrates the effects implied by averaging across the models on the basis of an equally weighted probability for inflation and GDP.18 The average model prediction indicates that, without the 100‐basis‐point contraction in government bond spreads following the implementation of QE, output would have been between 1.4% and 3.6% lower while CPI inflation would have been reduced by between 1.2% and 2.6% points relative to the baseline model prediction. The range of these estimates reflects the different assumptions made about the policy rate in the two counterfactual simulations. Making Bank Rate exogenous produces a much larger range of results across the models. We put more emphasis on the more conservative model average results, the Bank Rate endogenous scenario. Our preferred average estimates from the three models therefore suggest that QE may have had a peak effect on the level of real GDP of around % and a peak effect on annual CPI inflation of about points. Clearly, there is considerable uncertainty around all of the estimates, which increase as the forecast horizon lengthens. These results should be viewed as an attempt to quantify the macroeconomic effects of a 100‐basis‐point reduction in long‐term interest rates. Of course, as noted earlier, QE may have affected the real economy in a variety of other ways and not just through its effect on long rates (through confidence effects) but we have not investigated the impact of these other possible transmission channels in this article. 8. Some Caveats We have noted a number of caveats to our analysis. We summarise these caveats in this Section and provide some suggestions for further research. We do not identify how QE is transmitted into the economy, through either portfolio balance or/and inflation expectations or other channels. However, we believe that this does not alter our inference as we focus mainly on the reduced‐form impact from a fall in spreads on output and inflation.19 Although, the models used in this study are variants of VAR models that capture different aspects of the evolution in macroeconomic variables, arguably, a structural DSGE‐type model could potentially provide some further useful insights. However, as discussed previously, it is not immediately clear either what such a model would be or how well it would fit the data. Research on DSGE‐type models for QE is ongoing. Our econometric models might be a useful way to take such models to the data. Also, any form of counterfactual exercise is uncertain, particularly so in this case given the relative uniqueness of QE and the economic conditions in which it took place. We have also chosen to consider only models that account for structural change associated with parameter time‐variation so as to minimise any biases arising from not accounting for structural change. A by‐product of this choice is the likelihood that the estimates of the effects of QE are more uncertain than would otherwise be the case. However, as we have argued before, taking potential structural changes into account is extremely important for the validity of reduced‐form modelling of QE.20 Focusing our discussion on experiments where spreads fall by 100 basis points might seem restrictive. However, we do consider alternative scenarios, which deliver reasonably similar conclusions. A related issue is the possibility that QE may have influenced other variables in our models but we only condition on the spread and may miss contemporaneous shocks to those variables from QE. However, Pesaran and Smith (2012) present an autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) model of GDP growth and bond spreads and undertake a counterfactual exercise which indicates that the effect of a 100‐basis‐point reduction in spreads has similar positive effects to GDP as those we find in the current article. As the model of Pesaran and Smith does not contain any other variables, there is no ambiguity as to the appropriate conditioning assumptions that define the counterfactual exercise. As a consequence, we consider the results of Pesaran and Smith (2012) to be a useful, relevant and positive robustness check on the results presented in this article. Finally, the usual caveats concerning the econometric specification, estimation and validation of our models apply. However, our use of state of the art econometric techniques hopefully minimise the effects of such issues. 