Get 20M+ Full-Text Papers For Less Than $1.50/day. Start a 14-Day Trial for You or Your Team.

Learn More →

Demand for Crash Insurance, Intermediary Constraints, and Risk Premia in Financial Markets

Demand for Crash Insurance, Intermediary Constraints, and Risk Premia in Financial Markets Abstract We propose a new measure of financial intermediary constraints based on how intermediaries manage their tail risk exposures. Using data for the trading activities in the market of deep out-of-the-money index put options, we identify periods when the variations in the net amount of trading between financial intermediaries and public investors are likely to be mainly driven by shocks to intermediary constraints. We then infer tightness of intermediary constraints from the quantities of option trading. A tightening of intermediary constraints according to our measure is associated with increasing option expensiveness, higher risk premia, deteriorating funding liquidity, and broker-dealer deleveraging. Received December 1, 2014; editorial decision May 19, 2017 by Editor Geert Bekaert. Authors have furnished an Internet Appendix, which is available on the Oxford University Press Web site next to the link to the final published paper online. In this paper, we present new evidence connecting financial intermediary constraints to asset prices. We propose to measure the tightness of intermediary constraints based on how the intermediaries manage their aggregate tail risk exposures. Using data on the trading activities between public investors and financial intermediaries in the market of deep out-of-the-money put options on the S&P 500 index (abbreviated as DOTM SPX puts), we exploit the price-quantity relations to identify periods when shocks to intermediary constraints are likely to be the main driver of the variations in the net amount of trading between public investors and financial intermediaries. This then enables us to infer tight intermediary constraints from the option trading quantities. We show that tight intermediary constraints under our measure are associated with increasing option expensiveness, rising risk premia for a wide range of financial assets, deteriorating funding liquidity, and deleveraging by broker-dealers. To construct the constraint measure, we start by computing the net amount of DOTM SPX puts that public investors in aggregate purchase each month (henceforth referred to as |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠), which also reflects the net amount of the same options that broker-dealers and market-makers sell in that month. While it is well known that financial intermediaries are net sellers of these types of options during normal times, we find that |$\textit{PNBO}$| varies significantly over time and tends to be negative during times of market distress. |$\textit{PNBO}$| could be low during periods of weak supply by intermediaries (because of tight constraints) or during periods of weak demand by public investors. One needs to separate these two effects in order to link |$\textit{PNBO}$| to intermediary constraints. We propose exploiting the relation between the quantities of trading, as measured by |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, and prices (expensiveness of SPX options), as measured by the variance premium. Positive comovements in prices and quantities are consistent with the presence of demand shocks, whereas negative comovements are consistent with the presence of supply shocks.1 We summarize the daily price-quantity relations each month. On average, supply shocks are likely to be the main driver of the quantity of trading in months with a negative price-quantity relation. Then we take low |$\textit{PNBO}$| in a month with negative price-quantity relation as indicative of tight intermediary constraints. In monthly data from January 1991 to December 2012, |$\textit{PNBO}$| is significantly negatively related to option expensiveness, and this negative relation becomes stronger when jump risk in the market is higher. In daily data, the correlation between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and our measure of option expensiveness is negative in 159 out of 264 months. These results highlight the significant role that supply shocks play in the market of DOTM SPX puts. In periods with a negative price-quantity relation, |$\textit{PNBO}$| significantly predicts future market excess returns. A one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| (normalized |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) in a month with negative price-quantity relation is on average associated with a 4.3% (3%) increase in the subsequent 3-month log market excess return. The |$R^2$| of the regression is 24.7% (12.3%). The predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is even stronger in months when market jump risk is above the median level (in addition to the negative price-quantity relation), but becomes much weaker in months when the price-quantity relations are positive. Besides equity, a lower |$\textit{PNBO}$| also predicts higher future excess returns for high-yield corporate bonds, an aggregate hedge fund portfolio, a carry trade portfolio, and a commodity index, and it predicts lower future excess returns on long-term Treasuries and (pay-fix) SPX variance swaps. The predictability results survive extensive robustness checks, which include different statistical methods for determining the significance of the predictive power, excluding the 2008–2009 financial crisis, extreme observations of |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, different ways to define option moneyness, and an alternative quantity measure based on end-of-period open interest instead of trading volume, among others. In addition, we consider an alternative method for identifying periods of weak supply based on Rigobon (2003) (see also Sentana and Fiorentini 2001). Using the reduced-form econometric assumptions of this method, we extract supply shocks to intermediaries and confirm the ability of the inferred supply shocks to predict future stock returns. The return predictability results are consistent with the intermediary asset pricing theories, in which a reduction in the risk-sharing capacity of the financial intermediaries causes the aggregate risk premium in the economy to rise. An alternative explanation of the predictability results is that |$\textit{PNBO}$| is merely a proxy for standard macrofinancial factors that simultaneously drive the aggregate risk premium and intermediary constraints. If this alternative explanation is true, then the inclusion of proper risk factors in the predictability regression should drive away the predictive power of our constraint measure. We find that the predictive power of our measure is unaffected by the inclusion of a long list of return predictors in the literature, including various price ratios, consumption-wealth ratio, variance risk premium, default spread, term spread, and several tail risk measures. While these results do not lead to the rejection of the alternative explanation (there can always be omitted risk factors), they are at least consistent with intermediary constraints having a unique effect on the aggregate risk premium. Our intermediary constraint measure is significantly related to the funding condition measures of Fontaine and Garcia (2012) (extracted from the Treasury market) and Adrian, Etula, and Muir (2014) (based on the growth rate of broker-dealer leverage). At the same time, we also find that our constraint measure provides unique information about the aggregate risk premium not contained in the other funding liquidity measures. Our results suggest that when financial intermediaries switch from sellers of DOTM SPX puts to buyers (e.g., in the months following the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy in 2008), tight constraints likely forced intermediaries to aggressively hedge their tail risk exposures, rather than accommodate an increase in public investors’ demand to sell crash insurance. Examples of shocks to intermediary constraints include stricter regulatory requirements on banks’ tail risk exposures (e.g., because of the Dodd-Frank Act or Basel III) or losses incurred by intermediaries. To further examine the risk-sharing mechanism, we try to identify who among the public investors (retail or institutional) are the “liquidity providers” during times of distress: reducing the net amount of crash insurance acquired from financial intermediaries or even providing insurance to the latter group. We answer this question by comparing public investors’ demand in the markets of SPX verus SPY options. SPY options are options on the SPDR S&P 500 ETF Trust that have a significantly higher percentage of retail customers compared to SPX options. Our results suggest that institutional public investors are the liquidity providers during periods of distress. Our paper builds on and extends the work of Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2009) (henceforth GPP) by incorporating the impact of supply shocks into the options market. In a partial equilibrium setting, GPP demonstrate how exogenous public demand shocks affect option prices when risk-averse dealers bear the inventory risks. In their model, the dealers’ intermediation capacity is fixed, and the model implies a positive relation between the public demand for options and the option premium. Unlike GPP, we consider shocks to the intermediary constraint and the endogenous relations among public demand for options, option pricing, and aggregate market risk premium.2 In the empirical analysis, we try to separate the effects of public demand shocks and shocks to intermediary constraints, and show that the latter is linked to the time-varying risk premia for a wide range of financial assets. Our empirical strategy based on the price-quantity dynamics is motivated by Cohen, Diether, and Malloy (2007), who use a similar strategy to identify demand and supply shocks in the equity shorting market. The recent financial crisis has highlighted the importance of understanding the potential impact of intermediary constraints on the financial markets and the real economy. Following the seminal contributions by Bernanke and Gertler (1989), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), and Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999), other theoretical developments include Gromb and Vayanos (2002), Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), Geanakoplos (2009), He and Krishnamurthy (2013), Adrian and Boyarchenko (2012), Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2014), among others. In contrast to the fast-growing body of theoretical work, there is relatively little empirical work measuring intermediary constraints and studying their aggregate effects on asset prices. The notable exceptions include Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010) and Adrian, Etula, and Muir (2014), who show that changes in aggregate broker-dealer leverage are linked to the time series and cross-section of asset returns. Our paper uses a new venue (the crash insurance market) to capture intermediary constraint variations and study their effects on asset prices. Moreover, compared to intermediary leverage changes, our measure has the advantage of being forward-looking and available at a higher (daily and monthly instead of quarterly) frequency. The ability of option volume to predict returns has been examined in other contexts. Pan and Poteshman (2006) show that option volume predicts near-future individual stock returns (up to 2 weeks). They find the source of this predictability to be the nonpublic information possessed by option traders. Our evidence of return predictability applies to the market index and to longer horizons (up to 4 months), and we argue that the source of this predictability is time-varying intermediary constraints. Finally, several studies have examined the role that derivatives markets play in the aggregate economy. Buraschi and Jiltsov (2006) study option pricing and trading volume when investors have incomplete and heterogeneous information. Bates (2008) shows how options can complete the markets in the presence of crash risk. Longstaff and Wang (2012) show that the credit market plays an important role in facilitating facilitates risk sharing among heterogeneous investors. Chen, Joslin, and Tran (2012) show that the market risk premium is highly sensitive to the amount of sharing of tail risks in at equilibrium. 1. Research Design Our goal is to measure the degree to which financial intermediaries are constrained through the ways they manage their exposures to aggregate tail risks. The market of DOTM SPX put options is well suited for this purpose. First, this market is large in terms of economic exposure to aggregate tail risks.3 Second, compared to other over-the-counter derivatives that also provide exposures to aggregate tail risks, the exchange-traded SPX options have the advantages of better liquidity and almost no counterparty risk (other than exchange failure). Third, the Options Clearing Corporation (OCC) classifies exchange option transactions by investor types, a classification that allows us to determine the net exposures of the financial intermediaries and is essential for constructing our measure. Specifically, the OCC classifies each option transaction as one of three categories based on who initiates the trade. They include public investors, firm investors, and market-makers. Transactions initiated by public investors include those initiated by retail investors and those by institutional investors such as hedge funds. Trades initiated by firm investors are those that securities broker-dealers (who are not designated market-makers) make for their own accounts or for another broker-dealer. Since we focus on financial intermediaries as a whole, it is natural to merge firm investors and market-makers into one group and observe how they trade against public investors. We classify DOTM puts as having a strike-to-price ratio |$K/S \leq 0.85$|⁠. For robustness, we also consider different strike-to-price cutoffs, as well as cutoffs that adjust for option maturity and the volatility of the S&P 500 index (which is similar to cutoffs based on option delta). Another feature of option transaction is that an order can either be an open order (to open new positions) or be a closed order (to close existing positions). We will focus on open orders, because they are less likely to be mechanically influenced by existing positions (see Pan and Poteshman, 2006). We construct a measure of the public net buying-to-open volume for DOTM SPX puts (abbreviated as |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠). In period |$t$| (e.g., a day or a month), |$\textit{PNBO}_t$| is defined as \begin{align} \textit{PBNO}_t \equiv \mbox{public open-buy volume}_t - \mbox{public open-sell volume}_t. \label{eqn.pnbo} \end{align} (1) |$\textit{PNBO}$| represents the amount of new DOTM SPX puts bought (sold if negative) by public investors in a period. Because of the growth in size of the options market, there could be a time trend in the level or volatility of |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. Thus, we also consider normalizing |$\textit{PNBO}$| by the average monthly volume of all SPX options traded by public investors over the past 3 months,4 \begin{align} \textit{PNBON}_t \equiv \frac{\textit{PNBO}_t} {\mbox{Average monthly public SPX volume over past 3 months}}. \label{eqn.pnbon} \end{align} (2) |$\textit{PNBON}$| helps address the potential issue with growth in the size of market, and |$\textit{PNBO}$| better captures the actual magnitude of the tail risk exposures being transferred between public investors and intermediaries. The latter matters for measuring the degree of intermediary constraints. Considering this trade-off, we conduct all of our main analyses using both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. It is well documented (see, e.g., Bollen and Whaley 2004) that, during normal times, public investors are net buyers of index puts, while financial intermediaries are net sellers. All else equal, when financial intermediaries become more constrained, their willingness to supply crash insurance to the market is reduced. It is thus tempting to infer the degree to which financial intermediaries are constrained based on the net amount of crash insurance they sell to public investors each period, as captured by |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. However, besides weak supply from constrained intermediaries, weak public demand can also cause the equilibrium amount of crash insurance traded between public investors and intermediaries to be low. The challenge is to separate the effects of supply from demand. We address this problem in two ways: (1) by exploiting the price-quantity relation to identify periods of “supply environments,” when variations in |$\textit{PNBO}$| are likely to be mainly driven by shocks to intermediary constraints and (2) using the Rigobon (2003) method, which identifies demand and supply by exploiting the heteroscedasticity of shocks. Before presenting the identification methodology, we briefly explain our “price” measure, that is, the expensiveness of SPX options. One would ideally like to calculate the difference between the market price of an option and its hypothetical price without any market frictions. The latter is not observable and can only be approximated by adopting a specific pricing model. For simplicity and robustness, we use the variance premium (⁠|$VP$|⁠) in Bekaert and Hoerova (2014) as a proxy for overall expensiveness of SPX options, which is the difference between |$\rm VIX^2$| and the expected physical variance of the return of the S&P 500 index.5 1.1 Identification through the price-quantity relation Our first empirical strategy is motivated by Cohen, Diether, and Malloy (2007) (CDM), who identify shifts in demand versus supply in the securities shorting market by examining the relation between the changes in the loan fee (price) and the changes in the percentage of outstanding shares on loan (quantity). In their setting, a simultaneous increase (decrease) in the price and quantity indicates at least an increase (decrease) in shorting demand, whereas an increase (decrease) in price coupled with a decrease (increase) in quantity indicates at least a decrease (increase) in shorting supply. The same logic applies to the options market. The demand pressure theory of GPP predicts that a positive exogenous shock to the public demand for DOTM SPX puts forces risk-averse dealers to bear more inventory risks. As a result, the dealers will raise the price of the option (a move along the upward-sloping supply curve). Thus, demand shocks generate a positive relation between changes in prices and in quantities. Alternatively, if intermediation shocks tighten the constraints facing financial intermediaries (e.g., due to a loss of capital or higher capital requirements), they will become less willing to provide crash insurance to public investors. Then the premium for the DOTM SPX puts rises, while the equilibrium quantity of such options traded falls (a move along the downward-sloping demand curve). Different from CDM, we would like to identify periods of weak and strong supply (level), instead of negative or positive supply shocks (changes). For this reason, we cannot directly apply their identification strategy. However, the ability to identify supply and demand shocks is still useful for our setting. Consider a month with low |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. If the price-quantity relations on a daily basis mainly suggest supply shocks in that month, then the low |$\textit{PNBO}$| is more likely to be driven by weak supply instead of weak demand. Based on this idea, we run the following regression using daily data in each month |$t$|⁠: \begin{align} VP_{i(t)} &= a_{VP,t} + b_{VP,t} \ \textit{PNBO}_{i(t)} + d_{VP,t} \ J_{i(t)} + \epsilon^v_{i(t)}, \label{eqn.VP} \end{align} (3) where |$i(t)$| denotes day |$i$| in month |$t$|⁠. The presence of jumps in the underlying stock index can affect |$VP$| even when markets are frictionless. Thus, when examining the relation between |$VP$| and |$PBNO$|⁠, we control for the level of jump risk |$J$| in the S&P 500 index based on the measure of Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold (2007). A negative coefficient |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| in month |$t$| suggests that supply shocks are the dominant driver of price-quantity relations in that month, and we expect |$\textit{PNBO}$| to be informative about the variation in intermediary constraints during such times. |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| does not confirm the existence of supply shock in a particular month and does not rule out the presence of demand shocks in the same month. It does indicate that supply shocks are likely to be more significant relative to demand shocks. Similarly, |$b_{VP,t} > 0$| does not rule out the presence of supply shocks in a month, but demand shocks are likely to be more significant. During such periods, we do not expect |$\textit{PNBO}$| to be informative about supply conditions. Furthermore, we expect high jump risk to amplify the effect of shocks to intermediary constraints on the equilibrium quantity of options traded. This is because a main reason that intermediary constraint matters for their supply of DOTM index puts is the difficulty to hedge the market jump risk embedded in their inventory positions. If public demand does not become more volatile during such times, variations in |$\textit{PNBO}$| will be more informative about shocks to intermediary constraints when jump risk is high. The validity of this assumption is an empirical question. In summary, in a month when the price-quantity relation is on average negative (⁠|$b_{VP,t} < 0$|⁠), we expect small (or negative) value for |$\textit{PNBO}_t$| (cumulative net-buying by public investors for the month) to indicate tight intermediary constraints. 1.2 Identification through heteroscedasticity Besides the identification of “supply environments” based on the price-quantity relation, supply shocks can be identified through econometric identification. One method suited for our study is identification through heteroscedasticity of Rigobon (2003).6Rigobon (2003) considers a standard linear supply-demand relationship between prices (⁠|$p_t$|⁠) and quantities (⁠|$q_t$|⁠): \begin{align} p_t &= b + \beta q_t + \epsilon_t, \quad \textrm{(demand equation),} \label{eqn.generic demand} \\ \end{align} (4a) \begin{align} q_t &= a + \alpha p_t + \eta_t, \quad \textrm{(supply equation),} \label{eqn.generic supply} \end{align} (4b) where the volatilities of the supply and demand shocks are |$\sigma_\epsilon$| and |$\sigma_\eta$|⁠, respectively. In general, the residuals will be correlated with the independent variables in each equation, and the parameters will not be identified. Rigobon (2003) solves this identification problem by considering the regime-dependent heteroscedasticity of |$(\epsilon, \eta)$|⁠. Supposing that there are two regimes and the relative volatilities of the supply and demand shocks vary across the regimes, the supply and demand Equations can be identified. In parallel to our empirical strategy motivated by CDM, we also identify demand and supply shocks following the method of Rigobon (2003). There is suggestive evidence that in the market for DOTM SPX puts supply shocks are more volatile relative to demand shocks during the period of the U.S. financial crisis and the European sovereign debt crisis. We thus date the low- and high-supply volatility regimes accordingly and use the price and quantity measures discussed above to estimate the supply-demand system in Equations (4a) and (4b). The two identification methods presented in Sections 1.1 and 1.2 have their respective advantages. On the one hand, the Rigobon method has the advantage of being based on a clean set of parametric assumptions, a basis that helps with the precise identification of the supply equation and supply shocks. However, these assumptions might be restrictive and potentially inconsistent with the data (e.g., the assumption about the linear relations between prices and quantities, the number of volatility regimes, and whether other parameters might change across these regimes). On the other hand, the method based on price-quantity relation does not identify the supply environment or supply shocks as cleanly, but it imposes weaker assumptions on the demand and supply curve that likely makes the results more robust. After constructing our measures of intermediary constraints, we investigate how these measures are linked to asset prices. According to the theory of financial intermediary constraints (see, e.g., Gromb and Vayanos 2002; He and Krishnamurthy 2013), variations in the aggregate intermediary constraints not only affect option prices but also drive the risk premia of other financial assets. This theory implies that low |$\textit{PNBO}_t$|⁠, when occurring in a period dominated by supply shocks, should imply high future expected excess returns on the market portfolio. That is, we expect |$b^-_r < 0$| in the following predictive regression: \begin{align} r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} &= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t \notag \\ &\quad+ c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} \label{eqn.r1} \end{align} (5) where |$r$| denotes log market excess return, and the notation |${t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| indicates the leading period from |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Similarly, we expect |$\hat \eta_t$| extracted from the supply-demand system in Equations (4a and (4b) to predict future market excess returns as well, \begin{align} r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} &= a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}, \end{align} (6) where we expect |$b_s \leq 0$|⁠. Besides the market portfolio, predictability should apply to other risky assets. Finally, the empirical strategy and testable hypotheses above are mainly based on economic intuition. In the Online Appendix, we present a dynamic general equilibrium model featuring time-varying intermediary constraints. The model not only helps formalize the main intuition but generates more rigorous predictions about how intermediary constraints affect the equilibrium price-quantity dynamics in the crash insurance market, the aggregate risk premium, and intermediary leverage. Moreover, we can use the calibrated model to examine the quantitative effects of intermediary constraints on asset prices. 