Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
J Econ Sci Assoc (2018) 4:86–97 https://doi.org/10.1007/s40881-018-0049-2 REPLICATION PAPER Framing effects on bribery behaviour: experimental evidence from China and Uganda 1 2 1 Alessio Gaggero · Simon Appleton · Lina Song Received: 13 December 2017 / Revised: 15 May 2018 / Accepted: 19 May 2018 / Published online: 4 June 2018 © The Author(s) 2018 Abstract In this study we investigate the effect of framing on bribery behaviour. To do this, we replicate Barr and Serra (Exp Econ, 12(4):488–503, (2009) and carry out a simple one-shot bribery game that mimics corruption. In one treatment, we presented the experiment in a framed version, in which wording was embedded with social context; in the other, we removed the social context and presented the game in a neutral manner. The contribution of this paper is that it offers a comparison of framing effects in two highly corrupt countries: China and Uganda. Our results provide evidence of strong and significant framing effects for Uganda, but not for China. Keywords Framing · Bribery behaviour JEL classification C91 · D73 · D91 1 Introduction and motivation In the last decades, there has been increasing interest in the effects of framing on decision making and experimental tasks. In particular, recent studies have reported the existence of significant framing effects in prisoner’s dilemma games (Ross and Ward, 1996; Liberman et al. 2004), public goods games (Andreoni 1995; Cook- son 2000; Rege and Telle 2004), and dictator games (Eckel and Grossman 1996; * Alessio Gaggero a.gaggero@nottingham.ac.uk Nottingham University Business School, Nottingham, UK School of Economics, University of Nottingham, Ningbo, China 1 3 Framing effects on bribery behaviour: experimental evidence… Branas-Garza 2007). There is little consensus among economists, however, on the existence of framing effects on bribery behaviour. Abbink and Hennig-Schmidt (2006, AHS hereafter) first investigate whether, and to what extent, presenting a bribery game framed as a (repeated) corrupt exchange between a firm and a public official, as opposed to the same game framed neutrally and in abstract terms, would reduce bribery behaviour. In the study, the authors find no evidence that loading the context of the instructions with an immoral ethi- cal preconception has an effect on bribery behaviour, for a sample of students at the University of Bonn. As argued by Barr and Serra (2009), however, the obtained null results may be driven by either artificiality, in that participants did not identify themselves with either being a firm or a public official, or by the fact that the original AHS game was repeated for thirty rounds with fixed matching and hence also involved feelings of trust and reciprocity. Barr and Serra (2009) tackle these potential issues by design- ing a simple one-shot petty corruption experiment, in which participants interact with each other as ‘citizens’ and ‘officials.’ The main advantages of their setting are that (1) all students are citizens and, consequently, more likely to identify them- selves with the frame adopted, and (2) in a one-shot game, feelings such as trust and reciprocity are negligible. Using a sample of students at the University of Oxford, the authors do find evidence of framing effects, and successfully show that the exist- ence of a framing effect depends on the specific experimental design employed as well as the degree of artificiality of the corruption frame applied. In this study, we contribute to the literature by replicating the Barr and Serra (2009) petty corruption game in two highly corrupt countries, China and Uganda, currently ranked 77th and 151st out of 176 respectively in the Corruption Percep- tion Index. In 2012, China initiated the largest campaign against graft and corrup- tion ever made in the history of its Communist Party, leading to the indictment of over 120 high-ranking officials and 100,000 individuals. The latter, although its cor - ruption level keeps worsening, still has not embraced any official anti-corruption campaign. Our results provide evidence of strong and significant framing effects for Uganda, but not for China. 2 Experimental design The game includes 15 players. We randomly assigned players to three roles: private citizens, public officials, and other members of society (henceforth, ‘citizens’, ‘offi- cials’, and ‘members of society’). Each citizen is randomly matched with an official, and gets an initial endowment of I . He has to decide whether to offer a bribe to the matched official for a corrupt service, for which he will obtain a benefit of V . Let B be a dummy variable that equals unity if the citizen chooses to offer a bribe, and let b ∈{1, 2, … , 20} denote The game was first designed by Abbink et al. (2002). See Bardsley (2005) for a discussion of artificiality in experimental economics. 