9. Conclusion In this article, we provide new results on the potential macroeconomic effects of the Bank of England's QE programme during March 2009 to January 2010. We employ a multiple models approach, using three different time‐series models. Results from a large BVAR model suggest that without QE real GDP would have fallen by even more during 2009 and inflation would have reached low or even negative levels. Results obtained from analysis using an MS‐SVAR model and a TVP‐SVAR model broadly support those obtained from the BVAR, if anything suggesting that the impact might have been even larger. Overall, our analysis would suggest that QE was an effective policy option during the financial crisis. However, the magnitude of its effects varies considerably across the different model specifications, and with the precise assumptions made to generate the counterfactual simulations, so these estimates are subject to considerable uncertainty. We have qualified our analysis by a number of caveats. First, it is clear that any form of counterfactual exercise is very uncertain, particularly so in this case given the relative uniqueness of QE and the economic conditions in which it took place. Second, we have chosen a set of models that, while different, are nevertheless related and, therefore, may provide similar answers, which are subject to some uncertainty because they account for structural change associated with parameter time variation. Third, we have exclusively focused on the link between government bond spreads and macroeconomic variables, ignoring other possible transmission channels. Despite these caveats, our multiple time‐series approach provide a useful benchmark for assessing the macroeconomic impact of QE. Footnotes 1 " Aït‐Sahalia et al. (2009) and Lenza et al. (2010), among others, provide a review of the various measures used by major central banks in response to the Great Financial Crisis of 2008. 2 " The analysis in the article is for the first round of asset purchases by the Bank of England. The Bank began a second round asset purchases in October 2011. 3 " A comprehensive review of the financial and macroeconomic effects of QE in Japan is provided by Ugai (2007). 4 " Other supportive evidence on the effects of the Fed's LSAPs programme is provided by Hamilton and Wu (2012) and Doh (2010). 5 " Others have also used portfolio balance models to estimate the impact of LSAPs. (for example, Kimura and Small, 2006) who suggested that QE in Japan had some positive portfolio balance effects and reduced risk premia on some assets. Neely (2010) used a portfolio balance model to examine the international effects of US LSAPs. 6 " Analysis of the effects of altering the maturity structure of government debt is not new. Informal analysis of the preferred‐habitat theory and empirical evidence on debt maturity structure are available in, for example, Modigliani and Sutch (1966, 1967). 7 " Christiano and Ikeda (2011) also consider the role of credit easing using theoretical models with financial frictions. ‘Credit easing’ in the US is described as the Fed's purchases of mortgage‐backed securities, which changed the composition of assets on the Fed's balance sheet. 8 " See, for example, Banbura et al. (2010). 9 " The Bank of England was given operational independence for monetary policy in 1997. However, the UK has had an inflation target since late 1992 and the Bank held joint meetings with the Treasury ahead of policy decisions by the Chancellor of the Exchequer. 10 " We obtain monthly GDP estimates from the National Institute of Economic and Social Research. These estimates are obtained from statistical projection and involve a fair amount of interpolation. Mitchell et al. (2005) discuss the methodology in detail. 11 " These data actually start from 1958 Q1 but we have used the first 10 years as a training sample to calibrate the priors. 12 " This type of conditioning assumption is similar to the ‘hard conditions’ discussed in Waggoner and Zha (1999). 13 " In subsequent months after the seven months increase of 100 basis points, the increase in spreads will be equivalent to a decline of about 6% in the previous month's increase in spreads. For example, the increase in spreads in the 11th month is equivalent to 100 basis points minus 100(1/9). These types of conditioning assumptions are similar to the ‘soft conditions’ described in Waggoner and Zha (1999). 14 " In addition, we also tried combining changes in yields with shocks to the money stock, with the aim of combining quantity and asset price effects. This is consistent with a standard portfolio balance approach; see Joyce et al. (2011). These results proved very sensitive to which monetary aggregate we assumed was affected by QE and they are not reported here. Further analysis of the effects of QE using a monetary approach is provided in another Bank of England Working Paper by Bridges and Thomas (2012). 