2. Empirical Results We now present the empirical evidence connecting the option trading activities to the constraints of the financial intermediaries and the risk premia in financial markets. 2.1 Data Figure 1 plots the monthly time series of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and its normalized version |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. Consistent with the findings of Pan and Poteshman (2006) and GPP, the net public purchase of DOTM SPX puts was positive in the majority of the months prior to the financial crisis in 2008, suggesting that broker-dealers and market-makers were mainly supplying crash insurance to public investors. A few notable exceptions include the period around the Asian financial crisis (December 1997), the period around the Russian default, the period around the financial crisis in Latin America (November 1998 to January 1999), the period around the Iraq War (April 2003), and 2 months in 2005 (March and November 2005).7 Figure 1 View largeDownload slide Time series of net public purchase for DOTM SPX puts |$\textit{PNBO}$| is the net amount of deep out-of-the-money (DOTM)(with |$K/S\leq0.85$|⁠) SPX puts public investors buying-to-open each month. |$\textit{PNBON}$| is |$\textit{PNBO}$| normalized by average of previous 3-month total volume from public investors. “Asian” (Oct. 1997): period around the Asian financial crisis. “Russian” (Nov. 1998): period around Russian default. “Iraq” (Apr. 2003): start of the Iraq War. “Quant” (Aug. 2007): the crisis of quant-strategy hedge funds. “Bear Sterns” (Mar. 2008): acquisition of Bear Sterns by J. P. Morgan. “Lehman” (Sept. 2008): Lehman bankruptcy. “TARP” (Oct. 2008): establishment of TARP. “TALF1” (Nov. 2008): creation of TALF. “BoA” (Jan. 2009): Treasury, Fed, and FDIC assistance to Bank of America. “TALF2” (Feb. 2009): increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion. “Euro” (Dec. 2009): escalation of Greek debt crisis. “GB1” (Apr. 2010): Greece seeks financial support from euro and IMF. “EFSF” (May 2010): establishment of EFSM and EFSF; 110 billion bailout package to Greece agreed. “GB2” (Sept. 2010): a second Greek bailout installment. “Voluntary” (Jun. 2011): Merkel agrees to voluntary Greece bondholder role. “Referendum” (Oct. 2011): further escalation of Euro debt crisis with the call for a Greek referendum. Figure 1 View largeDownload slide Time series of net public purchase for DOTM SPX puts |$\textit{PNBO}$| is the net amount of deep out-of-the-money (DOTM)(with |$K/S\leq0.85$|⁠) SPX puts public investors buying-to-open each month. |$\textit{PNBON}$| is |$\textit{PNBO}$| normalized by average of previous 3-month total volume from public investors. “Asian” (Oct. 1997): period around the Asian financial crisis. “Russian” (Nov. 1998): period around Russian default. “Iraq” (Apr. 2003): start of the Iraq War. “Quant” (Aug. 2007): the crisis of quant-strategy hedge funds. “Bear Sterns” (Mar. 2008): acquisition of Bear Sterns by J. P. Morgan. “Lehman” (Sept. 2008): Lehman bankruptcy. “TARP” (Oct. 2008): establishment of TARP. “TALF1” (Nov. 2008): creation of TALF. “BoA” (Jan. 2009): Treasury, Fed, and FDIC assistance to Bank of America. “TALF2” (Feb. 2009): increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion. “Euro” (Dec. 2009): escalation of Greek debt crisis. “GB1” (Apr. 2010): Greece seeks financial support from euro and IMF. “EFSF” (May 2010): establishment of EFSM and EFSF; 110 billion bailout package to Greece agreed. “GB2” (Sept. 2010): a second Greek bailout installment. “Voluntary” (Jun. 2011): Merkel agrees to voluntary Greece bondholder role. “Referendum” (Oct. 2011): further escalation of Euro debt crisis with the call for a Greek referendum. However, starting in 2007, |$\textit{PNBO}$| became significantly more volatile.8 It turned negative during the quant crisis in August 2007, when a host of quant-driven hedge funds experienced significant losses. It then rose significantly and peaked in October 2008, following the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy. As market conditions continued to deteriorate, |$\textit{PNBO}$| plunged rapidly and turned significantly negative in the following months. Following a series of government interventions, |$\textit{PNBO}$| bottomed out in April 2009, rebounded briefly, and then dropped again in December 2009, when the Greek debt crisis escalated. During the period from November 2008 to December 2012, public investors on average sold 44,000 DOTM SPX puts to open new positions each month. In contrast, they bought on average 17,000 DOTM SPX puts each month in the period from 1991 to 2007. One reason that the |$\textit{PNBO}$| series appears more volatile in the latter part of the sample is because the options market (e.g., in terms of total trading volume) had grown significantly over time. As the bottom panel of Figure 1 shows, after normalizing |$\textit{PNBO}$| with the total SPX volume (see the definition in Equation (2)), the |$\textit{PNBON}$| series no longer demonstrates visible trend in volatility. Table 1 reports the summary statistics of the option volume and pricing variables and their correlation coefficients. From January 1991 to December 2012, the public net buying-to-open volume of DOTM SPX puts (⁠|$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) is close to 10,000 contracts per month on average (each contract has a notional size of 100 times the index). In comparison, the average total open interest for all DOTM SPX puts is around 0.9 million contracts during the period from January 1996 to December 2012. This figure highlights the significant difference between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and open interest. The option volume measures have relatively modest autocorrelations at monthly frequency (0.61 for |$\textit{PNBO}$| and 0.48 for |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) compared to standard return predictors such as dividend yield and term spread. The correlation matrix in panel B shows that the various quantity measures are negatively related to variance premium (⁠|$VP$|⁠). In addition, both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| are negatively correlated with the unemployment rate (see Table IA1 in the Online Appendix). Table 1 Summary statistics and correlation A. Summary statistics Mean Median SD AC(1) pp test |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 10.00 9.67 51.12 0.61 0.00 |$\textit{PNBON}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.56 0.53 1.07 0.48 0.00 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 138.08 117.10 113.64 0.76 0.01 |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 28.79 19.85 63.21 0.74 0.00 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.18 0.15 0.36 0.70 0.00 |$J$| (%) 12.14 10.81 6.17 0.62 0.00 |$VP$| 19.37 14.56 21.66 0.54 0.00 A. Summary statistics Mean Median SD AC(1) pp test |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 10.00 9.67 51.12 0.61 0.00 |$\textit{PNBON}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.56 0.53 1.07 0.48 0.00 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 138.08 117.10 113.64 0.76 0.01 |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 28.79 19.85 63.21 0.74 0.00 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.18 0.15 0.36 0.70 0.00 |$J$| (%) 12.14 10.81 6.17 0.62 0.00 |$VP$| 19.37 14.56 21.66 0.54 0.00 B. Correlation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$J$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| 0.71 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| 0.21 0.04 |$\textit{PNOI}$| 0.67 0.48 0.33 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| 0.58 0.59 0.23 0.90 |$\textit{J}$| 0.03 0.03 0.08 0.16 0.12 |$\textit{VP}$| –0.22 –0.15 –0.06 –0.07 –0.09 0.54 B. Correlation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$J$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| 0.71 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| 0.21 0.04 |$\textit{PNOI}$| 0.67 0.48 0.33 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| 0.58 0.59 0.23 0.90 |$\textit{J}$| 0.03 0.03 0.08 0.16 0.12 |$\textit{VP}$| –0.22 –0.15 –0.06 –0.07 –0.09 0.54 This table reports the summary statistics for the SPX options volume from public investors and pricing variables in the empirical analysis. |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠: public net open-buying volume of DOTM puts (⁠|$K/S \leq 0.85$|⁠). |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠: |$\textit{PNBO}$| normalized by average monthly public SPX volume over past 12 months (in million contracts). |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$|⁠: public net open-buying volume of all SPX options excluding DOTM puts. |$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠: public net open interest for DOTM SPX puts (in million contracts). |$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠: |$\textit{PNOI}$| normalized by the total public open interest of all options (long and short). |$J$|⁠: monthly average of the daily physical jump risk measure by Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold (2007). |$VP$|⁠: variance premium based on Bekaert and Hoerova (2014). AC(1) is the first-order autocorrelation for monthly time series; the pp test is the |$p$|-value for the Phillips-Perron test for unit root. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 1 Summary statistics and correlation A. Summary statistics Mean Median SD AC(1) pp test |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 10.00 9.67 51.12 0.61 0.00 |$\textit{PNBON}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.56 0.53 1.07 0.48 0.00 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 138.08 117.10 113.64 0.76 0.01 |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 28.79 19.85 63.21 0.74 0.00 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.18 0.15 0.36 0.70 0.00 |$J$| (%) 12.14 10.81 6.17 0.62 0.00 |$VP$| 19.37 14.56 21.66 0.54 0.00 A. Summary statistics Mean Median SD AC(1) pp test |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 10.00 9.67 51.12 0.61 0.00 |$\textit{PNBON}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.56 0.53 1.07 0.48 0.00 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 138.08 117.10 113.64 0.76 0.01 |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 28.79 19.85 63.21 0.74 0.00 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.18 0.15 0.36 0.70 0.00 |$J$| (%) 12.14 10.81 6.17 0.62 0.00 |$VP$| 19.37 14.56 21.66 0.54 0.00 B. Correlation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$J$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| 0.71 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| 0.21 0.04 |$\textit{PNOI}$| 0.67 0.48 0.33 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| 0.58 0.59 0.23 0.90 |$\textit{J}$| 0.03 0.03 0.08 0.16 0.12 |$\textit{VP}$| –0.22 –0.15 –0.06 –0.07 –0.09 0.54 B. Correlation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$J$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| 0.71 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| 0.21 0.04 |$\textit{PNOI}$| 0.67 0.48 0.33 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| 0.58 0.59 0.23 0.90 |$\textit{J}$| 0.03 0.03 0.08 0.16 0.12 |$\textit{VP}$| –0.22 –0.15 –0.06 –0.07 –0.09 0.54 This table reports the summary statistics for the SPX options volume from public investors and pricing variables in the empirical analysis. |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠: public net open-buying volume of DOTM puts (⁠|$K/S \leq 0.85$|⁠). |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠: |$\textit{PNBO}$| normalized by average monthly public SPX volume over past 12 months (in million contracts). |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$|⁠: public net open-buying volume of all SPX options excluding DOTM puts. |$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠: public net open interest for DOTM SPX puts (in million contracts). |$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠: |$\textit{PNOI}$| normalized by the total public open interest of all options (long and short). |$J$|⁠: monthly average of the daily physical jump risk measure by Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold (2007). |$VP$|⁠: variance premium based on Bekaert and Hoerova (2014). AC(1) is the first-order autocorrelation for monthly time series; the pp test is the |$p$|-value for the Phillips-Perron test for unit root. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Figure 2 provides information about the trading volume of SPX options at different moneyness. Over our entire sample, put options account for 63% of the total trading volume of SPX options. Among put options, out-of-the-money puts account for over 75% of the total trading volume; in particular, DOTM puts (with |$K/S < 0.85$|⁠) account for 23% of the total volume. These statistics demonstrate the importance of the market for DOTM SPX puts. Figure 2 View largeDownload slide Percentage of total put and call volumes at different moneyness This figure plots the total fraction of volume for calls and puts at different levels of moneyness (measure by strike price, |$K$|⁠, divided by spot price |$S$|⁠). The height of each bar indicates the fraction of the total market volume at that moneyness level, while the colors indicate the breakdown within the strike between public (blue) and private (red) orders. Figure 2 View largeDownload slide Percentage of total put and call volumes at different moneyness This figure plots the total fraction of volume for calls and puts at different levels of moneyness (measure by strike price, |$K$|⁠, divided by spot price |$S$|⁠). The height of each bar indicates the fraction of the total market volume at that moneyness level, while the colors indicate the breakdown within the strike between public (blue) and private (red) orders. Although financial intermediaries can partially hedge the risks of their option inventories through dynamic hedging, the hedge is imperfect and costly. This is especially true for DOTM SPX puts, because they are highly sensitive to jump risk, which is difficult to hedge. To demonstrate this point, we regress put option returns on the returns of the corresponding hedging portfolios at both weekly and daily horizons. We consider both delta hedging (using the S&P 500 index) and delta-gamma hedging.9 The |$R^2$| of these regressions demonstrates the effectiveness of the hedging methods. As Table 2 shows, with daily (weekly) rebalancing, delta hedging can capture around 72% (76%) of the return variation of ATM SPX puts, but only 41% (34%) of the return variation of DOTM puts. With delta-gamma hedging, the |$R^2$| for ATM puts can exceed 90%, but it is still below 60% for DOTM puts. These results imply that when holding nonzero inventories of DOTM SPX puts, financial intermediaries will be exposed to significant inventory risks even after dynamically hedging these positions. It is because of such inventory risks that financial intermediaries become more reluctant to supply crash insurance to the public investors when they are more constrained. Table 2 Explaining options returns with hedging portfolios |$\frac{K}{S}<0.85$| |$0.85<\frac{K}{S}<0.95$| |$0.95<\frac{K}{S}<0.99$| |$0.99<\frac{K}{S}<1.01$| delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam Weekly |$R^2$| 0.34 0.54 0.45 0.75 0.59 0.86 0.76 0.91 Daily |$R^2$| 0.41 0.59 0.46 0.74 0.56 0.82 0.72 0.87 |$\frac{K}{S}<0.85$| |$0.85<\frac{K}{S}<0.95$| |$0.95<\frac{K}{S}<0.99$| |$0.99<\frac{K}{S}<1.01$| delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam Weekly |$R^2$| 0.34 0.54 0.45 0.75 0.59 0.86 0.76 0.91 Daily |$R^2$| 0.41 0.59 0.46 0.74 0.56 0.82 0.72 0.87 This table shows the |$R^2$| from regressing option returns on hedging portfolios returns. The dependent variables are the returns of put options with different moneyness. delta denotes the returns on the delta hedging portfolio for the corresponding put option. delt+gam denotes the returns on the delta-gamma hedging portfolio. The sample period is from 1996 to 2012. Table 2 Explaining options returns with hedging portfolios |$\frac{K}{S}<0.85$| |$0.85<\frac{K}{S}<0.95$| |$0.95<\frac{K}{S}<0.99$| |$0.99<\frac{K}{S}<1.01$| delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam Weekly |$R^2$| 0.34 0.54 0.45 0.75 0.59 0.86 0.76 0.91 Daily |$R^2$| 0.41 0.59 0.46 0.74 0.56 0.82 0.72 0.87 |$\frac{K}{S}<0.85$| |$0.85<\frac{K}{S}<0.95$| |$0.95<\frac{K}{S}<0.99$| |$0.99<\frac{K}{S}<1.01$| delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam Weekly |$R^2$| 0.34 0.54 0.45 0.75 0.59 0.86 0.76 0.91 Daily |$R^2$| 0.41 0.59 0.46 0.74 0.56 0.82 0.72 0.87 This table shows the |$R^2$| from regressing option returns on hedging portfolios returns. The dependent variables are the returns of put options with different moneyness. delta denotes the returns on the delta hedging portfolio for the corresponding put option. delt+gam denotes the returns on the delta-gamma hedging portfolio. The sample period is from 1996 to 2012. 2.2 Option volume and the expensiveness of SPX options We start by investigating the link between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and the expensiveness of SPX options as proxied by the variance premium (⁠|$VP$|⁠) in Bekaert and Hoerova (2014). Before constructing the measure |$b_{VP,t}$| in Equation (3) for the price-quantity relation based on daily data, we first examine the relation between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$VP$| at monthly frequency. Table 3 reports the results. In both the cases of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, the coefficient |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| is negative and statistically significant, consistent with the hypothesis that shocks to intermediary constraints generate a negative relation between the equilibrium quantities of DOTM SPX puts that public investors purchase and the expensiveness of SPX options. The coefficient (-94.60) in the univariate regression suggests that a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| is associated with an increase in |$VP$| of 4.82, a 25% increase relative to the average variance premium. Similarly, a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBON}$| is associated with a 3.15 unit increase in |$VP$|⁠. Table 3 |$\textit{PNBO}$| and SPX option expensiveness |$\textit{VP}_{t} = a_{\textit{VP}} + b_{\textit{VP}} \ \textit{PNBO}_{t} + c_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} \times \textit{PNBO}_{t} + d_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} + \epsilon^v_{t}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$a_{\textit{VP}}$| 20.32*** –2.83 –4.80 21.05*** –1.88 –5.92 20.96*** –1.13 –7.08 (2.60) (3.05) (3.17) (3.32) (3.35) (3.45) (3.35) (4.23) (7.40) |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| –94.60** –101.57*** 13.16 –2.94** –3.24*** 4.51 –11.48 –20.22 11.43 (40.18) (24.13) (27.09) (1.39) (1.40) (2.80) (18.16) (13.73) (29.18) |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| –6.83*** –0.57** –2.33 (1.81) (0.24) (2.85) |$d_{\textit{VP}}$| 1.91*** 2.05*** 1.90*** 2.20*** 1.92*** 2.38*** (0.31) (0.32) (0.35) (0.34) (0.38) (0.75) |$R^2$| 4.6 34.1 36.8 1.7 30.9 34.5 0.0 29.5 30.1 |$\textit{VP}_{t} = a_{\textit{VP}} + b_{\textit{VP}} \ \textit{PNBO}_{t} + c_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} \times \textit{PNBO}_{t} + d_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} + \epsilon^v_{t}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$a_{\textit{VP}}$| 20.32*** –2.83 –4.80 21.05*** –1.88 –5.92 20.96*** –1.13 –7.08 (2.60) (3.05) (3.17) (3.32) (3.35) (3.45) (3.35) (4.23) (7.40) |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| –94.60** –101.57*** 13.16 –2.94** –3.24*** 4.51 –11.48 –20.22 11.43 (40.18) (24.13) (27.09) (1.39) (1.40) (2.80) (18.16) (13.73) (29.18) |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| –6.83*** –0.57** –2.33 (1.81) (0.24) (2.85) |$d_{\textit{VP}}$| 1.91*** 2.05*** 1.90*** 2.20*** 1.92*** 2.38*** (0.31) (0.32) (0.35) (0.34) (0.38) (0.75) |$R^2$| 4.6 34.1 36.8 1.7 30.9 34.5 0.0 29.5 30.1 The dependent variable is |${\textit{VP}}$|⁠. We use three different measures of the public net-buying volumes: |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, and |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (public net buying volume of all SPX options excluding deep out-of-the-money puts). Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the Newey and West (1987) method with 6 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 3 |$\textit{PNBO}$| and SPX option expensiveness |$\textit{VP}_{t} = a_{\textit{VP}} + b_{\textit{VP}} \ \textit{PNBO}_{t} + c_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} \times \textit{PNBO}_{t} + d_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} + \epsilon^v_{t}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$a_{\textit{VP}}$| 20.32*** –2.83 –4.80 21.05*** –1.88 –5.92 20.96*** –1.13 –7.08 (2.60) (3.05) (3.17) (3.32) (3.35) (3.45) (3.35) (4.23) (7.40) |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| –94.60** –101.57*** 13.16 –2.94** –3.24*** 4.51 –11.48 –20.22 11.43 (40.18) (24.13) (27.09) (1.39) (1.40) (2.80) (18.16) (13.73) (29.18) |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| –6.83*** –0.57** –2.33 (1.81) (0.24) (2.85) |$d_{\textit{VP}}$| 1.91*** 2.05*** 1.90*** 2.20*** 1.92*** 2.38*** (0.31) (0.32) (0.35) (0.34) (0.38) (0.75) |$R^2$| 4.6 34.1 36.8 1.7 30.9 34.5 0.0 29.5 30.1 |$\textit{VP}_{t} = a_{\textit{VP}} + b_{\textit{VP}} \ \textit{PNBO}_{t} + c_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} \times \textit{PNBO}_{t} + d_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} + \epsilon^v_{t}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$a_{\textit{VP}}$| 20.32*** –2.83 –4.80 21.05*** –1.88 –5.92 20.96*** –1.13 –7.08 (2.60) (3.05) (3.17) (3.32) (3.35) (3.45) (3.35) (4.23) (7.40) |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| –94.60** –101.57*** 13.16 –2.94** –3.24*** 4.51 –11.48 –20.22 11.43 (40.18) (24.13) (27.09) (1.39) (1.40) (2.80) (18.16) (13.73) (29.18) |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| –6.83*** –0.57** –2.33 (1.81) (0.24) (2.85) |$d_{\textit{VP}}$| 1.91*** 2.05*** 1.90*** 2.20*** 1.92*** 2.38*** (0.31) (0.32) (0.35) (0.34) (0.38) (0.75) |$R^2$| 4.6 34.1 36.8 1.7 30.9 34.5 0.0 29.5 30.1 The dependent variable is |${\textit{VP}}$|⁠. We use three different measures of the public net-buying volumes: |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, and |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (public net buying volume of all SPX options excluding deep out-of-the-money puts). Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the Newey and West (1987) method with 6 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. After adding the interaction between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and the jump risk measure |$J$| into the regression, the coefficient |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| of the interaction term is significantly negative, which implies that |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$VP$| are more likely to be negatively related during times of high jump risk, and that their relation can turn positive when jump risk is sufficiently low. To understand the economic magnitude of the coefficient |$c_{\textit{VP}}$|⁠, we can compare how the marginal effect of |$\textit{PNBO}$| on |$VP$|⁠, |$b_{\textit{VP}} + c_{\textit{VP}} J$|⁠, changes for different levels of jump risk. Our estimates imply that a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| is associated with an increase in |$VP$| of 1.41 when |$J$| is one standard deviation below its mean, while the increase in |$VP$| is 5.71 when |$J$| is one standard deviation above its mean. Similar calculations show that the marginal effect of |$\textit{PNBON}$| on |$VP$| is even more sensitive to |$J$|⁠. The result is again consistent with the intermediary constraint theory, as the effects of shocks to intermediary constraints on the supply of DOTM SPX puts by financial intermediaries tend to strengthen when the aggregate tail risk is high. In contrast, when we replace |$\textit{PNBO}$| with the public net buying volume for all other SPX options excluding DOTM puts (⁠|$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$|⁠), not only are the |$R^2$| of the regressions smaller but the regression coefficients |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| and |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| are no longer significantly different from zero. As we have demonstrated in Table 2, DOTM SPX puts are more difficult to hedge and hence expose intermediaries to higher inventory risks. Thus, the trading activities of DOTM SPX puts are likely to be more informative about the fluctuations in intermediary constraints compared to those for other options. Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2009) show that exogenous public demand shocks can generate a positive relation between net public demand for index options and measures of option expensiveness. They find support for this prediction using data from October 1997 to December 2001. Bollen and Whaley (2004) also find evidence of the effects of public demand pressure on option pricing in daily data. Our results above are not a rejection of the effect of demand shocks on option prices. In Appendix 3.5, we replicate the results of Table 2 in GPP and show that the different time periods is the main reason for the opposite signs of the price-quantity relation in the two papers. Conceptually, the demand pressure theory and the intermediary constraint theory share the common assumption of constrained intermediaries, and both can be at work in the data. For instance, our results in Table 3 show that the price-quantity relation is more likely to be negative (positive) when the jump risk in the market is high (low), indicating that the supply (demand) effects tend to become dominant under such conditions. Next, we estimate the monthly price-quantity relation measure |$b_{VP,t}$| from regression (3) using daily data. The fact that demand effects and supply effects are both present in the data is again evident. Out of 264 months, the coefficient |$b_{VP,t}$| is negative in 159 (significant at 5% level in 44 of them), and positive in 105 (significant at 5% level in 24 of them). These statistics suggest that, according to the price-quantity relation, shocks to intermediary constraints are present in a significant part of our sample period. The months that have significantly negative price-quantity relations include periods in the Asian financial crisis, Russian default, the 2008 financial crisis, and several episodes during the European debt crisis.10 2.3 Option volume and risk premia We now examine the predictions from Section 1 linking |$\textit{PNBO}$| and risk premia in the financial markets. For initial exploration, we run the basic univariate return-forecasting regression using |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. Table 4 shows that |$\textit{PNBO}$| has strong predictive power for future market excess returns up to 4 months ahead. The coefficient estimate |$b_r$| for predicting 1-month-ahead market excess returns is |$-24.26$| (⁠|$t$|-stat of |$-3.45$|⁠),11 with |$R^2$| of |$7.7%$|⁠. For 4-month ahead returns (⁠|$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$|⁠), the coefficient estimate is |$-18.05$| and statistically significant (⁠|$t$|-stat of |$-2.36$|⁠), and |$R^2$| drops to |$4.3%$|⁠. From 5 months out, the predictive coefficient is no longer statistically significant. When we aggregate the effect for the cumulative market excess returns in the next 3 months, the coefficient |$b_r$| is |$-67.16$| (⁠|$t$|-stat of |$-3.54$|⁠) and |$R^2$| is |$18.0%$|⁠. The economic significance that this coefficient estimate implies is striking. A one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| is associated with a |$3.4%$| (nonannualized) increase in the future 3-month market excess return. Table 4 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –24.26*** (7.04) 7.7 –0.92*** (0.32) 4.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.03*** (6.79) 4.8 –0.65** (0.28) 2.5 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –23.86*** (7.64) 7.5 –0.75*** (0.29) 3.2 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –18.05** (7.65) 4.3 –0.62** (0.29) 2.2 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –67.16*** (18.96) 18.0 –2.32*** (0.75) 9.4 |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –24.26*** (7.04) 7.7 –0.92*** (0.32) 4.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.03*** (6.79) 4.8 –0.65** (0.28) 2.5 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –23.86*** (7.64) 7.5 –0.75*** (0.29) 3.2 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –18.05** (7.65) 4.3 –0.62** (0.29) 2.2 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –67.16*** (18.96) 18.0 –2.32*** (0.75) 9.4 This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} $| represents log market excess return from month |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 4 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –24.26*** (7.04) 7.7 –0.92*** (0.32) 4.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.03*** (6.79) 4.8 –0.65** (0.28) 2.5 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –23.86*** (7.64) 7.5 –0.75*** (0.29) 3.2 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –18.05** (7.65) 4.3 –0.62** (0.29) 2.2 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –67.16*** (18.96) 18.0 –2.32*** (0.75) 9.4 |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –24.26*** (7.04) 7.7 –0.92*** (0.32) 4.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.03*** (6.79) 4.8 –0.65** (0.28) 2.5 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –23.86*** (7.64) 7.5 –0.75*** (0.29) 3.2 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –18.05** (7.65) 4.3 –0.62** (0.29) 2.2 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –67.16*** (18.96) 18.0 –2.32*** (0.75) 9.4 This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} $| represents log market excess return from month |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Figure 1 indicates that nonstationarity might be a potential concern for |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. The autocorrelation of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is only 0.61 and a Phillips-Perron test strongly rejects the null of a unit root (see Table 1). However, nonstationarity may arise elsewhere, e.g., through the 2nd moment. For this reason, we also use the normalized |$\textit{PNBO}$| to predict market excess returns. Table 4 shows that, like |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, |$\textit{PNBON}$| also predicts future market returns negatively. The coefficient estimate |$b_r$| remains statistically significant up to 4 months ahead, but with lower |$R^2$| than |$\textit{PNBO}$| at all horizons. The difference in |$R^2$| between |$\textit{PNBON}$| and |$\textit{PNBO}$| shows that we should interpret the high |$R^2$| for |$\textit{PNBO}$| with caution, which could partially be due to its volatility trend. As for economic significance, a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBON}$| is associated with a |$2.5%$| increase in the future 3-month market excess return.12 While |$\textit{PNBO}$| shows predictive power for market risk premia in the full sample, theories of intermediary constraints imply that the predictive power should be concentrated in periods when variations in |$\textit{PNBO}$| are mainly driven by changes in supply conditions. In Section 1, we have proposed to identify supply environments based on the negative price-quantity relation (⁠|$b_{VP,t} < 0$|⁠), and we expect high level of jump risks (⁠|$J_t$|⁠) to also help with identifying such environments under certain assumptions. Next, we examine how the predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| changes in the subsamples identified by |$b_{VP,t}$| and |$J_t$|⁠. Table 5 shows that the predictive power of both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| are indeed stronger (in terms of both economic and statistical significance) during the periods of negative price-quantity relation and during periods of high jump risks. For example, when |$b_{VP,t} < 0$|⁠, a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) is associated with a |$4.1%$| (⁠|$3.0%$|⁠) increase in the future 3-month market excess return. The coefficient for |$\textit{PNBO}$| becomes considerably smaller in the subsample when |$b_{VP,t}$| is positive, and it becomes insignificant for |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. Table 5 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠: Subsample results |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Subsample |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| obs |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| –84.75*** (26.16) 24.7 –2.67*** (0.85) 12.3 159 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0$| –42.46** (19.65) 9.2 –1.58 (1.01) 4.3 105 |$J_t \geq \bar J$| –87.49*** (26.26) 26.8 –3.08*** (0.98) 13.0 132 |$J_t < \bar J$| –33.80* (17.93) 6.0 –1.47* (0.81) 5.6 132 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –114.11*** (42.65) 32.4 –3.55*** (1.19) 14.2 80 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t < \bar J$| –53.19*** (18.61) 16.3 –1.95** (0.91) 12.1 79 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –60.98*** (22.39) 20.8 –2.36** (1.16) 10.5 52 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t < \bar J$| 17.53 (37.12) 1.3 0.50 (1.74) 0.4 53 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Subsample |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| obs |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| –84.75*** (26.16) 24.7 –2.67*** (0.85) 12.3 159 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0$| –42.46** (19.65) 9.2 –1.58 (1.01) 4.3 105 |$J_t \geq \bar J$| –87.49*** (26.26) 26.8 –3.08*** (0.98) 13.0 132 |$J_t < \bar J$| –33.80* (17.93) 6.0 –1.47* (0.81) 5.6 132 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –114.11*** (42.65) 32.4 –3.55*** (1.19) 14.2 80 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t < \bar J$| –53.19*** (18.61) 16.3 –1.95** (0.91) 12.1 79 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –60.98*** (22.39) 20.8 –2.36** (1.16) 10.5 52 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t < \bar J$| 17.53 (37.12) 1.3 0.50 (1.74) 0.4 53 This table reports the subsample results of the 3-month return forecasting regressions. Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 5 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠: Subsample results |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Subsample |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| obs |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| –84.75*** (26.16) 24.7 –2.67*** (0.85) 12.3 159 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0$| –42.46** (19.65) 9.2 –1.58 (1.01) 4.3 105 |$J_t \geq \bar J$| –87.49*** (26.26) 26.8 –3.08*** (0.98) 13.0 132 |$J_t < \bar J$| –33.80* (17.93) 6.0 –1.47* (0.81) 5.6 132 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –114.11*** (42.65) 32.4 –3.55*** (1.19) 14.2 80 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t < \bar J$| –53.19*** (18.61) 16.3 –1.95** (0.91) 12.1 79 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –60.98*** (22.39) 20.8 –2.36** (1.16) 10.5 52 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t < \bar J$| 17.53 (37.12) 1.3 0.50 (1.74) 0.4 53 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Subsample |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| obs |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| –84.75*** (26.16) 24.7 –2.67*** (0.85) 12.3 159 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0$| –42.46** (19.65) 9.2 –1.58 (1.01) 4.3 105 |$J_t \geq \bar J$| –87.49*** (26.26) 26.8 –3.08*** (0.98) 13.0 132 |$J_t < \bar J$| –33.80* (17.93) 6.0 –1.47* (0.81) 5.6 132 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –114.11*** (42.65) 32.4 –3.55*** (1.19) 14.2 80 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t < \bar J$| –53.19*** (18.61) 16.3 –1.95** (0.91) 12.1 79 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –60.98*** (22.39) 20.8 –2.36** (1.16) 10.5 52 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t < \bar J$| 17.53 (37.12) 1.3 0.50 (1.74) 0.4 53 This table reports the subsample results of the 3-month return forecasting regressions. Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. We then further split the full sample into 4 subsample periods based on the two criteria (⁠|$b_{VP,t} < (\geq) 0$|⁠, |$J_t < (\geq) \bar J$|⁠).13Table 5 shows that for both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, the predictive power is the strongest when |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| and the level of jump risk is high. If |$b_{\textit{VP}} \geq 0$| and jump risk is low, then the coefficient |$b_r$| becomes positive and insignificant for both measures, and the |$R^2$| drops to near zero. In summary, the subsample results suggest that our strategy based on the price-quantity relation does a good job identifying those periods when |$\textit{PNBO}$| are connected to variations in intermediary constraints and in turn the conditional market risk premia. For the remainder of the paper, we use the regression specification (5), which summarizes the subsample results succinctly. To investigate whether the predictability results above are useful in forming real-time forecasts, we follow Welch and Goyal (2008) and compute the out-of-sample |$R^2$| for |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| based on various sample-split dates, starting in January 1996 (implying a minimum estimation period of 5 years) and ending in December 2007 (with a minimum evaluation period of 5 years). We consider the wide range of sample-split dates because recent studies suggest that sample splits themselves can be data-mined (Hansen and Timmermann (2012)). In forming the return forecasts, we first estimate the predictability regression (5) during the estimation period (from date |$1$| to |$t$|⁠), and then use the estimated coefficients to forecast the 3-month future market excess return for |$t+1$|⁠. After obtaining all the return forecasts, we then compute the mean squared forecast errors for the predictability model (⁠|$MSE_A$|⁠) and the historical mean model (⁠|$MSE_N$|⁠) in various evaluation periods that begin at the sample-split dates and end at the end of the full sample. The out-of-sample |$R^2$| is given by \[ \widehat{R}^2 = 1 - \frac{\textit{MSE}_A}{\textit{MSE}_N}. \] Panel A of Figure 3 shows the results. |$\textit{PNBO}$| achieves an out-of-sample |$R^2$| above 10% for all the sample splits and remains above 20% from 2003 onward. |$\textit{PNBON}$| has an an out-of-sample |$R^2$| above 5% for all the sample splits and remains above 10% in the later period. All of the out-of-sample |$R^2$| are significant at the 5% level (1% level since 2000) based on the MSE-F statistic by McCracken (2007). Figure 3 View largeDownload slide Out-of-sample |$R^{2}$| and |$R^{2}$| from 5-year moving-window regressions This figures plots the out-of-sample |$R^2$| and |$R^{2}$| of 5-year moving windows from forecasting 3-month market excess returns based on the specification of (5). Panel A plots the out-of-sample |$R^{2}$| as a function of the sample split date. Panel B plots the in-sample |$R^2$| as a function of the end of 5-year moving windows. Figure 3 View largeDownload slide Out-of-sample |$R^{2}$| and |$R^{2}$| from 5-year moving-window regressions This figures plots the out-of-sample |$R^2$| and |$R^{2}$| of 5-year moving windows from forecasting 3-month market excess returns based on the specification of (5). Panel A plots the out-of-sample |$R^{2}$| as a function of the sample split date. Panel B plots the in-sample |$R^2$| as a function of the end of 5-year moving windows. Panel B of Figure 3 plots the in-sample |$R^2$| from the predictive regressions of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| using 5-year moving windows. The two |$R^2$|s vary significantly over time. They are low at the beginning of the sample. Both |$R^2$| rise to near 18% in the period around the Asian financial crisis and Russian default in 1997–1998. During the 2008–2009 financial crisis period, the |$R^2$| rise above 40%. These high |$R^2$| for the return-forecasting regressions would translate into striking Sharpe ratios for investment strategies that try to exploit such predictability. For example, Cochrane (1999) shows that the best unconditional Sharpe ratio |$s^{\ast}$| for a market timing strategy is related to the predictability regression |$R^2$| by \begin{align*} s^{\ast} =\frac{\sqrt{s_0^2 +R^2}}{\sqrt{1-R^2}}, \end{align*} where |$s_0$| is the unconditional Sharpe ratio of a buy-and-hold strategy. Assuming the Sharpe ratio of the market portfolio is 0.5, then an |$R^2$| of 40% implies a Sharpe ratio for the market timing strategy that exceeds 1. Such high Sharpe ratios could persist during the financial crisis because of the presence of severe financial constraints that prevent arbitrageurs from taking advantage of the investment opportunities. Theories of intermediary constraints argue that variations in the constraints not only affect the risk premium of the market portfolio but also the risk premia on any financial assets for which the financial intermediaries are the marginal investor. Having examined the ability of |$\textit{PNBO}$| to predict future market excess returns, we now apply the predictability regressions to other asset classes. Among the assets we consider are (1) high-yield corporate bonds (based on the Barclays U.S. Corporate High Yield total return index), (2) hedge funds (based on the HFRI fund-weighted average return index), (3) carry trade (constructed by Lustig, Roussanov, and Verdelhan 2011 using the exchange rates of 15 developed countries), (4) commodity (based on the Goldman Sachs commodity index excess return series), (5) the 10-year U.S. Treasury, and (6) variance swap for the S&P 500 index returns (with the excess return defined as the log ratio of the realized annualized return variance over the swap rate; see, e.g., Carr and Wu 2009).14 As benchmark, the first row of Table 6 restates the predictability results for equity (market excess returns). It then shows that, our constraint measures predict the future excess returns for a variety of assets besides equity. In periods with |$b_{VP,t}<0$|⁠, |$\textit{PNBO}$| predicts negatively and statistically significantly (at least at the 10% level) the future 3-month returns of high yield bonds, hedge funds, carry trade, and commodity (for |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, the coefficient |$b_r^-$| for carry trade and commodity returns are still negative but insignificant). Thus, like the market portfolio, the risk premia on these assets tend to rise when the intermediary constraints tighten. The predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| on these asset returns is also economically significant. For example, in a supply environment, a one-standard-deviation decrease of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is associated with a 2.8% and 1.6% increase in the subsequent 3-month expected excess returns of the high-yield bond index and the hedge fund index, respectively. Table 6 Return forecasts for various financial assets |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| Asset class |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Equity –84.75*** –42.46** 19.8 –2.67*** –1.58 9.9 (26.16) (19.65) (0.85) (1.01) High yield –55.23*** –35.26** 22.2 –1.37*** –1.99*** 11.0 (21.37) (15.55) (0.50) (0.66) Hedge fund –32.48*** –18.98* 11.6 –1.01*** –0.40 5.4 (10.67) (9.82) (0.33) (0.44) Carry trade –38.34** –23.10 9.1 –0.47 –0.88 2.0 (18.13) (14.20) (0.43) (0.62) Commodity –71.54* –43.70 8.1 –1.30 –1.80 2.3 (42.26) (30.19) (0.94) (1.34) 10-year Treasury 20.57** 10.76 5.5 0.79** 0.37 3.8 (8.92) (10.65) (0.33) (0.45) Variance swap (⁠|$\times 1{\%}$|⁠) 13.64*** 4.82** 21.2 0.38*** 0.25** 9.5 (4.02) (2.16) (0.11) (0.11) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| Asset class |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Equity –84.75*** –42.46** 19.8 –2.67*** –1.58 9.9 (26.16) (19.65) (0.85) (1.01) High yield –55.23*** –35.26** 22.2 –1.37*** –1.99*** 11.0 (21.37) (15.55) (0.50) (0.66) Hedge fund –32.48*** –18.98* 11.6 –1.01*** –0.40 5.4 (10.67) (9.82) (0.33) (0.44) Carry trade –38.34** –23.10 9.1 –0.47 –0.88 2.0 (18.13) (14.20) (0.43) (0.62) Commodity –71.54* –43.70 8.1 –1.30 –1.80 2.3 (42.26) (30.19) (0.94) (1.34) 10-year Treasury 20.57** 10.76 5.5 0.79** 0.37 3.8 (8.92) (10.65) (0.33) (0.45) Variance swap (⁠|$\times 1{\%}$|⁠) 13.64*** 4.82** 21.2 0.38*** 0.25** 9.5 (4.02) (2.16) (0.11) (0.11) This table reports the results of forecasting future excess returns on a variety of assets. All excess returns are in percentages except those for variance swap, which are divided by 100 for scaling. Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 6 Return forecasts for various financial assets |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| Asset class |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Equity –84.75*** –42.46** 19.8 –2.67*** –1.58 9.9 (26.16) (19.65) (0.85) (1.01) High yield –55.23*** –35.26** 22.2 –1.37*** –1.99*** 11.0 (21.37) (15.55) (0.50) (0.66) Hedge fund –32.48*** –18.98* 11.6 –1.01*** –0.40 5.4 (10.67) (9.82) (0.33) (0.44) Carry trade –38.34** –23.10 9.1 –0.47 –0.88 2.0 (18.13) (14.20) (0.43) (0.62) Commodity –71.54* –43.70 8.1 –1.30 –1.80 2.3 (42.26) (30.19) (0.94) (1.34) 10-year Treasury 20.57** 10.76 5.5 0.79** 0.37 3.8 (8.92) (10.65) (0.33) (0.45) Variance swap (⁠|$\times 1{\%}$|⁠) 13.64*** 4.82** 21.2 0.38*** 0.25** 9.5 (4.02) (2.16) (0.11) (0.11) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| Asset class |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Equity –84.75*** –42.46** 19.8 –2.67*** –1.58 9.9 (26.16) (19.65) (0.85) (1.01) High yield –55.23*** –35.26** 22.2 –1.37*** –1.99*** 11.0 (21.37) (15.55) (0.50) (0.66) Hedge fund –32.48*** –18.98* 11.6 –1.01*** –0.40 5.4 (10.67) (9.82) (0.33) (0.44) Carry trade –38.34** –23.10 9.1 –0.47 –0.88 2.0 (18.13) (14.20) (0.43) (0.62) Commodity –71.54* –43.70 8.1 –1.30 –1.80 2.3 (42.26) (30.19) (0.94) (1.34) 10-year Treasury 20.57** 10.76 5.5 0.79** 0.37 3.8 (8.92) (10.65) (0.33) (0.45) Variance swap (⁠|$\times 1{\%}$|⁠) 13.64*** 4.82** 21.2 0.38*** 0.25** 9.5 (4.02) (2.16) (0.11) (0.11) This table reports the results of forecasting future excess returns on a variety of assets. All excess returns are in percentages except those for variance swap, which are divided by 100 for scaling. Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Next, both for |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, the predictive coefficient |$b_r^-$| is positive and significant for the 3-month excess returns of the 10-year Treasury and the S&P 500 variance swap. Here, a one-standard-deviation decrease of |$\textit{PNBO}$| in a supply environment is associated with a 1% and 68% decrease in the subsequent 3-month expected excess returns of 10-year Treasuries and variance swaps, respectively. The result on Treasuries is consistent with Fontaine and Garcia (2012), who find the deterioration in funding liquidity predicts lower risk premia for Treasuries. Intuitively, when financial intermediaries become constrained, Treasury values tend to rise (“flight to quality”) as does the volatility in the market. Thus, Treasuries and (pay-fix) variance swaps provide a hedge against negative shocks to intermediary constraints. 