1 3 88 A. Gaggero et al. Table 1 Summary statistics (1) China (2) Uganda (3) p value Female 0.77 (0.424) 0.34 (0.474) 0.000 Years of age 21.45 (1.952) 23.87 (3.573) 0.000 Father years of schooling 11.82 (2.867) 10.82 (3.864) 0.000 Mother years of schooling 10.95 (3.326) 9.13 (4.198) 0.000 Observations 396 405 801 The table presents summary statistics of the experimental sample, comparing China and Uganda. Stand- ard deviations in parenthesis the amount of the bribe offered. Notice, if the citizen decides to offer a bribe to the official, he will pay a (deterministic) cost, denoted K, which reflects the expected cost of getting caught and punished. Each official receives an initial endowment of I . He has to decide whether or not to accept the bribe offered by the matched citizen. Let A be a dummy variable which equals one if the official decides to accept the bribe. Similar to above, if the official accepts the bribe, he will also incur a deterministic loss,K , reflecting the expected cost of being caught. Finally, each member of society receives an initial endowment of I . They are a passive group, and as such do not make any decisions in the game. They will, how- ever, incur a loss of endowment, h , each time a citizen-official pair chooses to act corruptly. Let Y , Y , and Y represent the final payoffs of the citizens, officials, and mem- C O M bers of society, respectively, at the end of the bribery game. Thus, the payoff sched- ule for the three types of players can be written in the following compact form: I if B = 0 I − K if B = 1 and A = 0 Y = (1) C ⎨ C ⎪ I + V − K − b if B = 1 and A = 1, I if A = 0 Y = (2) I + b − K if A = 1 Y = I − N ⋅ h, (3) M M where N ∈{0, 1, 2, 3, 4, 5} represents the number of citizen-officials pairs who suc- cessfully exchange bribes. Following the original paper, we set I = I = 35 money C O units and I = 25 money units. Further, we set V = 20 , h = 4 , and K = 5 . A total This difference in initial endowments reflects the fact that other members of the society do not usually have the means to engage in corrupt behaviour. 1 3 Framing effects on bribery behaviour: experimental evidence… of 54 experimental sessions were conducted, 27 in each country. Every session involved 15 players, with the exception of two sessions in China, in which we only managed to recruit 9 and 12 players, respectively. Table 1 presents demographic fea- tures of the sample of students, and reports that participants in China were younger and there was a higher proportion of females. The sessions were conducted in vari- ous teaching and seminar rooms, depending on availability, and carried out with pen and paper. Participants were randomly allocated to their role, and at no time knew which player they were matched with. Besides the instructions, on each desk, par- ticipants found tables describing the payoff schedule of the game, and an envelope containing a specially designed form for players to express their preferences. In par- ticular, citizens had to state the amount, if any, they wanted to offer to their matched official; officials, instead, had to state whether they would accept or reject each one of the possible bribes, b ∈{1, 2, … , 20} . This allows us to identify officials who would reject all of the possible bribes, as well as the minimum amount offered for the bribe to be accepted. Once all the forms were filled, envelopes were collected and payoffs calculated. We had two treatments of the game. In the framed treatment, each role and action was embedded in the social context, as explained above. In the neutral treatment, however, we removed the social context and presented the game in an abstract man- ner. Specifically, player roles went from citizen, official, and member of society, to player A, player B, and player C, respectively; and the word “bribe” was replaced with the word “offer”. In each country, we randomly drew 14 sessions to be pre- sented in the framed version, and the remaining in the neutral one. Before presenting our result, it is important to mention the power of this replica- tion. Accordingly, we follow the guidelines of Nikiforakis and Slonim (2015) and Drichoutis et al. (2015), and implement a power calculation for our study to find whether or not there is an effect statistically significant at the 5% level. Given our sample size, and the observed means and standard deviations in the original study of Barr and Serra (2009), the power of our experiment is 99%. 