15 " The responses have been normalised to make them comparable across different regimes. 16 " This is a standard feature of structural models with adaptive learning; see, for example, Evans and Honkapohja (2001). 17 " Although from Proposition 1 in Waggoner and Zha (1999) it is clear that the structural identification scheme plays no role in the conditional forecast, in this instance we could only loosely compare these models due to the different manner in which the reduced‐form dynamics are modelled. 18 " To enable model comparison, we convert the GDP growth effects obtained from the smaller models to an equivalent GDP level effect. 19 " We have exclusively focused on the link between government bond spreads and macroeconomic variables, ignoring other possible channels. However, the consideration of additional channels would have complicated substantially the construction of the counterfactual exercise and rendered it potentially more controversial. 20 " A related issue is the possibility that the estimated time variation in the parameters may reflect the impact of policy changes rather than structural change. This may occur, for example, if the VAR models omit important variables; see, for example, Benati and Surico (2009), for arguments along this line. Note, however, that our findings on the impact of QE are relatively similar across three time varying parameter models that range from parsimonious to large scale. This provides some evidence that the estimated time‐variation reflects underlying structural change. References Aït‐Sahalia , Y. , Andritzky , J.R, Jobst , A., Nowak , S.B. and Tamirisa , N.T. ( 2009 ). ‘How to stop a herd of running bears? Market response to policy initiatives during the global financial crisis’ , IMF Working Paper No. 09/204, International Monetary Fund. Andrés , J. , López‐Salido , J.D. and Nelson , E. ( 2004 ). ‘Tobin's imperfect asset substitution in optimizing general equilibrium’ , Journal of Money, Credit and Banking , vol. 36 , pp. 665 – 90 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Banbura , M. , Giannone , D. and Reichlin , L. ( 2010 ). ‘Large Bayesian vector auto regressions’ , Journal of Applied Econometrics , vol. 25 , pp. 71 – 92 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Baumeister , C. and Benati , L. ( 2010 ). ‘Unconventional monetary policy and the great recession – estimating the impact of a compression in the yield spread at the zero lower bound’ , Working Paper Series No. 1258, European Central Bank, October. Bauwens , L. , Lubrano , M. and Richard , J.‐F. ( 1999 ). Bayesian Inference In Dynamic Econometric Models , Oxford: Oxford University Press . Google Scholar Google Preview OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat COPAC Bean , C. ( 2011 ). ‘Lessons on unconventional monetary policy from the United Kingdom’ , speech given at the US Monetary Policy Forum, NewYork on 25 February 2011. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/2011/speech478.pdf (last accessed: 30 May 2011). Bean , C. , Paustian , M., Penalver , A. and Taylor , T. ( 2010 ). ‘Monetary policy after the fall’ , speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Annual Conference, Jackson Hole, Wyoming. Benati , L. and Surico , P. ( 2009 ). ‘VAR Analysis and the great moderation’ , American Economic Review , vol. 99 , pp. 1636 – 52 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Benford , J. , Berry , S., Nikolov , K. and Young , C. ( 2009 ). ‘Quantitative easing’ , Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin , vol. 49 , pp. 90 – 100 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Bernanke , B.S. , Reinhart , V.R. and Sack , B.P. ( 2004 ). ‘ Monetary policy alternatives at the zero bound: an empirical assessment’ , Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , vol. 35 , pp. 1 – 100 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Bridges , J. and Thomas , R. ( 2012 ). ‘The impact of QE on the UK economy – some supportive monetarist arithmetic’ , Bank of England Working Paper No. 442. Carriero , A. , Kapetanios , G. and Marcellino , M. ( 2010 ). ‘Forecasting government bond yields with large Bayesian VARs ’ , Working Paper No. 662, Queen Mary, University of London, School of Economics and Finance . Carter , C.K. and Kohn , R. ( 1994 ). ‘On Gibbs sampling for state space models’ , Biometrika , vol. 81 , pp. 541 – 53 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Chib , S. ( 1998 ). ‘Estimation and comparison of multiple change‐point models’ , Journal of Econometrics , vol. 86 (June), pp. 221 – 41 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Christiano , L. ( 2011 ). ‘Commentary: remarks on unconventional monetary policy’ , International Journal of Central Banking , vol. 7 , pp. 121 – 30 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Christiano , L. and Ikeda , D. ( 2011 ). ‘Government policy, credit markets and economic activity’ , Working Paper No. 17142, National Bureau of Economic Research. Chung , H. , Laforte , J.