2.4 An alternative hypothesis The above return predictability results have two alternative interpretations. It is possible that financial intermediaries become more constrained when the market risk premium rises (e.g., due to higher aggregate uncertainty in the real economy), which in turn reduces their capacity to provide market crash insurance to public investors. As a result, a low |$\textit{PNBO}$| today would be associated with high future market returns, even though a tighter intermediary constraint does not cause the market risk premium to rise in this case. Alternatively, it is possible that intermediary constraints directly affect the aggregate market risk premium, which is a central prediction in intermediary asset pricing theories. To distinguish between these two interpretations, we compare |$\textit{PNBO}$| against a number of financial and macro variables that have been shown to predict market returns. If |$\textit{PNBO}$| is merely correlated with the standard risk factors and does not directly affect the risk premium, then the inclusion of the proper risk factors into the predictability regression should drive away the predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. The variables we consider include the difference between implied and historical volatility used in Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) (⁠|$IVRV$|⁠), the log dividend yield (⁠|$d-p$|⁠) of the market portfolio, the log net payout yield (lcrspnpy) by Boudoukh, Michaely, Richardson, and Roberts (2007), the Baa-Aaa credit spread (DEF), the 10-year minus 3-month Treasury term spread (TERM), the tail risk measure (Tail) by Kelly and Jiang (2014), the slope of the implied volatility curve (IVSlope), and the consumption-wealth ratio measure (⁠|$\widehat{cay}$|⁠) by Lettau and Ludvigson (2001). All the variables are available monthly except for |$\widehat{cay}$|⁠, which is at quarterly frequency. Table 7 shows that, with the inclusion of the various competing variables, the predictive coefficient |$b_r^-$| remains significantly negative and remarkably stable in magnitude for both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. Comparing the |$R^2$| from the regressions in Table 7 and the regression with only |$\textit{PNBO}$| (or |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) (first row, Table 6), we see that the incremental explanatory power for future market excess returns mostly comes from |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) interacted with the price-quantity relation indicator.15 Table 7 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and other predictors |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t}<0\}} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| A. PNBO |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –77.22*** –82.44*** –94.46*** –85.81*** –87.33*** –90.86*** –75.80*** –80.13*** –62.70*** (26.09) (26.66) (30.95) (26.61) (26.96) (31.35) (24.59) (31.40) (22.71) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –18.50 –37.81* –47.38** –44.73** –46.26** –47.54** –36.40* –14.42 –59.22 (20.16) (20.21) (22.76) (21.02) (20.32) (22.94) (19.84) (27.59) (37.45) IVRV 0.10*** 0.13*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.54 11.39 (3.20) (7.75) lcrspnpy 6.19 7.75 (4.89) (8.10) DEF –1.58 –5.96 (3.03) (3.83) Term –0.63 –0.63 (0.71) (0.83) Tail 30.56 –52.06 (35.02) (47.76) IVSlope 0.29 0.17 (0.26) (0.29) |$\widehat{cay}$| 92.71** (46.30) |$R^2$| 25.2 21.3 22.9 20.4 20.6 20.8 22.4 39.2 19.9 B. PNBON |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –2.50*** –2.42*** –2.47*** –2.70 *** –2.65*** –2.56*** –2.63*** –2.06*** –2.07** (0.85) (0.85) (0.89) (0.86) (0.85) (0.89) (1.00) (1.08) (0.86) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –0.85 –1.20 –1.41 –1.78 –1.61 –1.60 –1.17 0.06 –4.81* (1.01) (1.05) (1.12) (1.08) (1.02) (1.11) (1.08) (1.32) (2.60) IVRV 0.13*** 0.15*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.13 13.63 (3.17) (7.42) lcrspnpy 3.13 1.51 (5.02) (7.92) DEF –1.71 –5.57 (3.03) (3.89) Term –0.27 –0.10 (0.67) (0.85) Tail 26.94 –38.27 (34.87) (46.84) IVSlope 0.36 0.33 (0.28) (0.31) |$\widehat{cay}$| 108.03** (46.11) |$R^2$| 19.2 10.7 9.7 10.3 9.7 9.7 14.5 32.5 17.7 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t}<0\}} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| A. PNBO |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –77.22*** –82.44*** –94.46*** –85.81*** –87.33*** –90.86*** –75.80*** –80.13*** –62.70*** (26.09) (26.66) (30.95) (26.61) (26.96) (31.35) (24.59) (31.40) (22.71) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –18.50 –37.81* –47.38** –44.73** –46.26** –47.54** –36.40* –14.42 –59.22 (20.16) (20.21) (22.76) (21.02) (20.32) (22.94) (19.84) (27.59) (37.45) IVRV 0.10*** 0.13*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.54 11.39 (3.20) (7.75) lcrspnpy 6.19 7.75 (4.89) (8.10) DEF –1.58 –5.96 (3.03) (3.83) Term –0.63 –0.63 (0.71) (0.83) Tail 30.56 –52.06 (35.02) (47.76) IVSlope 0.29 0.17 (0.26) (0.29) |$\widehat{cay}$| 92.71** (46.30) |$R^2$| 25.2 21.3 22.9 20.4 20.6 20.8 22.4 39.2 19.9 B. PNBON |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –2.50*** –2.42*** –2.47*** –2.70 *** –2.65*** –2.56*** –2.63*** –2.06*** –2.07** (0.85) (0.85) (0.89) (0.86) (0.85) (0.89) (1.00) (1.08) (0.86) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –0.85 –1.20 –1.41 –1.78 –1.61 –1.60 –1.17 0.06 –4.81* (1.01) (1.05) (1.12) (1.08) (1.02) (1.11) (1.08) (1.32) (2.60) IVRV 0.13*** 0.15*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.13 13.63 (3.17) (7.42) lcrspnpy 3.13 1.51 (5.02) (7.92) DEF –1.71 –5.57 (3.03) (3.89) Term –0.27 –0.10 (0.67) (0.85) Tail 26.94 –38.27 (34.87) (46.84) IVSlope 0.36 0.33 (0.28) (0.31) |$\widehat{cay}$| 108.03** (46.11) |$R^2$| 19.2 10.7 9.7 10.3 9.7 9.7 14.5 32.5 17.7 The table reports the results of forecasting 3-month market excess returns with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and other predictors, including the difference between implied and historical volatility in Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) (IVRV), log dividend yield (⁠|$d-p$|⁠), log net payout yield (lcrspnpy), Baa-Aaa credit spread (DEF), term spread (TERM), tail risk measure (Tail), implied volatility slope (Slope), and the quarterly consumption-wealth ratio (⁠|$\widehat{cay}$|⁠). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from 1991 to 2012, except for lcrspnpy and Tail, which is from 1991 to 2010, and IVSlope, which is from 1996 to 2012. Table 7 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and other predictors |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t}<0\}} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| A. PNBO |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –77.22*** –82.44*** –94.46*** –85.81*** –87.33*** –90.86*** –75.80*** –80.13*** –62.70*** (26.09) (26.66) (30.95) (26.61) (26.96) (31.35) (24.59) (31.40) (22.71) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –18.50 –37.81* –47.38** –44.73** –46.26** –47.54** –36.40* –14.42 –59.22 (20.16) (20.21) (22.76) (21.02) (20.32) (22.94) (19.84) (27.59) (37.45) IVRV 0.10*** 0.13*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.54 11.39 (3.20) (7.75) lcrspnpy 6.19 7.75 (4.89) (8.10) DEF –1.58 –5.96 (3.03) (3.83) Term –0.63 –0.63 (0.71) (0.83) Tail 30.56 –52.06 (35.02) (47.76) IVSlope 0.29 0.17 (0.26) (0.29) |$\widehat{cay}$| 92.71** (46.30) |$R^2$| 25.2 21.3 22.9 20.4 20.6 20.8 22.4 39.2 19.9 B. PNBON |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –2.50*** –2.42*** –2.47*** –2.70 *** –2.65*** –2.56*** –2.63*** –2.06*** –2.07** (0.85) (0.85) (0.89) (0.86) (0.85) (0.89) (1.00) (1.08) (0.86) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –0.85 –1.20 –1.41 –1.78 –1.61 –1.60 –1.17 0.06 –4.81* (1.01) (1.05) (1.12) (1.08) (1.02) (1.11) (1.08) (1.32) (2.60) IVRV 0.13*** 0.15*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.13 13.63 (3.17) (7.42) lcrspnpy 3.13 1.51 (5.02) (7.92) DEF –1.71 –5.57 (3.03) (3.89) Term –0.27 –0.10 (0.67) (0.85) Tail 26.94 –38.27 (34.87) (46.84) IVSlope 0.36 0.33 (0.28) (0.31) |$\widehat{cay}$| 108.03** (46.11) |$R^2$| 19.2 10.7 9.7 10.3 9.7 9.7 14.5 32.5 17.7 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t}<0\}} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| A. PNBO |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –77.22*** –82.44*** –94.46*** –85.81*** –87.33*** –90.86*** –75.80*** –80.13*** –62.70*** (26.09) (26.66) (30.95) (26.61) (26.96) (31.35) (24.59) (31.40) (22.71) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –18.50 –37.81* –47.38** –44.73** –46.26** –47.54** –36.40* –14.42 –59.22 (20.16) (20.21) (22.76) (21.02) (20.32) (22.94) (19.84) (27.59) (37.45) IVRV 0.10*** 0.13*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.54 11.39 (3.20) (7.75) lcrspnpy 6.19 7.75 (4.89) (8.10) DEF –1.58 –5.96 (3.03) (3.83) Term –0.63 –0.63 (0.71) (0.83) Tail 30.56 –52.06 (35.02) (47.76) IVSlope 0.29 0.17 (0.26) (0.29) |$\widehat{cay}$| 92.71** (46.30) |$R^2$| 25.2 21.3 22.9 20.4 20.6 20.8 22.4 39.2 19.9 B. PNBON |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –2.50*** –2.42*** –2.47*** –2.70 *** –2.65*** –2.56*** –2.63*** –2.06*** –2.07** (0.85) (0.85) (0.89) (0.86) (0.85) (0.89) (1.00) (1.08) (0.86) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –0.85 –1.20 –1.41 –1.78 –1.61 –1.60 –1.17 0.06 –4.81* (1.01) (1.05) (1.12) (1.08) (1.02) (1.11) (1.08) (1.32) (2.60) IVRV 0.13*** 0.15*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.13 13.63 (3.17) (7.42) lcrspnpy 3.13 1.51 (5.02) (7.92) DEF –1.71 –5.57 (3.03) (3.89) Term –0.27 –0.10 (0.67) (0.85) Tail 26.94 –38.27 (34.87) (46.84) IVSlope 0.36 0.33 (0.28) (0.31) |$\widehat{cay}$| 108.03** (46.11) |$R^2$| 19.2 10.7 9.7 10.3 9.7 9.7 14.5 32.5 17.7 The table reports the results of forecasting 3-month market excess returns with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and other predictors, including the difference between implied and historical volatility in Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) (IVRV), log dividend yield (⁠|$d-p$|⁠), log net payout yield (lcrspnpy), Baa-Aaa credit spread (DEF), term spread (TERM), tail risk measure (Tail), implied volatility slope (Slope), and the quarterly consumption-wealth ratio (⁠|$\widehat{cay}$|⁠). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from 1991 to 2012, except for lcrspnpy and Tail, which is from 1991 to 2010, and IVSlope, which is from 1996 to 2012. In summary, the results from Table 7 show that the option trading activities of public investors and financial intermediaries contain unique information about the market risk premium that is not captured by the standard macro and financial factors. This result is consistent with the theories of intermediary constraints driving asset prices. Of course, the evidence above does not prove that intermediary constraints actually drive aggregate risk premia. It is possible that |$\textit{PNBO}$| is correlated with other risk factors not considered in our specifications. 2.5 Option volume and measures of funding constraints We have presented evidence linking |$\textit{PNBO}$| negatively with option expensiveness and market risk premium when |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$|⁠, which is consistent with the interpretation that low |$\textit{PNBO}$| is a sign of tight intermediary constraints. Thus, |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBON}_t$| can be viewed as a measure of intermediary constraint. We now compare this measure to several measures of financial intermediary funding constraints proposed in the literature. These measures include the year-over-year change in broker-dealer leverage advocated by Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010) (⁠|$\Delta lev$|⁠), the fixed-income market based funding liquidity measure by Fontaine and Garcia (2012) (FG), the TED spread (TED, the difference between the 3-month LIBOR and the 3-month T-bill rate), and the LIBOR-OIS spread (LIBOR-OIS, the difference between the 3-month LIBOR and the 3-month overnight indexed swap rate).16 TED spread and LIBOR-OIS spread measure the credit risk of banks. We first run OLS regressions of our constraint measure on the funding constraint measures in the literature. As panel A of Table 8 shows, TED spread is significantly positively related to |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t$|⁠, but insignificantly related to |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBON}_t$|⁠. The positive relation between TED spread and |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t$| is mainly due to the fact that |$\textit{PNBO}$| rose significantly along with the TED spread during the early part of the financial crisis. Subsequently, while |$\textit{PNBO}$| becomes lower (and turned significantly negative), the TED spread also fell and then remained at low levels. This result points out a potential weakness of TED spread (and LIBOR-OIS) as a measure of funding constraint. TED spread could become lower due to banks reducing their own credit risk through deleveraging, reducing risk taking, and buying crash insurance, but that does not necessarily imply banks are less constrained (could be the opposite). Table 8 |$\textit{PNBO}$| and measures of funding constraints A.|$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t = a + b \ \mathbf{X}_t + e_t$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| TED 22.04** 0.56 (10.57) (147.30) LIBOR-OIS 0.25 –0.17 (0.16) (2.04) FG –4.89** –200.65*** (2.32) (77.30) |$\Delta lev$| 42.59** 50.86** (16.68) (23.18) |$R^2$| 4.3 2.9 1.5 8.9 0.0 0.0 4.4 3.4 B. |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{b_{VP,t}<0} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t +\epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –79.97*** –75.91*** –83.52*** –53.78** –2.62*** –3.81*** –2.57*** –1.63** (24.66) (23.94) (26.65) (22.47) (0.84) (1.23) (0.85) (0.83) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –34.84* –38.41** –42.00** –37.02 –1.38 –3.07** –1.50 –3.69 (19.34) (19.37) (19.65) (40.89) (1.02) (1.27) (1.01) (2.79) TED –2.44 –4.83 (3.19) (3.25) LIBOR-OIS –0.05 –0.08 (0.05) (0.05) FG 0.50 0.24 (0.88) (0.86) |$\Delta Lev$| –4.76 –5.82* (3.51) (3.41) |$R^2$| 20.4 34.9 19.6 19.9 14.4 33.1 9.6 18.9 A.|$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t = a + b \ \mathbf{X}_t + e_t$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| TED 22.04** 0.56 (10.57) (147.30) LIBOR-OIS 0.25 –0.17 (0.16) (2.04) FG –4.89** –200.65*** (2.32) (77.30) |$\Delta lev$| 42.59** 50.86** (16.68) (23.18) |$R^2$| 4.3 2.9 1.5 8.9 0.0 0.0 4.4 3.4 B. |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{b_{VP,t}<0} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t +\epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –79.97*** –75.91*** –83.52*** –53.78** –2.62*** –3.81*** –2.57*** –1.63** (24.66) (23.94) (26.65) (22.47) (0.84) (1.23) (0.85) (0.83) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –34.84* –38.41** –42.00** –37.02 –1.38 –3.07** –1.50 –3.69 (19.34) (19.37) (19.65) (40.89) (1.02) (1.27) (1.01) (2.79) TED –2.44 –4.83 (3.19) (3.25) LIBOR-OIS –0.05 –0.08 (0.05) (0.05) FG 0.50 0.24 (0.88) (0.86) |$\Delta Lev$| –4.76 –5.82* (3.51) (3.41) |$R^2$| 20.4 34.9 19.6 19.9 14.4 33.1 9.6 18.9 Panel A reports the results of the OLS regressions of |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t$| on measures of funding constraints. Panel B reports the results of return predictability regressions with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and funding constraint measures. TED is the TED spread; LIBOR-OIS is the spread between 3-month LIBOR and overnight indexed swap rates; FG is the funding liquidity measure by Fontaine and Garcia (2012); and |$\Delta lev$| is the broker-dealer balance sheet growth measure by Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Newey and West (1987) with 3 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from 1991 to 2012, except for the regressions with LIBOR-OIS, which is from 2002 to 2012. Table 8 |$\textit{PNBO}$| and measures of funding constraints A.|$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t = a + b \ \mathbf{X}_t + e_t$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| TED 22.04** 0.56 (10.57) (147.30) LIBOR-OIS 0.25 –0.17 (0.16) (2.04) FG –4.89** –200.65*** (2.32) (77.30) |$\Delta lev$| 42.59** 50.86** (16.68) (23.18) |$R^2$| 4.3 2.9 1.5 8.9 0.0 0.0 4.4 3.4 B. |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{b_{VP,t}<0} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t +\epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –79.97*** –75.91*** –83.52*** –53.78** –2.62*** –3.81*** –2.57*** –1.63** (24.66) (23.94) (26.65) (22.47) (0.84) (1.23) (0.85) (0.83) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –34.84* –38.41** –42.00** –37.02 –1.38 –3.07** –1.50 –3.69 (19.34) (19.37) (19.65) (40.89) (1.02) (1.27) (1.01) (2.79) TED –2.44 –4.83 (3.19) (3.25) LIBOR-OIS –0.05 –0.08 (0.05) (0.05) FG 0.50 0.24 (0.88) (0.86) |$\Delta Lev$| –4.76 –5.82* (3.51) (3.41) |$R^2$| 20.4 34.9 19.6 19.9 14.4 33.1 9.6 18.9 A.|$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t = a + b \ \mathbf{X}_t + e_t$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| TED 22.04** 0.56 (10.57) (147.30) LIBOR-OIS 0.25 –0.17 (0.16) (2.04) FG –4.89** –200.65*** (2.32) (77.30) |$\Delta lev$| 42.59** 50.86** (16.68) (23.18) |$R^2$| 4.3 2.9 1.5 8.9 0.0 0.0 4.4 3.4 B. |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{b_{VP,t}<0} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t +\epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –79.97*** –75.91*** –83.52*** –53.78** –2.62*** –3.81*** –2.57*** –1.63** (24.66) (23.94) (26.65) (22.47) (0.84) (1.23) (0.85) (0.83) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –34.84* –38.41** –42.00** –37.02 –1.38 –3.07** –1.50 –3.69 (19.34) (19.37) (19.65) (40.89) (1.02) (1.27) (1.01) (2.79) TED –2.44 –4.83 (3.19) (3.25) LIBOR-OIS –0.05 –0.08 (0.05) (0.05) FG 0.50 0.24 (0.88) (0.86) |$\Delta Lev$| –4.76 –5.82* (3.51) (3.41) |$R^2$| 20.4 34.9 19.6 19.9 14.4 33.1 9.6 18.9 Panel A reports the results of the OLS regressions of |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t$| on measures of funding constraints. Panel B reports the results of return predictability regressions with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and funding constraint measures. TED is the TED spread; LIBOR-OIS is the spread between 3-month LIBOR and overnight indexed swap rates; FG is the funding liquidity measure by Fontaine and Garcia (2012); and |$\Delta lev$| is the broker-dealer balance sheet growth measure by Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Newey and West (1987) with 3 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from 1991 to 2012, except for the regressions with LIBOR-OIS, which is from 2002 to 2012. Next, our constraint measure is significantly negatively related to the measure FG. This is consistent with FG’s interpretation that financial intermediaries are more constrained (low |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) in periods when the value of funding liquidity is high (high FG). In the quarterly regression, our constraint measure is significantly positively related to the growth rate in broker-dealer leverage |$\Delta lev$|⁠. That is, intermediary constraint tends to be tight (low |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) when broker-dealers are deleveraging (low |$\Delta lev$|⁠).17 In panel B of Table 8, we further examine the ability of the various funding constraint measures to predict aggregate market returns. Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010) show that |$\Delta lev$| has strong predictive power for excess returns on stocks, corporate bonds, and treasuries. In a univariate regression (unreported) with |$\Delta lev$|⁠, we find similar results in our sample period. When joint with our constraint measure, the coefficient on |$\Delta lev$| becomes insignificant in the case of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and marginally significant in the case of |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, while |$b_r^-$| remains significant. Similarly, when the other funding constraint measures are used in place of |$\Delta lev$|⁠, the coefficient |$b_r^-$| is always highly significant. These results suggest that relative to other funding constraint measures, our intermediary constraint measure contains unique information about conditional market risk premia. 2.6 Econometric identification of supply shocks Since equilibrium prices and quantities are jointly determined by supply and demand, a key element in establishing a causal link between supply and risk premia would be a method of identifying exogenous shocks to supply. Rigobon (2003) solves the identification problem in the supply and demand Equations (4a) and (4b) through heteroscedasticity. We implement this method using |$VP$| as the price variable and |$\textit{PNBO}$| (or |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) as the quantity variable. Following Rigobon (2003) (who uses crisis periods in debt markets to identify movement in bond markets in Latin America), we consider the high supply volatility (relative to demand volatility) regime for our identification as the period from September 2008 (the Lehman default) to November 2011 (cancellation of Greek referendum). The second regime is the remainder of our sample. The results of the estimation are shown in Table 9. We see when using either |$\textit{PNBO}$| or |$\textit{PNBON}$| as the quantity measure, there is a statistically significant positive (negative) slope for the supply (demand) curve. The point estimates indicate that a one-standard-deviation increase in the variance premium (an increase of 21.7) is associated with an increased quantity of 103,000 deep out-of-the-money put contracts, which represents an increase of 2.02 standard deviations to the equilibrium quantity. In terms of the normalized measure |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, a one-standard-deviation increase in the variance premium results in an increased quantity of 5.8% times the trailing 3-month volume of SPX options. Table 9 Supply-demand estimation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b$| 25.9|$^{***}$| (3.96) 55.5* (34.8) |$\beta$| |$-0.0823^{*}$| (0.0541) –4.63** (2.37) |$a$| |$-655^{*}$| |$(340)$| –63.4 (53.5) |$\alpha$| |$0.00477^{**}$| (0.00276) 0.269** (0.12) |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b$| 25.9|$^{***}$| (3.96) 55.5* (34.8) |$\beta$| |$-0.0823^{*}$| (0.0541) –4.63** (2.37) |$a$| |$-655^{*}$| |$(340)$| –63.4 (53.5) |$\alpha$| |$0.00477^{**}$| (0.00276) 0.269** (0.12) This table reports parameter estimates of the estimation of the supply-demand system given by \begin{align*} \textrm{Demand:} VP_t&= b + \beta \cdot \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_t,\\ \textrm{Supply:} \textit{PNBO}_t&= a + \alpha \cdot VP_t + \eta_t, \end{align*} using the econometric identification of Rigobon (2003). The |$\eta$| and |$\epsilon$| are uncorrelated with regime-dependent volatilities. We set the high supply volatility regime to be from September 2009 to November 2011. Standard errors are computed by bootstrap. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively; 1-sided p-values are computed for |$\alpha$| and |$\beta$|⁠. Table 9 Supply-demand estimation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b$| 25.9|$^{***}$| (3.96) 55.5* (34.8) |$\beta$| |$-0.0823^{*}$| (0.0541) –4.63** (2.37) |$a$| |$-655^{*}$| |$(340)$| –63.4 (53.5) |$\alpha$| |$0.00477^{**}$| (0.00276) 0.269** (0.12) |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b$| 25.9|$^{***}$| (3.96) 55.5* (34.8) |$\beta$| |$-0.0823^{*}$| (0.0541) –4.63** (2.37) |$a$| |$-655^{*}$| |$(340)$| –63.4 (53.5) |$\alpha$| |$0.00477^{**}$| (0.00276) 0.269** (0.12) This table reports parameter estimates of the estimation of the supply-demand system given by \begin{align*} \textrm{Demand:} VP_t&= b + \beta \cdot \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_t,\\ \textrm{Supply:} \textit{PNBO}_t&= a + \alpha \cdot VP_t + \eta_t, \end{align*} using the econometric identification of Rigobon (2003). The |$\eta$| and |$\epsilon$| are uncorrelated with regime-dependent volatilities. We set the high supply volatility regime to be from September 2009 to November 2011. Standard errors are computed by bootstrap. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively; 1-sided p-values are computed for |$\alpha$| and |$\beta$|⁠. Table 10 reproduces the predictability results of Table 4 replacing |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| with the extracted supply shocks and normalized supply shocks.18 The extracted supply shock is strongly related to |$\textit{PNBO}$| with a correlation of |$0.71$|⁠. Overall, the predictability with the extracted shocks is very similar to what we found with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, which reinforces our interpretation of the results. Table 10 Return forecasts with supply shocks |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| PNBO supply shocks PNBON supply shocks |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –5.80* (3.25) 2.7 –0.19** (0.08) 2.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –5.23 (3.30) 2.2 –0.14** (0.07) 1.7 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –7.92*** (2.83) 5.1 –0.06 (0.06) 0.3 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –6.32** (3.02) 3.2 –0.02 (0.06) 0.0 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –18.80** (7.48) 8.8 –0.39** (0.16) 3.8 |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| PNBO supply shocks PNBON supply shocks |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –5.80* (3.25) 2.7 –0.19** (0.08) 2.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –5.23 (3.30) 2.2 –0.14** (0.07) 1.7 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –7.92*** (2.83) 5.1 –0.06 (0.06) 0.3 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –6.32** (3.02) 3.2 –0.02 (0.06) 0.0 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –18.80** (7.48) 8.8 –0.39** (0.16) 3.8 This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using supply shocks extracted using the econometric identification of Rigobon (2003). We set the high supply volatility regime to be from September 2009 to November 2011. |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} $| represents log market excess return from month |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 10 Return forecasts with supply shocks |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| PNBO supply shocks PNBON supply shocks |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –5.80* (3.25) 2.7 –0.19** (0.08) 2.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –5.23 (3.30) 2.2 –0.14** (0.07) 1.7 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –7.92*** (2.83) 5.1 –0.06 (0.06) 0.3 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –6.32** (3.02) 3.2 –0.02 (0.06) 0.0 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –18.80** (7.48) 8.8 –0.39** (0.16) 3.8 |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| PNBO supply shocks PNBON supply shocks |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –5.80* (3.25) 2.7 –0.19** (0.08) 2.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –5.23 (3.30) 2.2 –0.14** (0.07) 1.7 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –7.92*** (2.83) 5.1 –0.06 (0.06) 0.3 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –6.32** (3.02) 3.2 –0.02 (0.06) 0.0 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –18.80** (7.48) 8.8 –0.39** (0.16) 3.8 This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using supply shocks extracted using the econometric identification of Rigobon (2003). We set the high supply volatility regime to be from September 2009 to November 2011. |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} $| represents log market excess return from month |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. However, we temper this evidence with a caveat based on the assumptions of the methodology and its application to our setting. The method used here to identify supply shocks assumes linear and stationary supply/demand relationships, and zero correlation between supply and demand shocks.19 The results are likely sensitive to these assumptions. 3. Robustness Checks In this section, we report the results of several robustness checks for our main results. 