3 Results Table 2 reports the effect of framing on bribery behaviour. Specifically, in columns (1) and (2) we compare the behaviour under the neutral and framed treatments for the Chinese sample, and in column (3) we report the p value of a t-test which compares the means of the two groups. Similarly, in columns (4), (5), and (6), we report the same for the participants from Uganda. The table shows that framing had In order to increase the representativeness of our samples, experiments were carried out in Kampala and Jinja, in Uganda, and Beijing, Ningbo, and Chengdu in China. It is important to emphasise that regression analysis can only partially account for this important dif- ference in composition of men and women across countries. In order to dispel potential issues, in Table 7 in the “Appendix”, we check for the possibility of a composition effect, but this does not seem to be the case. Table 6 in the “Appendix” compares our experimental results with those of Barr and Serra (2009). 1 3 90 A. Gaggero et al. 1 3 Table 2 Descriptive analysis China Uganda (1) Neutral (2) Framed (3) p value (4) Neutral (5) Framed (6) p value Successful bribes per session private Citizen 4.62 (0.045) 4.61 (0.040) 0.715 4.46 (0.045) 3.42 (0.072) 0.000 Offered no bribe 0.08 (0.267) 0.06 (0.239) 0.715 0.11 (0.312) 0.31 (0.468) 0.003 Mean bribe offered 7.67 (3.439) 8.21 (3.038) 0.361 6.66 (6.192) 5.77 (4.660) 0.416 Public official No acceptable bribes 0.02 (0.124) 0.04 (0.207) 0.336 0.05 (0.211) 0.20 (0.403) 0.007 Conditional mean acceptable offer 11.67 (3.904) 11.55 (3.433) 0.856 13.23 (4.107) 12.64 (4.201) 0.448 Observations 131 135 266 130 140 270 The table compares bribing behaviour of participants who played the bribery game in the framed and in the neutral treatment. Standard deviations in parenthesis Framing effects on bribery behaviour: experimental evidence… Table 3 Framing effects for private citizens China Uganda (1) Offered no bribe (2) Mean bribe (3) Offered no bribe (4) Mean bribe offered offered Framed [0, 1] − 0.067 (0.367) 0.524 (0.599) 0.727*** (0.266) − 0.784 (1.081) Covariates Female − 0.186 (0.431) − 0.387 (0.727) − 0.235 (0.277) − 2.814** (1.144) Years of age − 0.164 (0.142) − 0.010 (0.146) − 0.025 (0.043) 0.028 (0.151) Beijing 0.107 (0.557) − 0.702 (0.816) Chengdu 0.450 (0.543) 0.683 (0.835) Kampala − 0.016 (0.312) 1.269 (1.310) Constant 1.886 (3.137) 8.216** (3.356) − 0.524 (1.194) 6.057 (4.297) Observations 132 124 133 104 The table presents regression estimates of the effect of framing on corruption behaviour. Probit models were estimated if the dependent variable was dichotomous [0, 1]. Standard errors in parenthesis are clus- tered at the session level * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 virtually no effect on the behaviour of participants in China. Whether the game was played in the neutral or in the framed version, an average of 4.6 successful bribes per session occurred, that is, citizens’ offers were successfully accepted by the ran- domly paired officials. The table shows that only a small proportion of Chinese stu- dents either did not offer any bribes (8%), or did not accept any possible bribes (2%). Similarly, framing had no effect on the conditional amount of bribes offered, nor accepted. Conversely, framing had a strong and significant effect in Uganda. Specifically, students who played the bribery game in the framed form were significantly less likely to either offer or accept any bribe, and consequently, the number of success- ful bribes in framed sessions were significantly lower than in the neutral ones. The table, moreover, shows that while framing has a strong effect on the propensity to either offer or accept a bribe, it does not have an effect on the conditional amount offered nor on the conditional amount accepted. In Tables 3 and 4, we check the robustness of our results in a regression frame- work that allows us to control for a set of potentially confounding variables, as well as allowing for interdependence within sessions by clustering. Specifically, Table 3 reports framing effects on the citizens, and in Table 4 we report estimated coeffi- cients for the officials. The results confirm our descriptive analysis and show strong and significant framing effects for the sample from Uganda, and no significant effect for China. Further, in order to directly test whether there is a significant differen- tial framing effect between the two countries, in Table 5, we conduct a regression analysis on the pooled data in which we include an interaction term combining the framing dummy variable together with the Uganda dummy variable. The table con- firms a statistically significant differential framing effect for the private citizens in 1 3 92 A. Gaggero