‐P., Reifschneider , D. and Williams , J.C. ( 2012 ). ‘Have we underestimated the likelihood and severity of zero lower bound events?’ , Journal of Money, Credit and Banking , vol. 44 (February), pp. 47 – 82 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Cogley , T. and Sargent , T.J. ( 2005 ). ‘Drift and volatilities: monetary policies and outcomes in the post WWII US ’ , Review of Economic Dynamics , vol. 8 (April), pp. 262 – 302 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Curdia , V. and Woodford , M. ( 2009 ). ‘Conventional and unconventional monetary policy’ , CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7514, CEPR, October. Dale , S. ( 2010 ). ‘QE – one year on’, Remarks at the CIMF and MMF Conference . http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/speeches/2010/speech428. pdf (last accessed: 30 May 2011). Google Scholar Google Preview OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat COPAC D'Amico , S. and King , T.B. ( 2010 ). ‘Flow and stock effects of large‐scale treasury purchases’ , Working Paper No. 2010‐52, Federal Reserve Board. Doh , T. ( 2010 ). ‘The efficacy of large‐scale asset purchases at the zero lower bound’ , Economic Review , vol. 95 , pp. 5 – 34 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Eggertsson , G.B. and Woodford , M. ( 2003 ). ‘The zero bound on interest rates and optimal monetary policy’ , Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , vol. 34 , pp. 139 – 235 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Estrella , A. ( 2005 ). ‘Why does the yield curve predict output and inflation?’ , Economic Journal , vol. 115 , pp. 722 – 44 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Evans , G.W. and Honkapohja , S. ( 2001 ). Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics , Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press . Google Scholar Google Preview OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat COPAC Gagnon , J. , Raskin , M., Remache , J. and Sack , B. ( 2011 ). ‘The financial market effects of the Federal Reserve's large‐scale asset purchases’ , International Journal of Central Banking , vol. 7 (March), pp. 3 – 43 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Greenwood , R. and Vayanos , D. ( 2008 ). ‘Bond supply and excess bond returns’ , NBER Working Paper No. 13806, National Bureau of Economic Research , Inc, February. Hamilton , J.D. and Wu , J.C. ( 2012 ). ‘The effectiveness of alternative monetary policy tools in a zero lower bound environment’ , Journal of Money, Credit and Banking , vol. 44 (February), pp. 3 – 46 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Harrison , R. ( 2012 ). ‘Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates’ , Bank of England Working Paper No. 444. Jacquier , E. , Polson , N. and Rossi , P. ( 2004 ). ‘Bayesian analysis of stochastic volatility models’ , Journal of Business and Economic Statistics , vol. 12 , pp. 371 – 418 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Joyce , M. , Lasaosa , A., Stevens , I. and Tong , M. ( 2011 ). ‘The financial market impact of quantitative easing’ , International Journal of Central Banking , vol. 7 , pp. 113 – 61 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Kadiyala , K.R. and Karlsson , S. ( 1997 ). ‘Numerical methods for estimation and inference in Bayesian VAR ‐models’ , Journal of Applied Econometrics , vol. 12 , pp. 99 – 132 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Kim , C.‐J. and Nelson , C.R. ( 1999 ). State‐Space Models With Regime Switching , Cambridge, MA: MIT Press . Google Scholar Google Preview OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat COPAC Kimura , T. and Small , D.H. ( 2006 ). ‘Quantitative monetary easing and risk in financial asset markets’ , B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics , vol. 6 , pp. 1 – 54 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Krishnamurthy , A. and Vissing‐Jorgensen , A. ( 2011 ). ‘The effects of quantitative easing on interest rates: channels and implications for policy’ , NBER Working Paper No. 17555, October. Lenza , M. , Pill , H. and Reichlin , L. ( 2010 ). ‘Monetary policy in exceptional times’ , Economic Policy , vol. 25 , pp. 295 – 339 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Litterman , R. ( 1986 ). ‘Forecasting with Bayesian vector autoregressions – five years of experience’ , Journal of Business and Economic Statistics , vol. 4 , pp. 25 – 38 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Markowitz , H. ( 1952 ). ‘Portfolio selection’ , Journal of Finance , vol. 7 , pp. 77 – 91 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Meier , A. ( 2009 ). ‘Panacea, curse, or nonevent? unconventional monetary policy in the United Kingdom’ , IMF Working Paper No. 09/163, International Monetary Fund, August. Mitchell , J. , Smith , R.J., Weale , M.R., Wright , S. and Salazar , E.L. ( 2005 ). ‘An indicator of monthly GDP and an early estimate of quarterly GDP growth’ , Economic Journal , vol. 115 , F108 – 29 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Modigliani , F. and Sutch , R. ( 1966 ). ‘Innovations in interest rate policy’ , American Economic Review , vol. 56 , pp. 178 – 97 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Modigliani , F. and Sutch , R. ( 1967 ). ‘Debt danagement and the term structure of interest rates: an empirical analysis of recent experience’ , Journal of Political Economy , vol. 75 , p. 569 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Neely , C.J. ( 2010 ). ‘The large scale asset purchases had large international effects’ , Working Paper No. 2010‐018, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Pesaran , M. and Smith , R. ( 2012 ). ‘ Counterfactual analysis in macroeconometrics: an empirical investigation into the effects of quantitative easing ’, mimeo, Cambridge University . Primiceri , G.E. ( 2005 ). ‘Time varying structural vector autoregressions and monetary policy’ , Review of Economic Studies , vol. 72 (July), pp. 821 – 52 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Sims , C. ( 1980 ). ‘Macroeconomics and reality’ , Econometrica , vol. 48 , pp. 1 – 48 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Swanson , E.T. ( 2011 ). ‘Let's twist again: a high‐frequency event‐study analysis of operation twist and its implications for QE 2’ , Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring , pp. 151 – 207 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Tobin , J. ( 1969 ). ‘A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory’ , Journal of Money, Credit and Banking , vol. 1 , pp. 15 – 29 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Trichet , J.‐C. ( 2009 ). ‘The ECB's enhanced credit support’ , Technical Report, keynote address at the University of Munich, 13 July 2009. http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2009/html/sp090713.en.html. (last accessed: 30 May 2011). Ugai , H. ( 2007 ). ‘Effects of the quantitative easing policy: a survey of empirical analyses’ , Monetary and Economic Studies , vol. 25 , pp. 1 – 48 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Vayanos , D. and Vila , J.‐L. ( 2009 ). ‘A preferred‐habitat model of the term structure of interest rates’ , NBER Working Paper No. 15487, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, November. Waggoner , D.F. and Zha , T. ( 1999 ). ‘Conditional forecasts in dynamic multivariate models’ , The Review of Economics and Statistics , vol. 81 , pp. 639 – 51 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Zellner , A. ( 1973 ). An Introduction to Bayesian Inference in Econometrics , Chichester: Wiley . Google Scholar Google Preview OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat COPAC Appendix Appendix A. A.1. Estimation of Large BVAR Model In what follows, we briefly discuss the estimation of the large BVAR described in (1). We can compactly rewrite the VAR as follows (12) where is a T × N matrix containing all the data points in yt, is a T × M matrix containing a vector of ones (1) in the first columns and the h‐th lag of Y in the remaining columns, is a M × N matrix, and is a T × N matrix of disturbances. As only one lag is considered, we have M = N + 1. The prior distribution can then be written as follows (13) Note that Ψh | Σ is a matric‐variate normal distribution where the prior expectation and prior variance are set according to (2). The prior variance matrix has a Kroneker structure where Σ is the variance matrix of the disturbances and the elements of Ω0 are given by in (2). Since the normal‐inverted Wishart prior is conjugate, the conditional posterior distribution of this model is also normal‐inverted Wishart (Zellner, 1973): (14) where the bar denotes that the parameters are those of the posterior distribution. Defining and as the OLS estimates, we have that , , , and . To perform inference and forecasting, one needs the full joint posterior distribution and