3.1 Financial crisis One potential concern regarding the predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is that it might be driven by a small number of outliers, in particular the 2008–09 financial crisis. To address this concern, Table 11 reports the results of the return-forecasting regressions in two subsamples: pre-crisis (January 1991–November 2007) and post-crisis (June 2009–December 2012). The predictive powers of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| remain statistically significant in both subsamples. The economic significance of the predictive power is weaker in the pre-crisis period than in the full sample (in terms of smaller magnitude of |$b_r^-$| and lower |$R^2$|⁠), but it is quite strong in the post-crisis period. Thus, the predictive power of our measure of intermediary constraint is not just a crisis phenomenon. The weaker predictive power for |$\textit{PNBO}$| in the earlier sample period could be due to the fact that intermediary constraints are not as significant and volatile in the first half of the sample. Another reason might be that the SPX options market was less developed in the early periods and did not play as important a role in facilitating risk sharing as it does today. Table 11 Return forecasting outside the financial crisis |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Pre-crisis –66.50** 21.91 3.8 –1.85** –0.12 5.3 (27.53) (22.90) (0.92) (1.12) Post-crisis –50.88** –15.73 17.4 –4.87** –1.02 19.6 (25.72) (33.42) (2.39) (3.61) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Pre-crisis –66.50** 21.91 3.8 –1.85** –0.12 5.3 (27.53) (22.90) (0.92) (1.12) Post-crisis –50.88** –15.73 17.4 –4.87** –1.02 19.6 (25.72) (33.42) (2.39) (3.61) This table reports the 3-month return forecasting results outside the financial crisis. Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The pre-crisis period is from January 1991 to November 2007. The post-crisis period is from June 2009 to December 2012. Table 11 Return forecasting outside the financial crisis |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Pre-crisis –66.50** 21.91 3.8 –1.85** –0.12 5.3 (27.53) (22.90) (0.92) (1.12) Post-crisis –50.88** –15.73 17.4 –4.87** –1.02 19.6 (25.72) (33.42) (2.39) (3.61) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Pre-crisis –66.50** 21.91 3.8 –1.85** –0.12 5.3 (27.53) (22.90) (0.92) (1.12) Post-crisis –50.88** –15.73 17.4 –4.87** –1.02 19.6 (25.72) (33.42) (2.39) (3.61) This table reports the 3-month return forecasting results outside the financial crisis. Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The pre-crisis period is from January 1991 to November 2007. The post-crisis period is from June 2009 to December 2012. 3.2 Moneyness Next, we examine how the predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| changes based on option moneyness. Our baseline definition of DOTM puts uses a simple cutoff rule |$K/S \leq 0.85$|⁠. Panel A of Figure 4 plots the coefficient |$b_r^-$| and the confidence intervals as we change this cutoff value for SPX puts. The coefficient |$b_r^-$| in the return forecast regression is significantly negative for a wide range of moneyness cutoffs. The point estimate of |$b_r^-$| does become more negative as the cutoff becomes smaller. Because DOTM puts are more difficult to hedge than ATM puts, they expose financial intermediaries to more inventory risks. Hence, |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure based on DOTM puts should be more informative about intermediary constraints and in turn the aggregate risk premium than |$\textit{PNBO}$| based on ATM puts. At the same time, because far out-of-money options are less liquid, the |$\textit{PNBO}$| series becomes more noisy when we further reduce the cutoff, which widens the confidence interval on |$b_r^-$|⁠. In contrast, panel B shows that for essentially all moneyness cutoffs, |$\textit{PNBO}$| based on SPX call options does not predict market returns. Figure 4 View largeDownload slide Predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| at different moneyness This figure plots the point estimate and 95% confidence interval (based on standard errors computed using the method of Hodrick 1992) for the coefficient |$b_r^-$| from regression (5) forecasting 3-month market excess returns. In panels A and B, option moneyness is measured by the level of strike-to-price ratio |$K/S$|⁠. In panels C and D, option moneyness is measured by |$K/S$| relative to daily volatility of S&P returns scaled by the square root of days to maturity (see Section 3.2). Figure 4 View largeDownload slide Predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| at different moneyness This figure plots the point estimate and 95% confidence interval (based on standard errors computed using the method of Hodrick 1992) for the coefficient |$b_r^-$| from regression (5) forecasting 3-month market excess returns. In panels A and B, option moneyness is measured by the level of strike-to-price ratio |$K/S$|⁠. In panels C and D, option moneyness is measured by |$K/S$| relative to daily volatility of S&P returns scaled by the square root of days to maturity (see Section 3.2). A feature of our definition of DOTM puts above is that a constant strike-to-price cutoff implies different actual moneyness (e.g., as measured by option delta) for options with different maturities. A 15% drop in price over 1 month might seem very extreme in calm periods, but it is more likely when market volatility is high. For this reason, we also examine a maturity-adjusted moneyness definition. Specifically, we classify a put option as DOTM when |$K/S \leq 1+k \sigma_t \sqrt{T},$| where |$k$| is a constant, |$\sigma_t$| is the daily S&P return volatility in the previous 30 trading days, and |$T$| is the days to maturity for the option. This is similar to using option delta to define moneyness, but does not require a particular pricing model to compute the delta. Panel C of Figure 4 shows that this alternative classification of DOTM puts produces qualitatively similar results as our simple cutoff rule. Panel D shows again that |$\textit{PNBO}$| based on SPX calls and this alternative moneyness cutoff does not predict returns. 3.3 Volume versus open interest In our construction of |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, we focus on the net amount of new DOTM index puts that public investors buy in a period. An alternative way to gauge the economic exposure for public investors and financial intermediaries is to examine the net open interest for the two groups. Between new volume and open interest, which one better represents the degree of intermediary constraints? We use the volume-based measure in our main analysis for a few reasons. The first reason is data limitation, as CBOE does not provide daily long and short open interest data after 2001. Second, when financial intermediaries become constrained, it is likely easier (e.g., due to transaction costs) to adjust the quantity of new DOTM puts traded than to change their established positions. That would make the volume-based measure more sensitive to changes in intermediary constraints than open interest-based measure. Third, taking on an option position that is originally near the money but later becomes DOTM due to market movements is different from taking on a new DOTM option. In the former case, the intermediaries can put on hedges against tail risk over time, which again means these positions are less sensitive to changes in intermediary constraints. Nonetheless, we provide two robustness checks. First, we examine an alternative measure based on the end-of-month public net open interest for DOTM SPX puts (⁠|$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠). The results are discussed below. Second, we construct a |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure using only 1-month options, for which the monthly measures of net volume and open interest are equivalent. We find that the main results hold for the measure based on short-dated options (see Table IA4 in the Online Appendix). For the period of 1991 to 2001, we use daily long and short open interest provided by CBOE to compute |$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠. From 2001 onward, we compute daily net open interest from the volume information as follows: \begin{equation}\label{Eqoi} \textit{NOI}_d^{K,T}=\textit{NOI}_{d-1}^{K,T} +\rm openBuy_d^{K,T}-openSell_d^{K,T}+closeBuy_d^{K,T}-closeSell_d^{K,T}, \end{equation} (7) where |$NOI_d^{K,T}$| is the public investor net open interest of options with strike price |$K$| and maturity |$T$| on day |$d$|⁠, openBuy is the public investor buying volume from initiating long positions, openSell is the selling volume from initiating short, closeBuy is the buying volume from closing existing short positions, and closeSell is the selling volume from closing existing long positions. We then aggregate |$NOI_d^{K,T}$| to compute daily net open interest of DOTM puts (⁠|$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠). We also consider a normalized version of |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠), which is |$\textit{PNOI}$| divided by the sum of public long and short open interest for all SPX options. Table 1 shows that the end-of-month |$\textit{PNOI}$| is around 29,000 contracts on average, and |$\textit{PNOI}$| has higher autocorrelation than |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. Table 12 shows that, like |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, |$\textit{PNOI}$| predicts future market excess returns negatively in the periods with |$b_{VP,t} < 0$|⁠, with significant coefficient |$b_r^-$| up to 3 months in the future. The |$R^2$| of the regressions are also similar to |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. Additional subsample results for |$\textit{PNOI}$| are provided in Table IA5 of the Online Appendix. Table 12 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} =a_{r}+b^-_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, PNOI_t+b^+_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}}\,PNOI_t+c_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}}+\epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –25.10*** –11.72 8.1 –3.71*** –1.23 5.6 (8.65) (7.93) (1.11) (1.17) |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.79** –1.65 5.3 –2.11* –0.25 2.7 (9.59) (4.72) (1.17) (0.99) |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –19.34** –4.67 4.5 –2.21** –0.26 2.0 (7.73) (7.66) (0.97) (1.19) |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –9.75 –17.17* 4.2 –1.32 –2.32* 2.4 (6.85) (9.18) (0.96) (1.29) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –64.22*** –18.05 14.7 –8.03*** –1.74 7.8 (23.47) (13.50) (2.68) (2.28) |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} =a_{r}+b^-_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, PNOI_t+b^+_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}}\,PNOI_t+c_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}}+\epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –25.10*** –11.72 8.1 –3.71*** –1.23 5.6 (8.65) (7.93) (1.11) (1.17) |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.79** –1.65 5.3 –2.11* –0.25 2.7 (9.59) (4.72) (1.17) (0.99) |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –19.34** –4.67 4.5 –2.21** –0.26 2.0 (7.73) (7.66) (0.97) (1.19) |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –9.75 –17.17* 4.2 –1.32 –2.32* 2.4 (6.85) (9.18) (0.96) (1.29) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –64.22*** –18.05 14.7 –8.03*** –1.74 7.8 (23.47) (13.50) (2.68) (2.28) This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using |$\textit{PNOI}$| and |$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠. Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 12 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} =a_{r}+b^-_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, PNOI_t+b^+_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}}\,PNOI_t+c_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}}+\epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –25.10*** –11.72 8.1 –3.71*** –1.23 5.6 (8.65) (7.93) (1.11) (1.17) |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.79** –1.65 5.3 –2.11* –0.25 2.7 (9.59) (4.72) (1.17) (0.99) |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –19.34** –4.67 4.5 –2.21** –0.26 2.0 (7.73) (7.66) (0.97) (1.19) |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –9.75 –17.17* 4.2 –1.32 –2.32* 2.4 (6.85) (9.18) (0.96) (1.29) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –64.22*** –18.05 14.7 –8.03*** –1.74 7.8 (23.47) (13.50) (2.68) (2.28) |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} =a_{r}+b^-_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, PNOI_t+b^+_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}}\,PNOI_t+c_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}}+\epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –25.10*** –11.72 8.1 –3.71*** –1.23 5.6 (8.65) (7.93) (1.11) (1.17) |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.79** –1.65 5.3 –2.11* –0.25 2.7 (9.59) (4.72) (1.17) (0.99) |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –19.34** –4.67 4.5 –2.21** –0.26 2.0 (7.73) (7.66) (0.97) (1.19) |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –9.75 –17.17* 4.2 –1.32 –2.32* 2.4 (6.85) (9.18) (0.96) (1.29) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –64.22*** –18.05 14.7 –8.03*** –1.74 7.8 (23.47) (13.50) (2.68) (2.28) This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using |$\textit{PNOI}$| and |$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠. Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. 3.4 Public investors: Retail versus institutional As Figure 1 shows, while financial intermediaries typically sell DOTM SPX puts to public investors during normal times, the roles are often reversed during crisis times, most notably during the 2008-09 financial crisis. To understand the risk sharing mechanism between financial intermediaries and public investors, it is informative to find out who among the public investors are the “liquidity providers,” reducing the demand for crash insurance or even providing insurance to the intermediaries when the latter become constrained. The SPX volume data from CBOE do not provide further information about the types of public investors behind a given transaction (e.g., retail vs. institutional investors). We tackle this question by comparing the trading activities of the public investors in SPX options with those in SPY options. While SPX and SPY options have essentially identical underlying asset, it is well known among practitioners that institutional investors account for a significantly higher percentage of the trading volume of SPX options than do SPY options. Compared to retail investors, institutional investors prefer SPX options due to a larger contract size (10 times as large as SPY), cash settlement, more favorable tax treatment, as well as being more capable of trading in between the relatively wide bid-ask spreads of SPX options due to stronger bargaining power. We construct |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| for SPY options using the same procedure as |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, which covers the period from May 2005 to December 2012. While SPX options trade exclusively on the CBOE, SPY options are cross-listed at several option exchanges. |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| aggregates the volume from the CBOE and International Securities Exchange (ISE), which account for about half of the total trading volume for SPY options. Figure 5 compares the |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| and |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPX}$| (equivalent to |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) series. During the period of May 2005 to January 2012, |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| is positive in the majority of the months. From September 2008 to December 2010, |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPX}$| is negative in 22 out of 28 months, whereas |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| is negative in just 7 of the 28 months. Figure 5 View largeDownload slide Comparing |$\textit{PNBO}$| for SPX and SPY options This figure plots the public net buying-to-open volume for deep out-of-the-money (with |$K/S\leq0.85$|⁠) puts in the market for SPX options and SPY options for the period of May 2005 to December 2012. Figure 5 View largeDownload slide Comparing |$\textit{PNBO}$| for SPX and SPY options This figure plots the public net buying-to-open volume for deep out-of-the-money (with |$K/S\leq0.85$|⁠) puts in the market for SPX options and SPY options for the period of May 2005 to December 2012. A systematic way to examine the difference in how the equilibrium quantities of trading in the two markets are connected to the intermediary constraints and market risk premium is through the regressions of (3) and (5). These results are reported in the Online Appendix, and we summarize the main findings here. Unlike SPX, the |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure based on SPY is insignificantly (positively) related to the variance premium on average, and does not predict future market excess returns. The contrast between SPX and SPY suggests that institutional investors and retail investors respond differently to the changes in intermediary constraints. In particular, when constrained financial intermediaries start buying crash insurance, they appear to be buying the insurance from the public (institutional) investors in the SPX market and not from the public (retail) investors in the SPY market.20 3.5 Comparison with GPP Our results on the price-quantity relation in the DOTM SPX puts market is related to Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2009). However, our results differ from GPPÕs along several aspects. First, we have a longer sample period, from 1991 to 2012, whereas theirs is from 1996 to 2001. Second, our |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure uses contemporaneous public net-buying volume, whereas GPP use public net open interest,21 which is the accumulation of past net-buying volumes. Third, our |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure focuses on DOTM SPX puts, whereas GPP use options of all moneyness (which is similar to the sum of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| in this regard). In this section, we first replicate the main results of GPP (in table 2, p. 4287) and then examine the differences between the two studies. The dependent variable in Table 13, option expensiveness, is the same as the one used in GPP Table 2, that is, the average implied volatility of ATM options minus a reference model-implied volatility used in Bates (2006).22 GPP regress the option expensiveness on several measures of SPX non-market-maker demand pressure, including the equal-weighted public open interest (NetDemand), and public open interest weighted by jump risk (JumpRisk). They find the regression coefficients to be positive in the period from October 1997 to December 2001. Table 13 Comparison with GPP Table 2 Net open interest Net volume Replicated results GPP results NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk Jan. 1996– 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 4.5|$\times 10^{-6}$| 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 6.4|$\times 10^{-6}$| 1.6|$\times 10^{-8}$| –5.1|$\times 10^{-6}$| Oct.1996 |$t$|-stat (0.72) (0.49) (0.87) (0.79) (0.10) (–0.23) Oct. 1997– 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$|** 2.6|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$| 3.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 4.7|$\times 10^{-6}$|** 4.9|$\times 10^{-5}$|** Dec.2001 |$t$|-stat (2.17) (2.80) (1.55) (3.68) (2.25) (2.57) Jan. 2002– –9.9|$\times 10^{-8}$|*** –7.8|$\times 10^{-6}$|** –6.7|$\times 10^{-7}$|** –5.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** Dec. 2012 |$t$|-stat (–3.13) (–2.40) (–2.35) (–3.32) Net open interest Net volume Replicated results GPP results NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk Jan. 1996– 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 4.5|$\times 10^{-6}$| 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 6.4|$\times 10^{-6}$| 1.6|$\times 10^{-8}$| –5.1|$\times 10^{-6}$| Oct.1996 |$t$|-stat (0.72) (0.49) (0.87) (0.79) (0.10) (–0.23) Oct. 1997– 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$|** 2.6|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$| 3.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 4.7|$\times 10^{-6}$|** 4.9|$\times 10^{-5}$|** Dec.2001 |$t$|-stat (2.17) (2.80) (1.55) (3.68) (2.25) (2.57) Jan. 2002– –9.9|$\times 10^{-8}$|*** –7.8|$\times 10^{-6}$|** –6.7|$\times 10^{-7}$|** –5.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** Dec. 2012 |$t$|-stat (–3.13) (–2.40) (–2.35) (–3.32) The table reports the results from regressing option expensiveness, measured by the average implied volatility of ATM options minus a reference model-implied volatility used in Bates (2006), on measures of option demand. NetDemand and JumpRisk are the equally and vega-weighted public net open interest (or net volume) for all SPX options. |$t$|-stats are computed based on Newey and West (1987) standard errors with 10 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Table 13 Comparison with GPP Table 2 Net open interest Net volume Replicated results GPP results NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk Jan. 1996– 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 4.5|$\times 10^{-6}$| 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 6.4|$\times 10^{-6}$| 1.6|$\times 10^{-8}$| –5.1|$\times 10^{-6}$| Oct.1996 |$t$|-stat (0.72) (0.49) (0.87) (0.79) (0.10) (–0.23) Oct. 1997– 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$|** 2.6|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$| 3.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 4.7|$\times 10^{-6}$|** 4.9|$\times 10^{-5}$|** Dec.2001 |$t$|-stat (2.17) (2.80) (1.55) (3.68) (2.25) (2.57) Jan. 2002– –9.9|$\times 10^{-8}$|*** –7.8|$\times 10^{-6}$|** –6.7|$\times 10^{-7}$|** –5.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** Dec. 2012 |$t$|-stat (–3.13) (–2.40) (–2.35) (–3.32) Net open interest Net volume Replicated results GPP results NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk Jan. 1996– 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 4.5|$\times 10^{-6}$| 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 6.4|$\times 10^{-6}$| 1.6|$\times 10^{-8}$| –5.1|$\times 10^{-6}$| Oct.1996 |$t$|-stat (0.72) (0.49) (0.87) (0.79) (0.10) (–0.23) Oct. 1997– 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$|** 2.6|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$| 3.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 4.7|$\times 10^{-6}$|** 4.9|$\times 10^{-5}$|** Dec.2001 |$t$|-stat (2.17) (2.80) (1.55) (3.68) (2.25) (2.57) Jan. 2002– –9.9|$\times 10^{-8}$|*** –7.8|$\times 10^{-6}$|** –6.7|$\times 10^{-7}$|** –5.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** Dec. 2012 |$t$|-stat (–3.13) (–2.40) (–2.35) (–3.32) The table reports the results from regressing option expensiveness, measured by the average implied volatility of ATM options minus a reference model-implied volatility used in Bates (2006), on measures of option demand. NetDemand and JumpRisk are the equally and vega-weighted public net open interest (or net volume) for all SPX options. |$t$|-stats are computed based on Newey and West (1987) standard errors with 10 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. In Table 13, we obtain very similar results to GPP for the two subsamples January 1996–October 1996 and October 1997–December 2001 for the open interest-based measures. We also construct two net volume-based measures and again find that they are positively related to option expensiveness in the period from October 1997 to December 2001. Next, for the period 2002–2012, we use daily volume data to extend the net open interest measures (constructed using the procedure described in Section 3.3). In this subsample, we find that the coefficients on both the open interest and volume-based measures become negative and statistically significant. This finding is consistent with our finding of a negative price-quantity relation in the full sample (see Table 3). The changing signs of the price-quantity relation in different subsamples suggest that the effects of demand shocks and supply shocks are both present in the SPX option market. 