et al. Table 4 Framing effects for public officials China Uganda (1) Accepted no bribe (2) Minimum accept- (3) Accepted no bribe (4) Minimum able bribe acceptable bribe Framed [0, 1] 0.473 (0.567) 0.230 (0.641) 0.947*** (0.335) -0.071 (0.794) Covariates Female − 1.034 (0.716) − 0.438 (0.831) − 0.214 (0.340) − 0.469 (0.839) Years of age − 0.173 (0.131) − 0.617*** (0.177) − 0.058 (0.077) 0.119 (0.128) Beijing 4.232 (702.133) − 1.730* (0.876) Chengdu 5.096 (702.133) − 1.072 (0.918) Kampala 0.563 (0.454) 1.930* (0.983) Constant − 2.421 (702.138) 26.115*** (4.028) − 0.781 (2.009) 9.034** (3.577) Observations 132 128 132 115 The table presents regression estimates of the effect of framing on corruption behaviour. Probit models were estimated if the dependent variable was dichotomous [0, 1]. Standard errors in parenthesis are clus- tered at the session level * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 Uganda with respect to the private citizens in China, but reports no differential fram- ing effect for the public officials between the two countries. 4 Discussion and conclusion In this paper, we replicate Barr and Serra (2009) one-shot petty corruption game, and compare framing effects between two countries with a high level of corruption: China and Uganda. We find strong and significant framing effects for the partici- pants from Uganda. Specifically, students exposed to the framed version of the petty corruption game were significantly less likely to offer, as well as accept, any bribe. On the contrary, we do not find any significant effects of framing on bribery behav - iour in China. The results for Uganda are consistent with those obtained by Barr and Serra (2009); however, this is not the case for China, suggesting other factors might be causing the differences in framing effects between the two countries. Follow - ing Cooper et al. (1999) and Barr and Serra (2010), the magnitude of the framing effect may change depending on the degree participants have been exposed to a cor - rupt environment, as well as on the social norms and values prevailing in a certain society. For example, it is likely that in a society with a higher exposure to cor- ruption, in which people engage in bribery in their everyday life, individuals would be less responsive to the corruption frame. As both China and Uganda have high levels of corruption, it is not obvious that differences in the degree of corruption in the two countries explain our result. Indeed, our results are somewhat paradoxical: 1 3 Framing effects on bribery behaviour: experimental evidence… 1 3 Table 5 Framing effects Private citizen Public official: (1) Offered no (2) Offered no (3) Mean bribe (4) Mean bribe (5) Accepted no (6) Accepted no (7) Minimum (8) Minimum bribe bribe offered offered bribe bribe acceptable bribe acceptable bribe Framed [0, 1] − 0.123 (0.320) − 0.087 (0.343) 0.534 (0.481) 0.363 (0.499) 0.455 (0.508) 0.305 (0.468) − 0.118 (0.687) 0.038 (0.673) Uganda 0.195 (0.309) 0.344 (0.546) − 1.017 (0.997) − 3.085*** 0.477 (0.510) 3.084*** 1.554** (0.735) − 1.013 (1.085) (1.032) (0.430) Framed* Uganda 0.878** (0.406) 0.841** (0.412) − 1.419 (1.358) − 1.008 (1.308) 0.386 (0.629) 0.676 (0.594) − 0.465 (1.064) − 0.179 (1.005) Covariates Female − 0.157 (0.229) − 1.756*** − 0.303 (0.272) − 0.216 (0.589) (0.618) Year of Enrol- − 0.051 (0.133) − 0.285 (0.328) − 0.183 (0.156) − 0.231 (0.254) ment Beijing 0.196 (0.551) − 0.385 (0.614) 3.513*** − 1.323 (0.826) (0.618) Chengdu 0.427 (0.476) 1.018 (0.725) 4.094*** − 0.953 (0.971) (0.504) Kampala 0.085 (0.301) 1.391 (1.010) 0.753** (0.315) 1.537* (0.778) Constant − 1.434*** − 1.453** 7.672*** (0.414) 9.991*** (1.516) − 2.160*** − 4.880*** 11.672*** 13.625*** (1.274) (0.242) (0.701) (0.385) (0.355) (0.513) Observations 266 266 229 229 264 264 243 243 The table presents regression estimates of the effect of framing on corruption behaviour. Probit models were estimated if the dependent variable was dichotomous [0, 1]. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at the session level * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 94 A. Gaggero et al. Transparency International’s data (based on perceptions by elites and business peo- ple) suggest Uganda has higher levels of corruption than China. Uganda certainly lacks China’s fierce official anti-corruption drive. However, our Ugandan subjects are more sensitive to framing the experiment in terms of corruption than their Chinese counterparts. Nor is there clear evidence that corruption is more socially acceptable in China than Uganda. Indeed, in the World Values Survey, Chinese citi- zens were less likely to agree that “it was justifiable that someone accepts a bribe in the