the marginal distributions of the parameters and Σ. One could use the conditional posteriors in (A.3) as a basis of a Gibbs sampling algorithm that drawing in turn from the conditionals Ψh | Σ,Y and Σ | Y would eventually produce a sequence of draws from the joint posterior ΨhΣ | Y and the marginal posteriors Ψh | Y, Σ | Y, as well as the posterior distribution of any function of these coefficients (e.g. multi‐step forecasts or impulse responses). Still, if one is interested only in the posterior distribution of Ψh (rather than in any non‐linear function of it) there is an alternative to simulation: by integrating out Σ from (A.3). Zellner, 1973), has shown that the marginal posterior distribution of Ψh is a matric‐variate t: (15) The expected value for this distribution is given by (16) which is obviously extremely fast to compute. Recalling that is the OLS estimator, and using the normal equations we can rewrite this as follows (17) which shows that the posterior mean of Ψh is a weighted average of the OLS estimator and of the prior mean Ψ0, with weights proportional to the inverse of their respective variances. In the presence of a tight prior (i.e. when θ → 0), the posterior estimate will collapse to , while with a diffuse prior (i.e. when θ → ∞) the posterior estimate will collapse to the unrestricted OLS estimate. Given the posterior mean , it is straightforward to produce forecasts up to h steps ahead simply by setting: (18) As shown by Banbura et al. (2010), it is also possible to implement the prior described above using a set of dummy observations. Consider adding Td dummy observations Yd and Xd such that their moments coincide with the prior moments: , , . Augmenting the system in 12 with the dummy observations gives (19) where and are (T + Td) × N matrices and is a (T + Td) × M matrix. Then, it is possible to show that the OLS estimator of the augmented system (given by the usual formula ) is numerically equivalent to the posterior mean . Prior tightness To make the prior operational, one needs to choose the value of the hyperparameter φ. We discuss a number of methods for addressing this issue. The marginal data density of the model can be obtained by integrating out all the coefficients, i.e. defining Θ as the set of all the coefficients of the model, the marginal data density is (20) Under our normal‐inverted Wishart prior the density p(Y) can be computed in closed form (Bauwens et al., 1999). At each point in time φ could be chosen by maximising: (21) This method has been used by Carriero et al. (2010). However, as discussed there, such a method may have a tendency to choose low values for the tightness parameter implying a large weight on the prior. It is important for our purposes to give considerable weight on the data. We therefore adopt an alternative approach whereby the tightness parameter is chosen by matching the fit of particular equations in the large VAR to those from smaller VAR models. Lenza et al. (2010) use a similar approach to set tightness. We find this approach produces a reasonable balance between the effects of priors and data that is appropriate for our analysis. A.2. Estimation of MS‐SVAR Model We follow Chib (1998) and adopt a Bayesian Gibbs sampling approach to the estimation of the MS‐SVAR models. Here, we briefly describe the main steps of the algorithm. The Gibbs sampling algorithm proceeds in the following steps: (i) Sampling: st: Following Kim and Nelson (1999), we use the Multi‐Move Gibbs sampling algorithm to draw st from the joint conditional density . We impose the restriction that each regime must have at least N × (K + 1) + 2 observations, where N denotes the number of endogenous variables in the VAR, to ensure sufficient degrees of freedom for each regime. (ii) Sampling: : Conditional on a draw for St, the model is simply a sequence of Bayesian VAR models. The regime‐specific VAR coefficients are sampled from a normal distribution and the covariances are drawn from an inverted Wishart distribution. For the first M regimes, we use a normal inverse Wishart prior (Kadiyala and Karlsson, 1997). However, as described in detail below, we employ a (normal diffuse) prior distribution for the VAR coefficients of the final regime, which is compatible with the identification of the shock to the government bond spread. In our sample, the recent financial crisis coincides with the final regime of the estimated VAR model. The prior on the VAR coefficients in this regime implies that the policy rate does not respond to lagged changes in other endogenous variables. This assumption is compatible with restrictions used to identify the shock to the bond