4. Conclusion We provide evidence that the trading activities of financial intermediaries in the market of DOTM SPX put options are informative about the degree of intermediary constraints. In periods when supply shocks are likely to be the main force behind the variations in the price-quantity relation in the DOTM SPX put market, our public investor net-buying volume measure, |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, has strong predictive power for future market excess returns and the returns for a range of other financial assets. The predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is stronger during periods when the market jump risk is high, and it is stronger for DOTM puts. |$\textit{PNBO}$| is also associated with several funding liquidity measures in the literature. Moreover, the information that |$\textit{PNBO}$| contains about the market risk premium is not captured by the standard financial and macro variables. These results suggest that time-varying intermediary constraints are driving the supply of crash insurance by financial intermediaries and the risk premia in financial markets. We thank Tobias Adrian, David Bates, Robert Battalio, Geert Bekaert, Harjoat Bhamra, Ken French, Nicolae Garleanu, Zhiguo He, Boris Ilyevsky, Gary Katz, Bryan Kelly, Lei Lian, Andrew Lo, Dmitriy Muravyev, Jun Pan, Lasse Pedersen, Steve Ross, Paul Stephens, Ken Singleton, Emil Siriwardane, Moto Yogo, and Hao Zhou and participants at numerous conferences and seminars for comments. We thank Ernest Liu for excellent research assistance. Ni acknowledges the financial support from Hong Kong RGC (644311). Supplementary data can be found on The Review of Financial Studies Web site. Appendix A1. Physical Jump Risk The construction of the jump risk measure |$J$|⁠, which we briefly outline here, follows Bekaert and Hoerova (2014) and Corsi, Pirino, and Reno (2010). The monthly jump |$J$| is the average of daily jump |$J^d$|⁠, which is defined as \begin{equation} J^d_t=\max[RV^d_t - TBPV^d_t, 0], \end{equation} (A1) where |$RV^d_t$| is the S&P 500 daily realized variance (based on 5-minute returns), and |$TBPV^d_t$| stands for threshold bipower variation, which is defined as follows (see Corsi, Pirino, and Reno, 2010, equation (2.14)): \begin{equation} TBPV^d_t=\frac{1}{0.7979^2}\sum^{N}_{j=2}\left |r_{j-1}\cdot r_j \right |\cdot I_{r^2_{j-1}\leq \vartheta_{j-1}}\cdot I_{r^2_{j}\leq \vartheta_{j}}. \end{equation} (A2) Here, |$r_j$| is the |$j$|th 5-minute return on day |$t$|⁠; |$\vartheta_{j}$| is a stochastic threshold, \begin{equation} \vartheta_{j}=c_{\vartheta}^2\cdot \hat{V_j}, \end{equation} (A3) where |$c_{\vartheta}$| is a scale-free constant (set to 3), and |$\hat{V_j}$| is an auxiliary estimator of variance, which is estimated through the following iteration, \begin{equation} \hat{V}^Z_j=\frac{\sum^L_{i=-L,i\neq-1,0,1} K \left( \frac{i}{L} \right) r^2_{j+i} I_{ \left \{ r^2_{j+i} \leq c_{\vartheta}^2 \cdot \hat {V}_{j+i}^{Z-1} \right \}}} { \sum^L_{i=-L,i \neq-1,0,1} K \left( \frac{i}{L} \right) I_{\left \{ r_{j+i}^2 \leq c_{\vartheta}^2 \cdot \hat{V}^{Z-1}_{j+i}\right \}}}, \quad Z=1,2,... \end{equation} (A4) The starting value is |$\hat{V}_j^0=+\infty$|⁠. In each iteration step, large returns are eliminated based on the condition |$r_{j}^2>c^2_{\vartheta}\cdot \hat{V}^{Z-1}_{j}$|⁠, and the iteration stops when there are no more large returns to remove. The bandwidth parameter |$L$| determines the number of adjacent returns included in the estimation of the local variance around point |$j$| (with the observation at |$j$| and the two adjacent ones excluded). We set |$L$| = 25 and use a Gaussian kernel |$K(y)= (1/\sqrt{2\pi}) \exp(-y^2/2)$|⁠. A2. Additional Empirical Results To check whether our supply-environment indicator |$I_{b_{VP,t} < 0}$| does a good job identifying important events of supply shocks, Table A1 shows the value of our indicator during a set of months in which significant events have occurred in the financial markets, and which are likely associated with either positive or negative supply shocks for financial intermediaries. In addition, Table A1 also reports the value of the indicators based on sign of |$b_{VP,t}$| and the CDM method from November 2007 to June 2009, the period of the 2008 financial crisis. Outside the 2008 crisis, the strategy based on the sign of |$b_{VP,t}$| identifies the major events seven times out of ten, whereas the CDM strategy identifies two events. Inside the 2008 crisis, the two indicators both pick up 12 out of 20 months. Table A1 Indicators of supply environment Month and Year |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$| CDM Events Oct. 1997 0 0 Asian financial crisis Nov. 1998 1 0 Russian financial crisis Apr. 2003 1 0 Start of the Iraq War Aug. 2007 0 1 Quant crisis Nov. 2007 1 1 Liquidity deterioration in interbank funding market Dec. 2007 1 0 Creation of TAF Jan. 2008 1 0 Bank of America acquisition of Countrywide Feb. 2008 0 0 Northern Rock taken into state ownership Mar. 2008 0 1 Sale of Bear Sterns to J. P. Morgan Apr. 2008 1 1 FOMC rate cut May 2008 0 1 FOMC expands the list of eligible collateral for TSLF Jun. 2008 1 0 S&P downgrade of AMBAC and MBIA Jul. 2008 1 1 Failure of IndyMac Aug. 2008 1 1 FOMC maintains federal funds rate target Sept. 2008 1 1 Lehman Bankruptcy Oct. 2008 0 0 Establishment of TARP Nov. 2008 1 0 Creation of TALF Dec. 2008 1 1 Fed extension of liquidity facility Jan. 2009 0 1 Treasury, Fed, FDIC assistance to BofA Feb. 2009 1 1 Increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion Mar. 2009 0 1 Apr. 2009 0 0 May 2009 1 1 Jun. 2009 0 0 Large banks’ repayments of bailout funds Dec. 2009 1 0 Escalation of Greek debt crisis Apr. 2010 0 0 Greece seeks financial support May 2010 1 0 Establishment of EFSM and EFSF Sept. 2010 1 1 Second Greek bailout installment Jun. 2011 1 0 Merkel agrees to Greece bondholder role Oct. 2011 1 0 Call for a Greek referendum Month and Year |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$| CDM Events Oct. 1997 0 0 Asian financial crisis Nov. 1998 1 0 Russian financial crisis Apr. 2003 1 0 Start of the Iraq War Aug. 2007 0 1 Quant crisis Nov. 2007 1 1 Liquidity deterioration in interbank funding market Dec. 2007 1 0 Creation of TAF Jan. 2008 1 0 Bank of America acquisition of Countrywide Feb. 2008 0 0 Northern Rock taken into state ownership Mar. 2008 0 1 Sale of Bear Sterns to J. P. Morgan Apr. 2008 1 1 FOMC rate cut May 2008 0 1 FOMC expands the list of eligible collateral for TSLF Jun. 2008 1 0 S&P downgrade of AMBAC and MBIA Jul. 2008 1 1 Failure of IndyMac Aug. 2008 1 1 FOMC maintains federal funds rate target Sept. 2008 1 1 Lehman Bankruptcy Oct. 2008 0 0 Establishment of TARP Nov. 2008 1 0 Creation of TALF Dec. 2008 1 1 Fed extension of liquidity facility Jan. 2009 0 1 Treasury, Fed, FDIC assistance to BofA Feb. 2009 1 1 Increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion Mar. 2009 0 1 Apr. 2009 0 0 May 2009 1 1 Jun. 2009 0 0 Large banks’ repayments of bailout funds Dec. 2009 1 0 Escalation of Greek debt crisis Apr. 2010 0 0 Greece seeks financial support May 2010 1 0 Establishment of EFSM and EFSF Sept. 2010 1 1 Second Greek bailout installment Jun. 2011 1 0 Merkel agrees to Greece bondholder role Oct. 2011 1 0 Call for a Greek referendum This table reports the indicators of supply environment based on the sign of |$b_{VP,t}$| and based on the Cohen, Diether, and Malloy (2007) (CDM) method. The months listed include those associated with major events in the global financial markets. They also include the period of November 2007 to June 2009, the period of the 2008 financial crisis. For more details of the events during the 2008 financial crisis, see the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Web page (https://www.stlouisfed.org/financial-crisis/full-timeline). Table A1 Indicators of supply environment Month and Year |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$| CDM Events Oct. 1997 0 0 Asian financial crisis Nov. 1998 1 0 Russian financial crisis Apr. 2003 1 0 Start of the Iraq War Aug. 2007 0 1 Quant crisis Nov. 2007 1 1 Liquidity deterioration in interbank funding market Dec. 2007 1 0 Creation of TAF Jan. 2008 1 0 Bank of America acquisition of Countrywide Feb. 2008 0 0 Northern Rock taken into state ownership Mar. 2008 0 1 Sale of Bear Sterns to J. P. Morgan Apr. 2008 1 1 FOMC rate cut May 2008 0 1 FOMC expands the list of eligible collateral for TSLF Jun. 2008 1 0 S&P downgrade of AMBAC and MBIA Jul. 2008 1 1 Failure of IndyMac Aug. 2008 1 1 FOMC maintains federal funds rate target Sept. 2008 1 1 Lehman Bankruptcy Oct. 2008 0 0 Establishment of TARP Nov. 2008 1 0 Creation of TALF Dec. 2008 1 1 Fed extension of liquidity facility Jan. 2009 0 1 Treasury, Fed, FDIC assistance to BofA Feb. 2009 1 1 Increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion Mar. 2009 0 1 Apr. 2009 0 0 May 2009 1 1 Jun. 2009 0 0 Large banks’ repayments of bailout funds Dec. 2009 1 0 Escalation of Greek debt crisis Apr. 2010 0 0 Greece seeks financial support May 2010 1 0 Establishment of EFSM and EFSF Sept. 2010 1 1 Second Greek bailout installment Jun. 2011 1 0 Merkel agrees to Greece bondholder role Oct. 2011 1 0 Call for a Greek referendum Month and Year |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$| CDM Events Oct. 1997 0 0 Asian financial crisis Nov. 1998 1 0 Russian financial crisis Apr. 2003 1 0 Start of the Iraq War Aug. 2007 0 1 Quant crisis Nov. 2007 1 1 Liquidity deterioration in interbank funding market Dec. 2007 1 0 Creation of TAF Jan. 2008 1 0 Bank of America acquisition of Countrywide Feb. 2008 0 0 Northern Rock taken into state ownership Mar. 2008 0 1 Sale of Bear Sterns to J. P. Morgan Apr. 2008 1 1 FOMC rate cut May 2008 0 1 FOMC expands the list of eligible collateral for TSLF Jun. 2008 1 0 S&P downgrade of AMBAC and MBIA Jul. 2008 1 1 Failure of IndyMac Aug. 2008 1 1 FOMC maintains federal funds rate target Sept. 2008 1 1 Lehman Bankruptcy Oct. 2008 0 0 Establishment of TARP Nov. 2008 1 0 Creation of TALF Dec. 2008 1 1 Fed extension of liquidity facility Jan. 2009 0 1 Treasury, Fed, FDIC assistance to BofA Feb. 2009 1 1 Increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion Mar. 2009 0 1 Apr. 2009 0 0 May 2009 1 1 Jun. 2009 0 0 Large banks’ repayments of bailout funds Dec. 2009 1 0 Escalation of Greek debt crisis Apr. 2010 0 0 Greece seeks financial support May 2010 1 0 Establishment of EFSM and EFSF Sept. 2010 1 1 Second Greek bailout installment Jun. 2011 1 0 Merkel agrees to Greece bondholder role Oct. 2011 1 0 Call for a Greek referendum This table reports the indicators of supply environment based on the sign of |$b_{VP,t}$| and based on the Cohen, Diether, and Malloy (2007) (CDM) method. The months listed include those associated with major events in the global financial markets. They also include the period of November 2007 to June 2009, the period of the 2008 financial crisis. For more details of the events during the 2008 financial crisis, see the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Web page (https://www.stlouisfed.org/financial-crisis/full-timeline). Additional empirical results and robustness checks are provided in the Online Appendix. They include (1) a table of correlations between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and various macroeconomic and financial variables (Table IA2); (2) systematic analysis of the statistical significance for the return-forecasting regressions using |$PBNO$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| (Table IA3); (3) return-forecasting regression with |$\textit{PNBO}_{1month}$| (and |$\textit{PNBON}_{1month}$|⁠), which is |$\textit{PNBO}$| constructed using only options with 1 month or less to maturity (Table IA4); (4) subsample return-forecasting regressions with |$\textit{PNOI}$| (Table IA5); (5) return-forecasting regression with |$PNB$| (and |$PNBN$|⁠), which is the public net buy volume for DOTM SPX puts including both open and close transactions (Table IA6); (6) return-forecasting regression using a modified CDM method (Table IA7); (7) return-forecasting regression using |$b_{\textit{VP}}+c_{\textit{VP}} J_t$| as indicator (Table IA8); and (8) subsample return-forecasting regressions with the log dividend-price ratio (Table IA9). Footnotes 1 We assume public investors’ demand curve is downward sloping and financial intermediaries’ supply curve is upward sloping. These assumptions apply when both groups are (effectively) risk averse and cannot fully unload their inventory risks through hedging. Notice that the presence of one type of shock does not rule out the presence of the other. 2 We present a general equilibrium model in the Online Appendix that captures time-varying intermediary constraints in reduced form and is quite tractable. 3 For example, Johnson, Liang, and Liu (2016) estimate that the change in value of index options outstanding is on the order of trillions of dollars following a severe market crash and the majority of which is contributed by out-of-money SPX puts. 4 For a robustness check, we also define |$\textit{PNBON}$| using past 12-month average public trading volume in the denominator. Doing so generates similar results. 5 The expected physical variance 1-month ahead (22 trading days) is computed using model 8 in Bekaert and Hoerova (2014): |$E_d\left [ RV_{d+1}^{(22)} \right] = 3.730+0.108\frac{VIX^2_d}{12} +0.199RV_{d}^{(-22)}+0.33\frac{22}{5}RV_{d}^{(-5)}+0.107\cdot22RV_{d}^{(-1)}$|⁠, where |$RV_{d}^{(-j)}$| is the sum of daily realized variances from day |$d-j+1$| to day |$d$|⁠. The daily realized variance sums squared 5-minute intraday S&P 500 returns and the squared close-to-open return. 6 We thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion. 7 The GM and Ford downgrades in May 2005 might have been related to the negative |$\textit{PNBO}$| in 2005. 8 One potential concern is that the volatility of |$\textit{PNBO}$| may be nonstationary. If we apply the structural break test of Andrews (1993) to the monthly realized volatility (computed from daily |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠), we find evidence for a break in the time trend in volatility at |$\tau=$| March 2007 (⁠|$F_{max} = 50.4> F_{crit, 1{\%}} = 15.56$|⁠). Subsequent to this break, the point estimate of the time trend is negative, indicating that volatilities declined (or at least didn’t continue to increase) from this point. 9 We restrict the options to be between 15 and 90 days to maturity to ensure liquidity. For delta-gamma hedging, we use at-the-money puts expiring in the following month in addition to the S&P 500 index. 10 Table A1 in the appendix provides more details, as well as a comparison between our strategy and a direct application of the CDM method to identify supply environments. 11 The standard errors for the return-forecasting regressions are based on the method of Hodrick (1992). We provide additional results on statistical inference in Table IA2 in the Online Appendix, including Newey and West (1987) standard errors with long lags, bootstrapped confidence intervals, and the test statistic of Muller (2014). See Ang and Bekaert (2007) for a further discussion on long-horizon statistical inference. 12 Note that the predictability in returns in Table 4 is not accounted for by variation in |$VP$|⁠, showing that |$\textit{PNBO}$| represents a risk source that drives returns independent incrementally to its effect of prices (seen in Table 3). Thus, |$\textit{PNBO}$| represents an unspanned risk similar to those found in the term structure literature like in Joslin, Priebsch, and Singleton (2014), Joslin (2017), or Joslin, and Konchitchki (Forthcoming), among others. 13 While using the level of jump risk to split the sample is motivated by the difficulty to hedge tail risk, the correlation between the two dummy variables of whether |$J_t$| and |$VP_t$| are above their respective sample medians is 0.97 (the correlation between |$J_t$| and |$VP_t$| is 0.54), meaning that the same results apply if we split the samples based on |$VP_t$|⁠. 14 Data for the returns on high-yield bonds, commodity, and hedge funds are from Datastream. Government bond return data are from Global Financial Data. 15 In theory, variation in the risk premium due to intermediary constraints should affect variables such as the dividend-price ratio. The reason that |$d-p$| does not show significant predictive power in Table 7 in the presence of |$\textit{PNBO}$| could be that |$d-p$| is affected by both the variation in discount rates and in expected dividend growth, and that transitory fluctuations in the discount rate caused by fluctuations in intermediary constraints have limited effects on prices. 16 We also examine the funding constraint measure by Hu, Pan, and Wang (2013) and the CBOE VIX index (VIX). Neither of them is statistically significantly related to PNBO. 17 He, Kelly, and Manela (2017) show that the leverage of commercial banks became higher during the financial crisis, while that of broker-dealers fell. 18 In the regression, we use the method of Hodrick (1992) to compute standard errors to be consistent with the remainder of the paper. These standard errors do not correct for the error in variables associated with uncertainty in the parameters used to extract the supply shocks. 19 One could easily imagine nonlinear relationships (such as a dependency on the level of jump risk) or slope coefficients that vary with the volatility regime, as well as nonzero correlation between supply and demand shocks due to exogenous factors simultaneously driving supply and demand. 20 Notice that this difference in public investor trading behaviors between the two markets does not necessarily imply arbitrage. 21 GPP aggregate the net demand of both public investors and firm investors, and refer to it as the non-market-maker demand. 22 We thank David Bates for sharing the data on this measure. References Adrian, T. , and Boyarchenko N. . 2012 . Intermediary leverage cycles and financial stability . Staff Reports, Federal Reserve Bank of New York . Adrian, T. , Etula E. , and Muir T. . 2014 . Financial intermediaries and the cross-section of asset returns . Journal of Finance 69 : 2557 – 96 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Adrian, T. , Moench E. , and Shin H. S. . 2010 . Financial intermediation, asset prices, and macroeconomic dynamics . Staff Reports, Federal Reserve Bank of New York . Andersen, T. G. , Bollerslev T. , and Diebold F. X. . 2007 . Roughing it up: Including jump components in the measurement, modeling, and forecasting of return volatility . Review of Economics and Statistics 89 : 701 – 20 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Andrews, Donald W. K. 1993 . Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point . Econometrica 61 : 821 – 56 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Ang, A. , and Bekaert G. . 2007 . Stock return predictability: Is it there? Review of Financial Studies 20 : 651 – 707 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bates, D. S. 2006 . Maximum likelihood estimation of latent affine processes . Review of Financial Studies 19 : 909 – 65 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bates, D. S. 2008 . The market for crash risk . Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32 : 2291 – 321 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bekaert, G. , and Hoerova M. . 2014 . The VIX, the variance premium and stock market volatility . Journal of Econometrics 183 : 181 – 92 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bernanke, B. , and Gertler M. . 1989 . Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations . American Economic Review 79 : 14 – 31 . Bernanke, B. S. , Gertler M. , and Gilchrist S. . 1999 . The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework . In Handbook of macroeconomics . Eds. Taylor, J. B. and Woodford, M. vol. 1 , chap. 21 , pp. 1341 – 93 . Amsterdam : Elsevier . Bollen, N. , and Whaley R. . 2004 . Does net buying pressure affect the shape of implied volatility functions? Journal of Finance 59 : 711 – 53 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bollerslev, T. , Tauchen G. , and Zhou H. . 2009 . Expected stock returns and variance risk premia . Review of Financial Studies 22 : 4463 – 92 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Boudoukh, J. , Michaely R. , Richardson M. , and Roberts M. R. . 2007 . On the importance of measuring payout yield: Implications for empirical asset pricing . Journal of Finance 62 : 877 – 915 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Brunnermeier, M. K. , and Pedersen L. H. . 2009 . Market liquidity and funding liquidity . Review of Financial Studies 22 : 2201 – 38 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Brunnermeier, M. K. , and Sannikov Y. . 2014 . A macroeconomic model with a financial sector . American Economic Review 104 : 379 – 421 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Buraschi, A. , and Jiltsov A. . 2006 . Model uncertainty and option markets with heterogeneous beliefs . Journal of Finance 61 : 2841 – 97 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Carr, P. , and Wu L. . 2009 . Variance risk premiums . Review of Financial Studies 22 : 1311 – 41 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Chen, H. , Joslin S. , and Tran N.-K. . 2012 . Rare disasters and risk sharing with heterogeneous beliefs . Review of Financial Studies 25 : 2189 – 224 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Cochrane, J. H. 1999 . Portfolio advice for a multifactor world . Economic Perspectives Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 23 : 59 – 78 . Cohen, L. , Diether K. B. , and Malloy C. J. . 2007 . Supply and demand shifts in the shorting market . Journal of Finance 62 : 2061 – 96 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Corsi, F. , Pirino D. , and Reno R. . 2010 . Threshold bipower variation and the impact of jumps on volatility forecasting , Journal of Econometrics 159 : 276 – 88 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Jean-Sebastien, Fontaine, and Rene Garcia. 2012 . Bond liquidity premia . Review of Financial Studies 25 : 1207 – 54 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Garleanu, N. , Pedersen L. H. , and Poteshman A. M. . 2009 . Demand-based option pricing . Review of Financial Studies 22 : 4259 – 99 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Geanakoplos, J. 2009 . The leverage cycle . Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers, Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics, Yale University . Gromb, D. , and Vayanos D. . 2002 . Equilibrium and welfare in markets with financially constrained arbitrageurs . Journal of Financial Economics 66 : 361 – 407 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Hansen, P. R. , and Timmermann A. . 2012 . Choice of sample split in out-of-sample forecast evaluation . Working Paper, Stanford University . He, Z. , Kelly B. , and Manela A. . 2017 . Intermediary asset pricing: New evidence from many asset classes . Journal of Financial Economics . Advance Access published August 12, 2017 , https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2017.08.002 . He, Z. , and Krishnamurthy A. . 2013 . Intermediary asset pricing . American Economic Review 103 : 732 – 70 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Hodrick, R. J. 1992 . Dividend yields and expected stock returns: Alternative procedures for inference and measurement . Review of Financial Studies 5 : 357 – 86 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Hu, G. X. , Pan J. , and Wang J. . 2013 . Noise as information for illiquidity . Journal of Finance 68 : 2341 – 82 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Johnson, T. C. , Liang M. , and Liu Y. . 2016 . What drives index options exposure? Review of Finance . Advance Access published November 13, 2016 , https://doi.org/10.1093/rof/rfw061 . Joslin, S. 2017 . Can unspanned stochastic volatility models explain the cross section of bond volatilities? Management Science . Advance Access published April 18, 2017 , https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2016.2623 . Joslin, S. , and Konchitchki Y. . Forthcoming . Interest rate volatility, the yield curve, and the macroeconomy . Journal of Financial Economics . Joslin, S. , Priebsch M. , and Singleton K. J. . 2014 . Risk premiums in dynamic term structure models with unspanned macro risks . Journal of Finance 69 : 1197 – 233 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Kelly, B. , and Jiang H. . 2014 . Editor’s choice tail risk and asset prices . Review of Financial Studies 27 : 2841 – 71 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Kiyotaki, N. , and Moore J. . 1997 . Credit cycles . Journal of Political Economy 105 : 211 – 48 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Lettau, M. , and Ludvigson S. . 2001 . Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A cross-sectional test when risk premia are time-varying . Journal of Political Economy 109 : 1238 – 87 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Longstaff, F. A. , and Wang J. . 2012 . Asset pricing and the credit market , Review of Financial Studies 25 : 3169 – 215 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Lustig, H. , Roussanov N. , and Verdelhan A. . 2011 . Common risk factors in currency markets . Review of Financial Studies 24 : 3731 – 77 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS McCracken, M. W. 2007 . Asymptotics for out of sample tests of Granger causality . Journal of Econometrics 140 : 719 – 52 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Muller, U. K. 2014 . HAC corrections for strongly autocorrelated time series . Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 32 : 311 – 22 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Newey, W. K. , and West K. D. . 1987 . A simple positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix estimator . Econometrica 55 : 703 – 8 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Pan, J. , and Poteshman A. . 2006 . The information in option volume for future stock prices . Review of Financial Studies 19 : 871 – 908 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Rigobon, R. 2003 . Identification through heteroskedasticity . Review of Economics and Statistics 85 : 777 – 92 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Sentana, E. , and Fiorentini G. . 2001 . Identification, estimation and testing of conditionally heteroskedastic factor models . Journal of Econometrics 102 : 143 – 64 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Welch, I. , and Goyal A. . 2008 . A comprehensive look at the empirical performance of equity premium prediction . Review of Financial Studies 21 : 1455 – 508 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS © The Author(s) 2018. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com. This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic.oup.com/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model) http://www.deepdyve.com/assets/images/DeepDyve-Logo-lg.png The Review of Financial Studies Oxford University Press

Demand for Crash Insurance, Intermediary Constraints, and Risk Premia in Financial Markets

Loading next page...
 
/lp/ou_press/demand-for-crash-insurance-intermediary-constraints-and-risk-premia-in-1KA0x6WxpV

References (81)

Publisher
Oxford University Press
Copyright
© The Author(s) 2018. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com.