course of their duties”. On scale of 1 = never justifiable to 10 = always justifiable, China averaged 1.20 in 1995 while Uganda averaged 2.14 in 2001—the latest years available (Inglehart et al. 2014; Gatti et al. 2003). Further research is necessary to explain our results. This may be a case where there is a disconnect between the attitudes people espouse in public opinion surveys and their behaviour in private games. One may disapprove of something in public— particularly when done by others—but engage in it personally in private. China has a culture of Guanxi (or personal relations) in business that can involve gift giving which potentially strays into corruption (Zhan 2012). For example, the government has recently cracked down on lavish banquets by public officials. A 2014 Pew survey of public attitudes found 38% of Chinese respondents thought bribery was important for getting ahead—the highest proportion in all the countries in the world and ahead of the 15% average for the African countries in the sample (which included Uganda, but the country specific figure was not available, Gao, 2014). Potentially related to this, corruption has sometimes been seen by economists as “greasing the wheels” of economic development in China by substituting for private property rights and the rule of law. For example, Qian (2003) argues that the incentivising cadres was the key to successful reform in China: local officials would encourage the develop- ment of publicly or collectively owned enterprises because they received a private share of the benefits (sometimes through corruption). Conversely, economists study - ing Uganda (and indeed the rest of Africa), tend to view corruption unequivocally a barrier to economic development, raising the costs of doing business, undermining government services, private property rights and the rule of law (Godfrey and Yu 2014). Future research to understand better private behaviour regarding corruption may be very important for policy, as anti-graft campaigns may not be successful if citizens do not adhere to the expected norms against corruption. Acknowledgements We thank Thorsten Chmura, Roberto Hernan Gonzalez, Simona Demel, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. Special thanks to Abigail Barr for the help during the initial stages of the project, and for providing the necessary experimental scripts. Financial support of the Eco- nomic and Social Research Council [ES/M004333/1] is gratefully acknowledged. Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 Inter- national License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribu- tion, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. Appendix See Tables 6 and 7. 1 3 Framing effects on bribery behaviour: experimental evidence… 1 3 Table 6 Comparison China Uganda Barr and Serra (1) Neutral (2) Framed (3) Diff. (4) Neutral (5) Framed (6) Diff. (7) Neutral (8) Framed (9) Diff. No bribe offered 0.08 (0.267) 0.06 (0.239) 0.02 (0.044) 0.11 (0.312) 0.31 (0.468) − 0.21 (0.069) 0.10 (0.305) 0.40 (0.497) − 0.30 (0.104) No acceptable bribes 0.02 (0.124) 0.04 (0.207) − 0.03 (0.030) 0.05 (0.211) 0.20 (0.403) − 0.15 (0.056) 0.10 (0.305) 0.26 (0.443) − 0.16 (0.096) Observations 131 135 266 130 140 270 30 35 65 The table compares results of our experimental sample with those of Barr and Serra (2009). Standard deviations in parenthesis 96 A. Gaggero et al. 1 3 Table 7 Framing effects Private citizen Public official (1) Offered no (2) Offered no (3) Mean bribe (4) Mean bribe (5) Accepted no (6) Accepted no (7) Minimum (8) Minimum bribe bribe offered offered bribe bribe acceptable bribe acceptable bribe Framed [0, 1] 0.59.3* (0.307) 0.616** (0.314) − 0.235 (1.236) − 0.476 (1.251) 0.814** (0.324) 0.815** (0.355) − 0.683 (0.780) − 0.407 (0.694) Female − 0.263 (0.334) − 0.098 (0.376) − 0.990 (0.787) − 1.777** − 0.498 (0.368) − 0.332 (0.479) − 1.288 (0.808) − 0.394 (0.816) (0.852) Framed* female − 0.249 (0.401) − 0.207 (0.392) 0.415 (1.309) 0.336 (1.281) − 0.087 (0.439) 0.014 (0.458) 0.673 (1.048) 0.488 (0.954) Covariates Year of Enrol- − 0.108 (0.118) 0.044 (0.309) − 0.204 (0.136) − 0.110 (0.226) ment Beijing − 0.411 (0.470) 1.437* (0.731) 0.079 (0.556) − 0.738 (0.785) Chengdu − 0.209 (0.339) 2.799*** (0.804) 0.604 (0.505) − 0.426 (0.920) Kampala 0.216 (0.295) 0.078 (1.049) 0.820*** 1.168* (0.684) (0.303) Constant − 1.231*** − 0.991* (0.553) 7.714*** (0.843) 7.246*** (1.435) − 1.668*** − 1.697*** 13.150*** 12.763*** (0.900) (0.246) (0.277) (0.493) (0.570) Observations 266 266 229 229 264 264 243 243 The table presents regression estimates of the effect of framing on corruption behaviour. Probit models were estimated if the dependent variable was dichotomous [0, 1]. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at the session level * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 Framing effects on bribery behaviour: experimental evidence… References Abbink, K., & Hennig-Schmidt, H. (2006). Neutral versus loaded instructions in a bribery experiment. Experimental Economics, 9(2), 103–121. Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., & Renner, E. (2002). An Experimental Bribery Game. Journal of Law, Eco- nomics, & Organisation, 18(2), 428–454. Andreoni, J. (1995). Warm-glow versus cold-prickle: the effects of positive and negative framing on cooperation in experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 1–21. Bardsley, N. (2005). Experimental economics and the artificiality of alteration. Journal of Economic Methodology, 12(2), 239–251. Barr, A., & Serra, D. (2009). The effects of externalities and framing on bribery in a petty corruption experiment. Experimental Economics, 12(4), 488–503. Barr, A., & Serra, D. (2010). Corruption and culture: an experimental analysis. Journal of Public Eco- nomics, 94(11–12), 862–869. Branas-Garza, P. (2007). Promoting helping behavior with framing in dictator games. Journal of Eco- nomic Psychology, 28(4), 477–486. Cookson, R. (2000). Framing effects in public goods experiments. Experimental Economics, 3, 55–79. Cooper, B. D. J., Kagel, J. H., Lo, W. E. I., & Gu, Q. L. (1999). Gaming against managers in incentive systems: experimental results with Chinese Students and Chinese Managers. The American Eco- nomic Review, 89(4), 781–804. Drichoutis, A. C., Lusk, J. L., & Nayga, R. M., Jr. (2015). The veil of experimental currency units in sec- ond price auctions. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 182–196. Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, Ph J. (1996). Altruism in anonymous dictator games. Games and Economic Behavior, 16, 181–191. Gao, G. (2014). Where people say giving bribes gets you ahead in life, Pew Research Center. http://www. pewre searc h.org/fact-tank/2014/10/23/where -peopl e-say-givin g-bribe s-gets-you-ahead -in-life/ Gatti, R., Paternostro, S., & Rigolini, J. (2003). Individual attitudes toward corruption: do social effects matter? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3122. Washington DC: The World Bank. Godfrey, M., & Yu, P. J. (2014). Patronage driven corruption undermining the fight against poverty in Uganda. African Social Science Review, 7(1), 54–69. Inglehart, R., Haerpfer, C., Moreno, A., Welzel, C., Kizilova, K., Diez-Medrano, J., et al. (Eds.). (2014). World Values Survey: Round Four - Country-Pooled Datafile Version: ww.worldvaluessurvey.org/ WVSDocumentationWV4.jsp. Madrid: JD Systems Institute. Liberman, V., Samuels, S., & Ross, L. (2004). The name of the game: predictive power of reputations vs. situational labels in determining prisoner’s dilemma game moves. Personality and Social Psychol- ogy Bulletin, 30, 1175–1185. Nikiforakis, N., & Slonim, R. (2015). Editors’ preface: statistics, replications and null results. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 127–131. Qian, Y. (2003). How reform worked in China. In Dani Rodrik (Ed.), In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth (pp. 297–333). Princeton: Princeton University Press. Rege, M., & Telle, K. (2004). The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public goods situations. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1625–1644. Ross, L., & Ward, A. (1996). Naive realism in everyday life: implications for social conflict and mis- understanding. In E. S. Reed, E. Turiel, & T. Brown (Eds.), Values and knowledge (pp. 103–135). Mahwah: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Zhan, J. V. (2012). Filling the gap of formal institutions: the effects of Guanxi network on corruption in reform-era China. Crime, Law and Social Change, 58(2), 93–109. 1 3
Journal of the Economic Science Association – Springer Journals
Published: Jun 4, 2018
You can share this free article with as many people as you like with the url below! We hope you enjoy this feature!
Read and print from thousands of top scholarly journals.
Already have an account? Log in
Bookmark this article. You can see your Bookmarks on your DeepDyve Library.
To save an article, log in first, or sign up for a DeepDyve account if you don’t already have one.
Copy and paste the desired citation format or use the link below to download a file formatted for EndNote
Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
All DeepDyve websites use cookies to improve your online experience. They were placed on your computer when you launched this website. You can change your cookie settings through your browser.