yield spread and reflects the fact that the policy rate is close to the ZLB. (iii) Sampling: : Given the state variables st, the non‐zero elements of the transition probability matrix are independent of Yt and the other parameters of the model and are drawn from a Dirichlet posterior. We estimate the MS‐SVAR model using 2,00,000 replications of the Gibbs sampler and discard the first 1,90,000 as burn‐in. Figure A1 plots the 20th‐order autocorrelation for the key parameters of the benchmark model. These are close to zero providing evidence in favour of convergence. A.3. Estimation of TVP‐SVAR Model The TVP‐SVAR model is estimated using the Bayesian methods described in Kim and Nelson (1999). In particular, we employ a Gibbs sampling algorithm that approximates the posterior distribution. Here, we summarise the basic algorithm which involves the following steps: (i) The VAR coefficients and the off‐diagonal elements of the covariance matrix At are simulated by using the methods described in Carter and Kohn (1994). As is common practice in this literature (Cogleya and Sargent, 2005) we impose the constraint that should be stable at each point in time. (ii) The volatilities of the reduced‐form shocks Ht are drawn using the date‐by‐date blocking scheme introduced in Jacquier et al. (2004). (iii) The hyperparameters Q and S are drawn from an inverse Wishart distribution while the elements of G are simulated from an inverse gamma distribution. Figure A2 shows the recursive means of the retained draws appear stable, providing evidence of convergence. The lag length is set at two. The data sample runs from 1958 Q1–2011 Q1 and we use the first 10 years of data as a training sample that is used to calibrate priors. A.4. Data Appendix for Large BVAR Model The data set for the large BVAR model is given in Table A1. Table A1 Data Appendix for Large BVAR Model No. . Variable . Source . No. . Variable . Source . 1 US industrial production DS 23 20‐year UK gilts BofE 2 US CPI DS 24 15‐year UK gilts BofE 3 Euro‐area industrial production DS 25 7‐year UK gilts BofE 4 Euro‐area HICP ECB 26 3‐year UK gilts BofE 5 UK GDP NIESR 27 5‐year 5‐year implied inflation BofE 6 UK industrial production ONS 28 6‐month Libor BG 7 Brent dollar oil price DS 29 12‐month Libor BG 8 UK CPI ONS 30 FTSE All‐Share index DS 9 UK‐PPI ONS 31 FTSE All‐Share dividend yield DS 10 UK‐UEMP ONS 32 FTSE All‐Share price‐earnings ratio DS 11 UK house price index HF 33 UK exchange rate index BofE 12 10‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 34 US dollar‐sterling exchange rate BofE 13 UK consumer confidence EC 35 Euro‐sterling exchange rate BofE 14 M4 BofE 36 T‐bill – Bank Rate spread BofE 15 M3 BofE 37 3‐month Libor – T‐bill spread BofE 16 Retail deposit and cash in M4 BofE 38 3‐month Libor‐Bank Rate spread BofE/BG 17 Secured lending to individuals BofE 39 2‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 18 M4 net lending to private sector BofE 40 5‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 19 M4 lending BofE 41 Bank Rate BofE 20 Household M4 BofE 42 US federal funds rate Fed 21 PNFC M4 BofE 43 Euro‐MRO interest rate BD/BG 22 OFC‐M4 BofE No. . Variable . Source . No. . Variable . Source . 1 US industrial production DS 23 20‐year UK gilts BofE 2 US CPI DS 24 15‐year UK gilts BofE 3 Euro‐area industrial production DS 25 7‐year UK gilts BofE 4 Euro‐area HICP ECB 26 3‐year UK gilts BofE 5 UK GDP NIESR 27 5‐year 5‐year implied inflation BofE 6 UK industrial production ONS 28 6‐month Libor BG 7 Brent dollar oil price DS 29 12‐month Libor BG 8 UK CPI ONS 30 FTSE All‐Share index DS 9 UK‐PPI ONS 31 FTSE All‐Share dividend yield DS 10 UK‐UEMP ONS 32 FTSE All‐Share price‐earnings ratio DS 11 UK house price index HF 33 UK exchange rate index BofE 12 10‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 34 US dollar‐sterling exchange rate BofE 13 UK consumer confidence EC 35 Euro‐sterling exchange rate BofE 14 M4 BofE 36 T‐bill – Bank Rate spread BofE 15 M3 BofE 37 3‐month Libor – T‐bill spread BofE 16 Retail deposit and cash in M4 BofE 38 3‐month Libor‐Bank Rate spread BofE/BG 17 Secured lending to individuals BofE 39 2‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 18 M4 net lending to private sector BofE 40 5‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 19 M4 lending BofE 41 Bank Rate BofE 20 Household M4 BofE 42 US federal funds rate Fed 21 PNFC M4 BofE 43 Euro‐MRO interest rate BD/BG 22 OFC‐M4 BofE Data Sources: Bank of England (BofE), Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Fed), Bundesbank (BD), European Central Bank (ECB), European Commission (EC), National Institute of Economic and Social Research (NIESR), Datastream (DS), Bloomberg (BG), Office for National Statistics (ONS) and Halifax (HF). Data transformation: We use log‐levels for the variables except those which are already in growth rates. Open in new tab Table A1 Data Appendix for Large BVAR Model No. . Variable . Source . No. . Variable . Source . 