ISSN
0893-9454
eISSN
1465-7368
DOI
10.1093/rfs/hhy004
Publisher site
See Article on Publisher Site

Abstract

Abstract We propose a new measure of financial intermediary constraints based on how intermediaries manage their tail risk exposures. Using data for the trading activities in the market of deep out-of-the-money index put options, we identify periods when the variations in the net amount of trading between financial intermediaries and public investors are likely to be mainly driven by shocks to intermediary constraints. We then infer tightness of intermediary constraints from the quantities of option trading. A tightening of intermediary constraints according to our measure is associated with increasing option expensiveness, higher risk premia, deteriorating funding liquidity, and broker-dealer deleveraging. Received December 1, 2014; editorial decision May 19, 2017 by Editor Geert Bekaert. Authors have furnished an Internet Appendix, which is available on the Oxford University Press Web site next to the link to the final published paper online. In this paper, we present new evidence connecting financial intermediary constraints to asset prices. We propose to measure the tightness of intermediary constraints based on how the intermediaries manage their aggregate tail risk exposures. Using data on the trading activities between public investors and financial intermediaries in the market of deep out-of-the-money put options on the S&P 500 index (abbreviated as DOTM SPX puts), we exploit the price-quantity relations to identify periods when shocks to intermediary constraints are likely to be the main driver of the variations in the net amount of trading between public investors and financial intermediaries. This then enables us to infer tight intermediary constraints from the option trading quantities. We show that tight intermediary constraints under our measure are associated with increasing option expensiveness, rising risk premia for a wide range of financial assets, deteriorating funding liquidity, and deleveraging by broker-dealers. To construct the constraint measure, we start by computing the net amount of DOTM SPX puts that public investors in aggregate purchase each month (henceforth referred to as |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠), which also reflects the net amount of the same options that broker-dealers and market-makers sell in that month. While it is well known that financial intermediaries are net sellers of these types of options during normal times, we find that |$\textit{PNBO}$| varies significantly over time and tends to be negative during times of market distress. |$\textit{PNBO}$| could be low during periods of weak supply by intermediaries (because of tight constraints) or during periods of weak demand by public investors. One needs to separate these two effects in order to link |$\textit{PNBO}$| to intermediary constraints. We propose exploiting the relation between the quantities of trading, as measured by |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, and prices (expensiveness of SPX options), as measured by the variance premium. Positive comovements in prices and quantities are consistent with the presence of demand shocks, whereas negative comovements are consistent with the presence of supply shocks.1 We summarize the daily price-quantity relations each month. On average, supply shocks are likely to be the main driver of the quantity of trading in months with a negative price-quantity relation. Then we take low |$\textit{PNBO}$| in a month with negative price-quantity relation as indicative of tight intermediary constraints. In monthly data from January 1991 to December 2012, |$\textit{PNBO}$| is significantly negatively related to option expensiveness, and this negative relation becomes stronger when jump risk in the market is higher. In daily data, the correlation between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and our measure of option expensiveness is negative in 159 out of 264 months. These results highlight the significant role that supply shocks play in the market of DOTM SPX puts. In periods with a negative price-quantity relation, |$\textit{PNBO}$| significantly predicts future market excess returns. A one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| (normalized |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) in a month with negative price-quantity relation is on average associated with a 4.3% (3%) increase in the subsequent 3-month log market excess return. The |$R^2$| of the regression is 24.7% (12.3%). The predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is even stronger in months when market jump risk is above the median level (in addition to the negative price-quantity relation), but becomes much weaker in months when the price-quantity relations are positive. Besides equity, a lower |$\textit{PNBO}$| also predicts higher future excess returns for high-yield corporate bonds, an aggregate hedge fund portfolio, a carry trade portfolio, and a commodity index, and it predicts lower future excess returns on long-term Treasuries and (pay-fix) SPX variance swaps. The predictability results survive extensive robustness checks, which include different statistical methods for determining the significance of the predictive power, excluding the 2008–2009 financial crisis, extreme observations of |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, different ways to define option moneyness, and an alternative quantity measure based on end-of-period open interest instead of trading volume, among others. In addition, we consider an alternative method for identifying periods of weak supply based on Rigobon (2003) (see also Sentana and Fiorentini 2001). Using the reduced-form econometric assumptions of this method, we extract supply shocks to intermediaries and confirm the ability of the inferred supply shocks to predict future stock returns. The return predictability results are consistent with the intermediary asset pricing theories, in which a reduction in the risk-sharing capacity of the financial intermediaries causes the aggregate risk premium in the economy to rise. An alternative explanation of the predictability results is that |$\textit{PNBO}$| is merely a proxy for standard macrofinancial factors that simultaneously drive the aggregate risk premium and intermediary constraints. If this alternative explanation is true, then the inclusion of proper risk factors in the predictability regression should drive away the predictive power of our constraint measure. We find that the predictive power of our measure is unaffected by the inclusion of a long list of return predictors in the literature, including various price ratios, consumption-wealth ratio, variance risk premium, default spread, term spread, and several tail risk measures. While these results do not lead to the rejection of the alternative explanation (there can always be omitted risk factors), they are at least consistent with intermediary constraints having a unique effect on the aggregate risk premium. Our intermediary constraint measure is significantly related to the funding condition measures of Fontaine and Garcia (2012) (extracted from the Treasury market) and Adrian, Etula, and Muir (2014) (based on the growth rate of broker-dealer leverage). At the same time, we also find that our constraint measure provides unique information about the aggregate risk premium not contained in the other funding liquidity measures. Our results suggest that when financial intermediaries switch from sellers of DOTM SPX puts to buyers (e.g., in the months following the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy in 2008), tight constraints likely forced intermediaries to aggressively hedge their tail risk exposures, rather than accommodate an increase in public investors’ demand to sell crash insurance. Examples of shocks to intermediary constraints include stricter regulatory requirements on banks’ tail risk exposures (e.g., because of the Dodd-Frank Act or Basel III) or losses incurred by intermediaries. To further examine the risk-sharing mechanism, we try to identify who among the public investors (retail or institutional) are the “liquidity providers” during times of distress: reducing the net amount of crash insurance acquired from financial intermediaries or even providing insurance to the latter group. We answer this question by comparing public investors’ demand in the markets of SPX verus SPY options. SPY options are options on the SPDR S&P 500 ETF Trust that have a significantly higher percentage of retail customers compared to SPX options. Our results suggest that institutional public investors are the liquidity providers during periods of distress. Our paper builds on and extends the work of Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2009) (henceforth GPP) by incorporating the impact of supply shocks into the options market. In a partial equilibrium setting, GPP demonstrate how exogenous public demand shocks affect option prices when risk-averse dealers bear the inventory risks. In their model, the dealers’ intermediation capacity is fixed, and the model implies a positive relation between the public demand for options and the option premium. Unlike GPP, we consider shocks to the intermediary constraint and the endogenous relations among public demand for options, option pricing, and aggregate market risk premium.2 In the empirical analysis, we try to separate the effects of public demand shocks and shocks to intermediary constraints, and show that the latter is linked to the time-varying risk premia for a wide range of financial assets. Our empirical strategy based on the price-quantity dynamics is motivated by Cohen, Diether, and Malloy (2007), who use a similar strategy to identify demand and supply shocks in the equity shorting market. The recent financial crisis has highlighted the importance of understanding the potential impact of intermediary constraints on the financial markets and the real economy. Following the seminal contributions by Bernanke and Gertler (1989), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), and Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999), other theoretical developments include Gromb and Vayanos (2002), Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), Geanakoplos (2009), He and Krishnamurthy (2013), Adrian and Boyarchenko (2012), Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2014), among others. In contrast to the fast-growing body of theoretical work, there is relatively little empirical work measuring intermediary constraints and studying their aggregate effects on asset prices. The notable exceptions include Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010) and Adrian, Etula, and Muir (2014), who show that changes in aggregate broker-dealer leverage are linked to the time series and cross-section of asset returns. Our paper uses a new venue (the crash insurance market) to capture intermediary constraint variations and study their effects on asset prices. Moreover, compared to intermediary leverage changes, our measure has the advantage of being forward-looking and available at a higher (daily and monthly instead of quarterly) frequency. The ability of option volume to predict returns has been examined in other contexts. Pan and Poteshman (2006) show that option volume predicts near-future individual stock returns (up to 2 weeks). They find the source of this predictability to be the nonpublic information possessed by option traders. Our evidence of return predictability applies to the market index and to longer horizons (up to 4 months), and we argue that the source of this predictability is time-varying intermediary constraints. Finally, several studies have examined the role that derivatives markets play in the aggregate economy. Buraschi and Jiltsov (2006) study option pricing and trading volume when investors have incomplete and heterogeneous information. Bates (2008) shows how options can complete the markets in the presence of crash risk. Longstaff and Wang (2012) show that the credit market plays an important role in facilitating facilitates risk sharing among heterogeneous investors. Chen, Joslin, and Tran (2012) show that the market risk premium is highly sensitive to the amount of sharing of tail risks in at equilibrium. 1. Research Design Our goal is to measure the degree to which financial intermediaries are constrained through the ways they manage their exposures to aggregate tail risks. The market of DOTM SPX put options is well suited for this purpose. First, this market is large in terms of economic exposure to aggregate tail risks.3 Second, compared to other over-the-counter derivatives that also provide exposures to aggregate tail risks, the exchange-traded SPX options have the advantages of better liquidity and almost no counterparty risk (other than exchange failure). Third, the Options Clearing Corporation (OCC) classifies exchange option transactions by investor types, a classification that allows us to determine the net exposures of the financial intermediaries and is essential for constructing our measure. Specifically, the OCC classifies each option transaction as one of three categories based on who initiates the trade. They include public investors, firm investors, and market-makers. Transactions initiated by public investors include those initiated by retail investors and those by institutional investors such as hedge funds. Trades initiated by firm investors are those that securities broker-dealers (who are not designated market-makers) make for their own accounts or for another broker-dealer. Since we focus on financial intermediaries as a whole, it is natural to merge firm investors and market-makers into one group and observe how they trade against public investors. We classify DOTM puts as having a strike-to-price ratio |$K/S \leq 0.85$|⁠. For robustness, we also consider different strike-to-price cutoffs, as well as cutoffs that adjust for option maturity and the volatility of the S&P 500 index (which is similar to cutoffs based on option delta). Another feature of option transaction is that an order can either be an open order (to open new positions) or be a closed order (to close existing positions). We will focus on open orders, because they are less likely to be mechanically influenced by existing positions (see Pan and Poteshman, 2006). We construct a measure of the public net buying-to-open volume for DOTM SPX puts (abbreviated as |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠). In period |$t$| (e.g., a day or a month), |$\textit{PNBO}_t$| is defined as \begin{align} \textit{PBNO}_t \equiv \mbox{public open-buy volume}_t - \mbox{public open-sell volume}_t. \label{eqn.pnbo} \end{align} (1) |$\textit{PNBO}$| represents the amount of new DOTM SPX puts bought (sold if negative) by public investors in a period. Because of the growth in size of the options market, there could be a time trend in the level or volatility of |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. Thus, we also consider normalizing |$\textit{PNBO}$| by the average monthly volume of all SPX options traded by public investors over the past 3 months,4 \begin{align} \textit{PNBON}_t \equiv \frac{\textit{PNBO}_t} {\mbox{Average monthly public SPX volume over past 3 months}}. \label{eqn.pnbon} \end{align} (2) |$\textit{PNBON}$| helps address the potential issue with growth in the size of market, and |$\textit{PNBO}$| better captures the actual magnitude of the tail risk exposures being transferred between public investors and intermediaries. The latter matters for measuring the degree of intermediary constraints. Considering this trade-off, we conduct all of our main analyses using both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. It is well documented (see, e.g., Bollen and Whaley 2004) that, during normal times, public investors are net buyers of index puts, while financial intermediaries are net sellers. All else equal, when financial intermediaries become more constrained, their willingness to supply crash insurance to the market is reduced. It is thus tempting to infer the degree to which financial intermediaries are constrained based on the net amount of crash insurance they sell to public investors each period, as captured by |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. However, besides weak supply from constrained intermediaries, weak public demand can also cause the equilibrium amount of crash insurance traded between public investors and intermediaries to be low. The challenge is to separate the effects of supply from demand. We address this problem in two ways: (1) by exploiting the price-quantity relation to identify periods of “supply environments,” when variations in |$\textit{PNBO}$| are likely to be mainly driven by shocks to intermediary constraints and (2) using the Rigobon (2003) method, which identifies demand and supply by exploiting the heteroscedasticity of shocks. Before presenting the identification methodology, we briefly explain our “price” measure, that is, the expensiveness of SPX options. One would ideally like to calculate the difference between the market price of an option and its hypothetical price without any market frictions. The latter is not observable and can only be approximated by adopting a specific pricing model. For simplicity and robustness, we use the variance premium (⁠|$VP$|⁠) in Bekaert and Hoerova (2014) as a proxy for overall expensiveness of SPX options, which is the difference between |$\rm VIX^2$| and the expected physical variance of the return of the S&P 500 index.5 1.1 Identification through the price-quantity relation Our first empirical strategy is motivated by Cohen, Diether, and Malloy (2007) (CDM), who identify shifts in demand versus supply in the securities shorting market by examining the relation between the changes in the loan fee (price) and the changes in the percentage of outstanding shares on loan (quantity). In their setting, a simultaneous increase (decrease) in the price and quantity indicates at least an increase (decrease) in shorting demand, whereas an increase (decrease) in price coupled with a decrease (increase) in quantity indicates at least a decrease (increase) in shorting supply. The same logic applies to the options market. The demand pressure theory of GPP predicts that a positive exogenous shock to the public demand for DOTM SPX puts forces risk-averse dealers to bear more inventory risks. As a result, the dealers will raise the price of the option (a move along the upward-sloping supply curve). Thus, demand shocks generate a positive relation between changes in prices and in quantities. Alternatively, if intermediation shocks tighten the constraints facing financial intermediaries (e.g., due to a loss of capital or higher capital requirements), they will become less willing to provide crash insurance to public investors. Then the premium for the DOTM SPX puts rises, while the equilibrium quantity of such options traded falls (a move along the downward-sloping demand curve). Different from CDM, we would like to identify periods of weak and strong supply (level), instead of negative or positive supply shocks (changes). For this reason, we cannot directly apply their identification strategy. However, the ability to identify supply and demand shocks is still useful for our setting. Consider a month with low |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. If the price-quantity relations on a daily basis mainly suggest supply shocks in that month, then the low |$\textit{PNBO}$| is more likely to be driven by weak supply instead of weak demand. Based on this idea, we run the following regression using daily data in each month |$t$|⁠: \begin{align} VP_{i(t)} &= a_{VP,t} + b_{VP,t} \ \textit{PNBO}_{i(t)} + d_{VP,t} \ J_{i(t)} + \epsilon^v_{i(t)}, \label{eqn.VP} \end{align} (3) where |$i(t)$| denotes day |$i$| in month |$t$|⁠. The presence of jumps in the underlying stock index can affect |$VP$| even when markets are frictionless. Thus, when examining the relation between |$VP$| and |$PBNO$|⁠, we control for the level of jump risk |$J$| in the S&P 500 index based on the measure of Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold (2007). A negative coefficient |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| in month |$t$| suggests that supply shocks are the dominant driver of price-quantity relations in that month, and we expect |$\textit{PNBO}$| to be informative about the variation in intermediary constraints during such times. |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| does not confirm the existence of supply shock in a particular month and does not rule out the presence of demand shocks in the same month. It does indicate that supply shocks are likely to be more significant relative to demand shocks. Similarly, |$b_{VP,t} > 0$| does not rule out the presence of supply shocks in a month, but demand shocks are likely to be more significant. During such periods, we do not expect |$\textit{PNBO}$| to be informative about supply conditions. Furthermore, we expect high jump risk to amplify the effect of shocks to intermediary constraints on the equilibrium quantity of options traded. This is because a main reason that intermediary constraint matters for their supply of DOTM index puts is the difficulty to hedge the market jump risk embedded in their inventory positions. If public demand does not become more volatile during such times, variations in |$\textit{PNBO}$| will be more informative about shocks to intermediary constraints when jump risk is high. The validity of this assumption is an empirical question. In summary, in a month when the price-quantity relation is on average negative (⁠|$b_{VP,t} < 0$|⁠), we expect small (or negative) value for |$\textit{PNBO}_t$| (cumulative net-buying by public investors for the month) to indicate tight intermediary constraints. 1.2 Identification through heteroscedasticity Besides the identification of “supply environments” based on the price-quantity relation, supply shocks can be identified through econometric identification. One method suited for our study is identification through heteroscedasticity of Rigobon (2003).6Rigobon (2003) considers a standard linear supply-demand relationship between prices (⁠|$p_t$|⁠) and quantities (⁠|$q_t$|⁠): \begin{align} p_t &= b + \beta q_t + \epsilon_t, \quad \textrm{(demand equation),} \label{eqn.generic demand} \\ \end{align} (4a) \begin{align} q_t &= a + \alpha p_t + \eta_t, \quad \textrm{(supply equation),} \label{eqn.generic supply} \end{align} (4b) where the volatilities of the supply and demand shocks are |$\sigma_\epsilon$| and |$\sigma_\eta$|⁠, respectively. In general, the residuals will be correlated with the independent variables in each equation, and the parameters will not be identified. Rigobon (2003) solves this identification problem by considering the regime-dependent heteroscedasticity of |$(\epsilon, \eta)$|⁠. Supposing that there are two regimes and the relative volatilities of the supply and demand shocks vary across the regimes, the supply and demand Equations can be identified. In parallel to our empirical strategy motivated by CDM, we also identify demand and supply shocks following the method of Rigobon (2003). There is suggestive evidence that in the market for DOTM SPX puts supply shocks are more volatile relative to demand shocks during the period of the U.S. financial crisis and the European sovereign debt crisis. We thus date the low- and high-supply volatility regimes accordingly and use the price and quantity measures discussed above to estimate the supply-demand system in Equations (4a) and (4b). The two identification methods presented in Sections 1.1 and 1.2 have their respective advantages. On the one hand, the Rigobon method has the advantage of being based on a clean set of parametric assumptions, a basis that helps with the precise identification of the supply equation and supply shocks. However, these assumptions might be restrictive and potentially inconsistent with the data (e.g., the assumption about the linear relations between prices and quantities, the number of volatility regimes, and whether other parameters might change across these regimes). On the other hand, the method based on price-quantity relation does not identify the supply environment or supply shocks as cleanly, but it imposes weaker assumptions on the demand and supply curve that likely makes the results more robust. After constructing our measures of intermediary constraints, we investigate how these measures are linked to asset prices. According to the theory of financial intermediary constraints (see, e.g., Gromb and Vayanos 2002; He and Krishnamurthy 2013), variations in the aggregate intermediary constraints not only affect option prices but also drive the risk premia of other financial assets. This theory implies that low |$\textit{PNBO}_t$|⁠, when occurring in a period dominated by supply shocks, should imply high future expected excess returns on the market portfolio. That is, we expect |$b^-_r < 0$| in the following predictive regression: \begin{align} r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} &= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t \notag \\ &\quad+ c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} \label{eqn.r1} \end{align} (5) where |$r$| denotes log market excess return, and the notation |${t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| indicates the leading period from |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Similarly, we expect |$\hat \eta_t$| extracted from the supply-demand system in Equations (4a and (4b) to predict future market excess returns as well, \begin{align} r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} &= a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}, \end{align} (6) where we expect |$b_s \leq 0$|⁠. Besides the market portfolio, predictability should apply to other risky assets. Finally, the empirical strategy and testable hypotheses above are mainly based on economic intuition. In the Online Appendix, we present a dynamic general equilibrium model featuring time-varying intermediary constraints. The model not only helps formalize the main intuition but generates more rigorous predictions about how intermediary constraints affect the equilibrium price-quantity dynamics in the crash insurance market, the aggregate risk premium, and intermediary leverage. Moreover, we can use the calibrated model to examine the quantitative effects of intermediary constraints on asset prices. 2. Empirical Results We now present the empirical evidence connecting the option trading activities to the constraints of the financial intermediaries and the risk premia in financial markets. 