1 US industrial production DS 23 20‐year UK gilts BofE 2 US CPI DS 24 15‐year UK gilts BofE 3 Euro‐area industrial production DS 25 7‐year UK gilts BofE 4 Euro‐area HICP ECB 26 3‐year UK gilts BofE 5 UK GDP NIESR 27 5‐year 5‐year implied inflation BofE 6 UK industrial production ONS 28 6‐month Libor BG 7 Brent dollar oil price DS 29 12‐month Libor BG 8 UK CPI ONS 30 FTSE All‐Share index DS 9 UK‐PPI ONS 31 FTSE All‐Share dividend yield DS 10 UK‐UEMP ONS 32 FTSE All‐Share price‐earnings ratio DS 11 UK house price index HF 33 UK exchange rate index BofE 12 10‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 34 US dollar‐sterling exchange rate BofE 13 UK consumer confidence EC 35 Euro‐sterling exchange rate BofE 14 M4 BofE 36 T‐bill – Bank Rate spread BofE 15 M3 BofE 37 3‐month Libor – T‐bill spread BofE 16 Retail deposit and cash in M4 BofE 38 3‐month Libor‐Bank Rate spread BofE/BG 17 Secured lending to individuals BofE 39 2‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 18 M4 net lending to private sector BofE 40 5‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 19 M4 lending BofE 41 Bank Rate BofE 20 Household M4 BofE 42 US federal funds rate Fed 21 PNFC M4 BofE 43 Euro‐MRO interest rate BD/BG 22 OFC‐M4 BofE No. . Variable . Source . No. . Variable . Source . 1 US industrial production DS 23 20‐year UK gilts BofE 2 US CPI DS 24 15‐year UK gilts BofE 3 Euro‐area industrial production DS 25 7‐year UK gilts BofE 4 Euro‐area HICP ECB 26 3‐year UK gilts BofE 5 UK GDP NIESR 27 5‐year 5‐year implied inflation BofE 6 UK industrial production ONS 28 6‐month Libor BG 7 Brent dollar oil price DS 29 12‐month Libor BG 8 UK CPI ONS 30 FTSE All‐Share index DS 9 UK‐PPI ONS 31 FTSE All‐Share dividend yield DS 10 UK‐UEMP ONS 32 FTSE All‐Share price‐earnings ratio DS 11 UK house price index HF 33 UK exchange rate index BofE 12 10‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 34 US dollar‐sterling exchange rate BofE 13 UK consumer confidence EC 35 Euro‐sterling exchange rate BofE 14 M4 BofE 36 T‐bill – Bank Rate spread BofE 15 M3 BofE 37 3‐month Libor – T‐bill spread BofE 16 Retail deposit and cash in M4 BofE 38 3‐month Libor‐Bank Rate spread BofE/BG 17 Secured lending to individuals BofE 39 2‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 18 M4 net lending to private sector BofE 40 5‐year gilt – T‐bill spread BofE 19 M4 lending BofE 41 Bank Rate BofE 20 Household M4 BofE 42 US federal funds rate Fed 21 PNFC M4 BofE 43 Euro‐MRO interest rate BD/BG 22 OFC‐M4 BofE Data Sources: Bank of England (BofE), Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Fed), Bundesbank (BD), European Central Bank (ECB), European Commission (EC), National Institute of Economic and Social Research (NIESR), Datastream (DS), Bloomberg (BG), Office for National Statistics (ONS) and Halifax (HF). Data transformation: We use log‐levels for the variables except those which are already in growth rates. Open in new tab A.5. Charts A1 [ Convergence Diagnostic Statistics: MS‐SVAR ] A2 [ Convergence Diagnostic Statistics: TVP‐SVAR ] Author notes " The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Bank of England. The authors thank Mark Astley, Ryan Banerjee, Jagjit Chadha, Spencer Dale, Stefania D'Amico, Rodrigo Guimaraes, Mike Joyce, Michele Lenza, Lea Paterson, Hashem Pesaran, Simon Price, Ron Smith, Ryland Thomas, Matthew Tong, Oreste Tristani, Robert Woods, Tony Yates, Chris Yeates, Chris Young and an anonymous referee for useful comments on a previous draft. We also thank Ahila Karan and Lydia Silver for research assistance. © 2012 The Author(s). The Economic Journal © 2012 Royal Economic Society
The Economic Journal – Oxford University Press
Published: Nov 1, 2012
Read and print from thousands of top scholarly journals.
Already have an account? Log in
Bookmark this article. You can see your Bookmarks on your DeepDyve Library.
To save an article, log in first, or sign up for a DeepDyve account if you don’t already have one.
Copy and paste the desired citation format or use the link below to download a file formatted for EndNote
Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
All DeepDyve websites use cookies to improve your online experience. They were placed on your computer when you launched this website. You can change your cookie settings through your browser.