2.1 Data Figure 1 plots the monthly time series of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and its normalized version |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. Consistent with the findings of Pan and Poteshman (2006) and GPP, the net public purchase of DOTM SPX puts was positive in the majority of the months prior to the financial crisis in 2008, suggesting that broker-dealers and market-makers were mainly supplying crash insurance to public investors. A few notable exceptions include the period around the Asian financial crisis (December 1997), the period around the Russian default, the period around the financial crisis in Latin America (November 1998 to January 1999), the period around the Iraq War (April 2003), and 2 months in 2005 (March and November 2005).7 Figure 1 View largeDownload slide Time series of net public purchase for DOTM SPX puts |$\textit{PNBO}$| is the net amount of deep out-of-the-money (DOTM)(with |$K/S\leq0.85$|⁠) SPX puts public investors buying-to-open each month. |$\textit{PNBON}$| is |$\textit{PNBO}$| normalized by average of previous 3-month total volume from public investors. “Asian” (Oct. 1997): period around the Asian financial crisis. “Russian” (Nov. 1998): period around Russian default. “Iraq” (Apr. 2003): start of the Iraq War. “Quant” (Aug. 2007): the crisis of quant-strategy hedge funds. “Bear Sterns” (Mar. 2008): acquisition of Bear Sterns by J. P. Morgan. “Lehman” (Sept. 2008): Lehman bankruptcy. “TARP” (Oct. 2008): establishment of TARP. “TALF1” (Nov. 2008): creation of TALF. “BoA” (Jan. 2009): Treasury, Fed, and FDIC assistance to Bank of America. “TALF2” (Feb. 2009): increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion. “Euro” (Dec. 2009): escalation of Greek debt crisis. “GB1” (Apr. 2010): Greece seeks financial support from euro and IMF. “EFSF” (May 2010): establishment of EFSM and EFSF; 110 billion bailout package to Greece agreed. “GB2” (Sept. 2010): a second Greek bailout installment. “Voluntary” (Jun. 2011): Merkel agrees to voluntary Greece bondholder role. “Referendum” (Oct. 2011): further escalation of Euro debt crisis with the call for a Greek referendum. Figure 1 View largeDownload slide Time series of net public purchase for DOTM SPX puts |$\textit{PNBO}$| is the net amount of deep out-of-the-money (DOTM)(with |$K/S\leq0.85$|⁠) SPX puts public investors buying-to-open each month. |$\textit{PNBON}$| is |$\textit{PNBO}$| normalized by average of previous 3-month total volume from public investors. “Asian” (Oct. 1997): period around the Asian financial crisis. “Russian” (Nov. 1998): period around Russian default. “Iraq” (Apr. 2003): start of the Iraq War. “Quant” (Aug. 2007): the crisis of quant-strategy hedge funds. “Bear Sterns” (Mar. 2008): acquisition of Bear Sterns by J. P. Morgan. “Lehman” (Sept. 2008): Lehman bankruptcy. “TARP” (Oct. 2008): establishment of TARP. “TALF1” (Nov. 2008): creation of TALF. “BoA” (Jan. 2009): Treasury, Fed, and FDIC assistance to Bank of America. “TALF2” (Feb. 2009): increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion. “Euro” (Dec. 2009): escalation of Greek debt crisis. “GB1” (Apr. 2010): Greece seeks financial support from euro and IMF. “EFSF” (May 2010): establishment of EFSM and EFSF; 110 billion bailout package to Greece agreed. “GB2” (Sept. 2010): a second Greek bailout installment. “Voluntary” (Jun. 2011): Merkel agrees to voluntary Greece bondholder role. “Referendum” (Oct. 2011): further escalation of Euro debt crisis with the call for a Greek referendum. However, starting in 2007, |$\textit{PNBO}$| became significantly more volatile.8 It turned negative during the quant crisis in August 2007, when a host of quant-driven hedge funds experienced significant losses. It then rose significantly and peaked in October 2008, following the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy. As market conditions continued to deteriorate, |$\textit{PNBO}$| plunged rapidly and turned significantly negative in the following months. Following a series of government interventions, |$\textit{PNBO}$| bottomed out in April 2009, rebounded briefly, and then dropped again in December 2009, when the Greek debt crisis escalated. During the period from November 2008 to December 2012, public investors on average sold 44,000 DOTM SPX puts to open new positions each month. In contrast, they bought on average 17,000 DOTM SPX puts each month in the period from 1991 to 2007. One reason that the |$\textit{PNBO}$| series appears more volatile in the latter part of the sample is because the options market (e.g., in terms of total trading volume) had grown significantly over time. As the bottom panel of Figure 1 shows, after normalizing |$\textit{PNBO}$| with the total SPX volume (see the definition in Equation (2)), the |$\textit{PNBON}$| series no longer demonstrates visible trend in volatility. Table 1 reports the summary statistics of the option volume and pricing variables and their correlation coefficients. From January 1991 to December 2012, the public net buying-to-open volume of DOTM SPX puts (⁠|$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) is close to 10,000 contracts per month on average (each contract has a notional size of 100 times the index). In comparison, the average total open interest for all DOTM SPX puts is around 0.9 million contracts during the period from January 1996 to December 2012. This figure highlights the significant difference between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and open interest. The option volume measures have relatively modest autocorrelations at monthly frequency (0.61 for |$\textit{PNBO}$| and 0.48 for |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) compared to standard return predictors such as dividend yield and term spread. The correlation matrix in panel B shows that the various quantity measures are negatively related to variance premium (⁠|$VP$|⁠). In addition, both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| are negatively correlated with the unemployment rate (see Table IA1 in the Online Appendix). Table 1 Summary statistics and correlation A. Summary statistics Mean Median SD AC(1) pp test |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 10.00 9.67 51.12 0.61 0.00 |$\textit{PNBON}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.56 0.53 1.07 0.48 0.00 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 138.08 117.10 113.64 0.76 0.01 |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 28.79 19.85 63.21 0.74 0.00 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.18 0.15 0.36 0.70 0.00 |$J$| (%) 12.14 10.81 6.17 0.62 0.00 |$VP$| 19.37 14.56 21.66 0.54 0.00 A. Summary statistics Mean Median SD AC(1) pp test |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 10.00 9.67 51.12 0.61 0.00 |$\textit{PNBON}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.56 0.53 1.07 0.48 0.00 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 138.08 117.10 113.64 0.76 0.01 |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 28.79 19.85 63.21 0.74 0.00 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.18 0.15 0.36 0.70 0.00 |$J$| (%) 12.14 10.81 6.17 0.62 0.00 |$VP$| 19.37 14.56 21.66 0.54 0.00 B. Correlation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$J$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| 0.71 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| 0.21 0.04 |$\textit{PNOI}$| 0.67 0.48 0.33 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| 0.58 0.59 0.23 0.90 |$\textit{J}$| 0.03 0.03 0.08 0.16 0.12 |$\textit{VP}$| –0.22 –0.15 –0.06 –0.07 –0.09 0.54 B. Correlation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$J$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| 0.71 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| 0.21 0.04 |$\textit{PNOI}$| 0.67 0.48 0.33 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| 0.58 0.59 0.23 0.90 |$\textit{J}$| 0.03 0.03 0.08 0.16 0.12 |$\textit{VP}$| –0.22 –0.15 –0.06 –0.07 –0.09 0.54 This table reports the summary statistics for the SPX options volume from public investors and pricing variables in the empirical analysis. |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠: public net open-buying volume of DOTM puts (⁠|$K/S \leq 0.85$|⁠). |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠: |$\textit{PNBO}$| normalized by average monthly public SPX volume over past 12 months (in million contracts). |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$|⁠: public net open-buying volume of all SPX options excluding DOTM puts. |$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠: public net open interest for DOTM SPX puts (in million contracts). |$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠: |$\textit{PNOI}$| normalized by the total public open interest of all options (long and short). |$J$|⁠: monthly average of the daily physical jump risk measure by Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold (2007). |$VP$|⁠: variance premium based on Bekaert and Hoerova (2014). AC(1) is the first-order autocorrelation for monthly time series; the pp test is the |$p$|-value for the Phillips-Perron test for unit root. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 1 Summary statistics and correlation A. Summary statistics Mean Median SD AC(1) pp test |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 10.00 9.67 51.12 0.61 0.00 |$\textit{PNBON}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.56 0.53 1.07 0.48 0.00 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 138.08 117.10 113.64 0.76 0.01 |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 28.79 19.85 63.21 0.74 0.00 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.18 0.15 0.36 0.70 0.00 |$J$| (%) 12.14 10.81 6.17 0.62 0.00 |$VP$| 19.37 14.56 21.66 0.54 0.00 A. Summary statistics Mean Median SD AC(1) pp test |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 10.00 9.67 51.12 0.61 0.00 |$\textit{PNBON}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.56 0.53 1.07 0.48 0.00 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 138.08 117.10 113.64 0.76 0.01 |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$10^3$| contracts) 28.79 19.85 63.21 0.74 0.00 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| (⁠|${\%}$|⁠) 0.18 0.15 0.36 0.70 0.00 |$J$| (%) 12.14 10.81 6.17 0.62 0.00 |$VP$| 19.37 14.56 21.66 0.54 0.00 B. Correlation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$J$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| 0.71 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| 0.21 0.04 |$\textit{PNOI}$| 0.67 0.48 0.33 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| 0.58 0.59 0.23 0.90 |$\textit{J}$| 0.03 0.03 0.08 0.16 0.12 |$\textit{VP}$| –0.22 –0.15 –0.06 –0.07 –0.09 0.54 B. Correlation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$J$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| 0.71 |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| 0.21 0.04 |$\textit{PNOI}$| 0.67 0.48 0.33 |$\textit{PNOIN}$| 0.58 0.59 0.23 0.90 |$\textit{J}$| 0.03 0.03 0.08 0.16 0.12 |$\textit{VP}$| –0.22 –0.15 –0.06 –0.07 –0.09 0.54 This table reports the summary statistics for the SPX options volume from public investors and pricing variables in the empirical analysis. |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠: public net open-buying volume of DOTM puts (⁠|$K/S \leq 0.85$|⁠). |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠: |$\textit{PNBO}$| normalized by average monthly public SPX volume over past 12 months (in million contracts). |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$|⁠: public net open-buying volume of all SPX options excluding DOTM puts. |$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠: public net open interest for DOTM SPX puts (in million contracts). |$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠: |$\textit{PNOI}$| normalized by the total public open interest of all options (long and short). |$J$|⁠: monthly average of the daily physical jump risk measure by Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold (2007). |$VP$|⁠: variance premium based on Bekaert and Hoerova (2014). AC(1) is the first-order autocorrelation for monthly time series; the pp test is the |$p$|-value for the Phillips-Perron test for unit root. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Figure 2 provides information about the trading volume of SPX options at different moneyness. Over our entire sample, put options account for 63% of the total trading volume of SPX options. Among put options, out-of-the-money puts account for over 75% of the total trading volume; in particular, DOTM puts (with |$K/S < 0.85$|⁠) account for 23% of the total volume. These statistics demonstrate the importance of the market for DOTM SPX puts. Figure 2 View largeDownload slide Percentage of total put and call volumes at different moneyness This figure plots the total fraction of volume for calls and puts at different levels of moneyness (measure by strike price, |$K$|⁠, divided by spot price |$S$|⁠). The height of each bar indicates the fraction of the total market volume at that moneyness level, while the colors indicate the breakdown within the strike between public (blue) and private (red) orders. Figure 2 View largeDownload slide Percentage of total put and call volumes at different moneyness This figure plots the total fraction of volume for calls and puts at different levels of moneyness (measure by strike price, |$K$|⁠, divided by spot price |$S$|⁠). The height of each bar indicates the fraction of the total market volume at that moneyness level, while the colors indicate the breakdown within the strike between public (blue) and private (red) orders. Although financial intermediaries can partially hedge the risks of their option inventories through dynamic hedging, the hedge is imperfect and costly. This is especially true for DOTM SPX puts, because they are highly sensitive to jump risk, which is difficult to hedge. To demonstrate this point, we regress put option returns on the returns of the corresponding hedging portfolios at both weekly and daily horizons. We consider both delta hedging (using the S&P 500 index) and delta-gamma hedging.9 The |$R^2$| of these regressions demonstrates the effectiveness of the hedging methods. As Table 2 shows, with daily (weekly) rebalancing, delta hedging can capture around 72% (76%) of the return variation of ATM SPX puts, but only 41% (34%) of the return variation of DOTM puts. With delta-gamma hedging, the |$R^2$| for ATM puts can exceed 90%, but it is still below 60% for DOTM puts. These results imply that when holding nonzero inventories of DOTM SPX puts, financial intermediaries will be exposed to significant inventory risks even after dynamically hedging these positions. It is because of such inventory risks that financial intermediaries become more reluctant to supply crash insurance to the public investors when they are more constrained. Table 2 Explaining options returns with hedging portfolios |$\frac{K}{S}<0.85$| |$0.85<\frac{K}{S}<0.95$| |$0.95<\frac{K}{S}<0.99$| |$0.99<\frac{K}{S}<1.01$| delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam Weekly |$R^2$| 0.34 0.54 0.45 0.75 0.59 0.86 0.76 0.91 Daily |$R^2$| 0.41 0.59 0.46 0.74 0.56 0.82 0.72 0.87 |$\frac{K}{S}<0.85$| |$0.85<\frac{K}{S}<0.95$| |$0.95<\frac{K}{S}<0.99$| |$0.99<\frac{K}{S}<1.01$| delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam Weekly |$R^2$| 0.34 0.54 0.45 0.75 0.59 0.86 0.76 0.91 Daily |$R^2$| 0.41 0.59 0.46 0.74 0.56 0.82 0.72 0.87 This table shows the |$R^2$| from regressing option returns on hedging portfolios returns. The dependent variables are the returns of put options with different moneyness. delta denotes the returns on the delta hedging portfolio for the corresponding put option. delt+gam denotes the returns on the delta-gamma hedging portfolio. The sample period is from 1996 to 2012. Table 2 Explaining options returns with hedging portfolios |$\frac{K}{S}<0.85$| |$0.85<\frac{K}{S}<0.95$| |$0.95<\frac{K}{S}<0.99$| |$0.99<\frac{K}{S}<1.01$| delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam Weekly |$R^2$| 0.34 0.54 0.45 0.75 0.59 0.86 0.76 0.91 Daily |$R^2$| 0.41 0.59 0.46 0.74 0.56 0.82 0.72 0.87 |$\frac{K}{S}<0.85$| |$0.85<\frac{K}{S}<0.95$| |$0.95<\frac{K}{S}<0.99$| |$0.99<\frac{K}{S}<1.01$| delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam delta delt+gam Weekly |$R^2$| 0.34 0.54 0.45 0.75 0.59 0.86 0.76 0.91 Daily |$R^2$| 0.41 0.59 0.46 0.74 0.56 0.82 0.72 0.87 This table shows the |$R^2$| from regressing option returns on hedging portfolios returns. The dependent variables are the returns of put options with different moneyness. delta denotes the returns on the delta hedging portfolio for the corresponding put option. delt+gam denotes the returns on the delta-gamma hedging portfolio. The sample period is from 1996 to 2012. 2.2 Option volume and the expensiveness of SPX options We start by investigating the link between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and the expensiveness of SPX options as proxied by the variance premium (⁠|$VP$|⁠) in Bekaert and Hoerova (2014). Before constructing the measure |$b_{VP,t}$| in Equation (3) for the price-quantity relation based on daily data, we first examine the relation between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$VP$| at monthly frequency. Table 3 reports the results. In both the cases of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, the coefficient |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| is negative and statistically significant, consistent with the hypothesis that shocks to intermediary constraints generate a negative relation between the equilibrium quantities of DOTM SPX puts that public investors purchase and the expensiveness of SPX options. The coefficient (-94.60) in the univariate regression suggests that a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| is associated with an increase in |$VP$| of 4.82, a 25% increase relative to the average variance premium. Similarly, a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBON}$| is associated with a 3.15 unit increase in |$VP$|⁠. Table 3 |$\textit{PNBO}$| and SPX option expensiveness |$\textit{VP}_{t} = a_{\textit{VP}} + b_{\textit{VP}} \ \textit{PNBO}_{t} + c_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} \times \textit{PNBO}_{t} + d_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} + \epsilon^v_{t}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$a_{\textit{VP}}$| 20.32*** –2.83 –4.80 21.05*** –1.88 –5.92 20.96*** –1.13 –7.08 (2.60) (3.05) (3.17) (3.32) (3.35) (3.45) (3.35) (4.23) (7.40) |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| –94.60** –101.57*** 13.16 –2.94** –3.24*** 4.51 –11.48 –20.22 11.43 (40.18) (24.13) (27.09) (1.39) (1.40) (2.80) (18.16) (13.73) (29.18) |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| –6.83*** –0.57** –2.33 (1.81) (0.24) (2.85) |$d_{\textit{VP}}$| 1.91*** 2.05*** 1.90*** 2.20*** 1.92*** 2.38*** (0.31) (0.32) (0.35) (0.34) (0.38) (0.75) |$R^2$| 4.6 34.1 36.8 1.7 30.9 34.5 0.0 29.5 30.1 |$\textit{VP}_{t} = a_{\textit{VP}} + b_{\textit{VP}} \ \textit{PNBO}_{t} + c_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} \times \textit{PNBO}_{t} + d_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} + \epsilon^v_{t}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$a_{\textit{VP}}$| 20.32*** –2.83 –4.80 21.05*** –1.88 –5.92 20.96*** –1.13 –7.08 (2.60) (3.05) (3.17) (3.32) (3.35) (3.45) (3.35) (4.23) (7.40) |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| –94.60** –101.57*** 13.16 –2.94** –3.24*** 4.51 –11.48 –20.22 11.43 (40.18) (24.13) (27.09) (1.39) (1.40) (2.80) (18.16) (13.73) (29.18) |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| –6.83*** –0.57** –2.33 (1.81) (0.24) (2.85) |$d_{\textit{VP}}$| 1.91*** 2.05*** 1.90*** 2.20*** 1.92*** 2.38*** (0.31) (0.32) (0.35) (0.34) (0.38) (0.75) |$R^2$| 4.6 34.1 36.8 1.7 30.9 34.5 0.0 29.5 30.1 The dependent variable is |${\textit{VP}}$|⁠. We use three different measures of the public net-buying volumes: |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, and |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (public net buying volume of all SPX options excluding deep out-of-the-money puts). Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the Newey and West (1987) method with 6 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 3 |$\textit{PNBO}$| and SPX option expensiveness |$\textit{VP}_{t} = a_{\textit{VP}} + b_{\textit{VP}} \ \textit{PNBO}_{t} + c_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} \times \textit{PNBO}_{t} + d_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} + \epsilon^v_{t}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$a_{\textit{VP}}$| 20.32*** –2.83 –4.80 21.05*** –1.88 –5.92 20.96*** –1.13 –7.08 (2.60) (3.05) (3.17) (3.32) (3.35) (3.45) (3.35) (4.23) (7.40) |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| –94.60** –101.57*** 13.16 –2.94** –3.24*** 4.51 –11.48 –20.22 11.43 (40.18) (24.13) (27.09) (1.39) (1.40) (2.80) (18.16) (13.73) (29.18) |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| –6.83*** –0.57** –2.33 (1.81) (0.24) (2.85) |$d_{\textit{VP}}$| 1.91*** 2.05*** 1.90*** 2.20*** 1.92*** 2.38*** (0.31) (0.32) (0.35) (0.34) (0.38) (0.75) |$R^2$| 4.6 34.1 36.8 1.7 30.9 34.5 0.0 29.5 30.1 |$\textit{VP}_{t} = a_{\textit{VP}} + b_{\textit{VP}} \ \textit{PNBO}_{t} + c_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} \times \textit{PNBO}_{t} + d_{\textit{VP}} \ J_{t} + \epsilon^v_{t}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$\textit{PNBO}_{\textit{ND}}$| |$a_{\textit{VP}}$| 20.32*** –2.83 –4.80 21.05*** –1.88 –5.92 20.96*** –1.13 –7.08 (2.60) (3.05) (3.17) (3.32) (3.35) (3.45) (3.35) (4.23) (7.40) |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| –94.60** –101.57*** 13.16 –2.94** –3.24*** 4.51 –11.48 –20.22 11.43 (40.18) (24.13) (27.09) (1.39) (1.40) (2.80) (18.16) (13.73) (29.18) |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| –6.83*** –0.57** –2.33 (1.81) (0.24) (2.85) |$d_{\textit{VP}}$| 1.91*** 2.05*** 1.90*** 2.20*** 1.92*** 2.38*** (0.31) (0.32) (0.35) (0.34) (0.38) (0.75) |$R^2$| 4.6 34.1 36.8 1.7 30.9 34.5 0.0 29.5 30.1 The dependent variable is |${\textit{VP}}$|⁠. We use three different measures of the public net-buying volumes: |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, and |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| (public net buying volume of all SPX options excluding deep out-of-the-money puts). Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the Newey and West (1987) method with 6 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. After adding the interaction between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and the jump risk measure |$J$| into the regression, the coefficient |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| of the interaction term is significantly negative, which implies that |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$VP$| are more likely to be negatively related during times of high jump risk, and that their relation can turn positive when jump risk is sufficiently low. To understand the economic magnitude of the coefficient |$c_{\textit{VP}}$|⁠, we can compare how the marginal effect of |$\textit{PNBO}$| on |$VP$|⁠, |$b_{\textit{VP}} + c_{\textit{VP}} J$|⁠, changes for different levels of jump risk. Our estimates imply that a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| is associated with an increase in |$VP$| of 1.41 when |$J$| is one standard deviation below its mean, while the increase in |$VP$| is 5.71 when |$J$| is one standard deviation above its mean. Similar calculations show that the marginal effect of |$\textit{PNBON}$| on |$VP$| is even more sensitive to |$J$|⁠. The result is again consistent with the intermediary constraint theory, as the effects of shocks to intermediary constraints on the supply of DOTM SPX puts by financial intermediaries tend to strengthen when the aggregate tail risk is high. In contrast, when we replace |$\textit{PNBO}$| with the public net buying volume for all other SPX options excluding DOTM puts (⁠|$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$|⁠), not only are the |$R^2$| of the regressions smaller but the regression coefficients |$b_{\textit{VP}}$| and |$c_{\textit{VP}}$| are no longer significantly different from zero. As we have demonstrated in Table 2, DOTM SPX puts are more difficult to hedge and hence expose intermediaries to higher inventory risks. Thus, the trading activities of DOTM SPX puts are likely to be more informative about the fluctuations in intermediary constraints compared to those for other options. Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2009) show that exogenous public demand shocks can generate a positive relation between net public demand for index options and measures of option expensiveness. They find support for this prediction using data from October 1997 to December 2001. Bollen and Whaley (2004) also find evidence of the effects of public demand pressure on option pricing in daily data. Our results above are not a rejection of the effect of demand shocks on option prices. In Appendix 3.5, we replicate the results of Table 2 in GPP and show that the different time periods is the main reason for the opposite signs of the price-quantity relation in the two papers. Conceptually, the demand pressure theory and the intermediary constraint theory share the common assumption of constrained intermediaries, and both can be at work in the data. For instance, our results in Table 3 show that the price-quantity relation is more likely to be negative (positive) when the jump risk in the market is high (low), indicating that the supply (demand) effects tend to become dominant under such conditions. Next, we estimate the monthly price-quantity relation measure |$b_{VP,t}$| from regression (3) using daily data. The fact that demand effects and supply effects are both present in the data is again evident. Out of 264 months, the coefficient |$b_{VP,t}$| is negative in 159 (significant at 5% level in 44 of them), and positive in 105 (significant at 5% level in 24 of them). These statistics suggest that, according to the price-quantity relation, shocks to intermediary constraints are present in a significant part of our sample period. The months that have significantly negative price-quantity relations include periods in the Asian financial crisis, Russian default, the 2008 financial crisis, and several episodes during the European debt crisis.10 2.3 Option volume and risk premia We now examine the predictions from Section 1 linking |$\textit{PNBO}$| and risk premia in the financial markets. For initial exploration, we run the basic univariate return-forecasting regression using |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. Table 4 shows that |$\textit{PNBO}$| has strong predictive power for future market excess returns up to 4 months ahead. The coefficient estimate |$b_r$| for predicting 1-month-ahead market excess returns is |$-24.26$| (⁠|$t$|-stat of |$-3.45$|⁠),11 with |$R^2$| of |$7.7%$|⁠. For 4-month ahead returns (⁠|$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$|⁠), the coefficient estimate is |$-18.05$| and statistically significant (⁠|$t$|-stat of |$-2.36$|⁠), and |$R^2$| drops to |$4.3%$|⁠. From 5 months out, the predictive coefficient is no longer statistically significant. When we aggregate the effect for the cumulative market excess returns in the next 3 months, the coefficient |$b_r$| is |$-67.16$| (⁠|$t$|-stat of |$-3.54$|⁠) and |$R^2$| is |$18.0%$|⁠. The economic significance that this coefficient estimate implies is striking. A one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| is associated with a |$3.4%$| (nonannualized) increase in the future 3-month market excess return. Table 4 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –24.26*** (7.04) 7.7 –0.92*** (0.32) 4.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.03*** (6.79) 4.8 –0.65** (0.28) 2.5 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –23.86*** (7.64) 7.5 –0.75*** (0.29) 3.2 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –18.05** (7.65) 4.3 –0.62** (0.29) 2.2 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –67.16*** (18.96) 18.0 –2.32*** (0.75) 9.4 |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –24.26*** (7.04) 7.7 –0.92*** (0.32) 4.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.03*** (6.79) 4.8 –0.65** (0.28) 2.5 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –23.86*** (7.64) 7.5 –0.75*** (0.29) 3.2 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –18.05** (7.65) 4.3 –0.62** (0.29) 2.2 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –67.16*** (18.96) 18.0 –2.32*** (0.75) 9.4 This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} $| represents log market excess return from month |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 4 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –24.26*** (7.04) 7.7 –0.92*** (0.32) 4.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.03*** (6.79) 4.8 –0.65** (0.28) 2.5 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –23.86*** (7.64) 7.5 –0.75*** (0.29) 3.2 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –18.05** (7.65) 4.3 –0.62** (0.29) 2.2 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –67.16*** (18.96) 18.0 –2.32*** (0.75) 9.4 |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –24.26*** (7.04) 7.7 –0.92*** (0.32) 4.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.03*** (6.79) 4.8 –0.65** (0.28) 2.5 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –23.86*** (7.64) 7.5 –0.75*** (0.29) 3.2 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –18.05** (7.65) 4.3 –0.62** (0.29) 2.2 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –67.16*** (18.96) 18.0 –2.32*** (0.75) 9.4 This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} $| represents log market excess return from month |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Figure 1 indicates that nonstationarity might be a potential concern for |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. The autocorrelation of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is only 0.61 and a Phillips-Perron test strongly rejects the null of a unit root (see Table 1). However, nonstationarity may arise elsewhere, e.g., through the 2nd moment. For this reason, we also use the normalized |$\textit{PNBO}$| to predict market excess returns. Table 4 shows that, like |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, |$\textit{PNBON}$| also predicts future market returns negatively. The coefficient estimate |$b_r$| remains statistically significant up to 4 months ahead, but with lower |$R^2$| than |$\textit{PNBO}$| at all horizons. The difference in |$R^2$| between |$\textit{PNBON}$| and |$\textit{PNBO}$| shows that we should interpret the high |$R^2$| for |$\textit{PNBO}$| with caution, which could partially be due to its volatility trend. As for economic significance, a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBON}$| is associated with a |$2.5%$| increase in the future 3-month market excess return.12 While |$\textit{PNBO}$| shows predictive power for market risk premia in the full sample, theories of intermediary constraints imply that the predictive power should be concentrated in periods when variations in |$\textit{PNBO}$| are mainly driven by changes in supply conditions. In Section 1, we have proposed to identify supply environments based on the negative price-quantity relation (⁠|$b_{VP,t} < 0$|⁠), and we expect high level of jump risks (⁠|$J_t$|⁠) to also help with identifying such environments under certain assumptions. Next, we examine how the predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| changes in the subsamples identified by |$b_{VP,t}$| and |$J_t$|⁠. Table 5 shows that the predictive power of both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| are indeed stronger (in terms of both economic and statistical significance) during the periods of negative price-quantity relation and during periods of high jump risks. For example, when |$b_{VP,t} < 0$|⁠, a one-standard-deviation decrease in |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) is associated with a |$4.1%$| (⁠|$3.0%$|⁠) increase in the future 3-month market excess return. The coefficient for |$\textit{PNBO}$| becomes considerably smaller in the subsample when |$b_{VP,t}$| is positive, and it becomes insignificant for |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. Table 5 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠: Subsample results |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Subsample |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| obs |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| –84.75*** (26.16) 24.7 –2.67*** (0.85) 12.3 159 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0$| –42.46** (19.65) 9.2 –1.58 (1.01) 4.3 105 |$J_t \geq \bar J$| –87.49*** (26.26) 26.8 –3.08*** (0.98) 13.0 132 |$J_t < \bar J$| –33.80* (17.93) 6.0 –1.47* (0.81) 5.6 132 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –114.11*** (42.65) 32.4 –3.55*** (1.19) 14.2 80 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t < \bar J$| –53.19*** (18.61) 16.3 –1.95** (0.91) 12.1 79 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –60.98*** (22.39) 20.8 –2.36** (1.16) 10.5 52 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t < \bar J$| 17.53 (37.12) 1.3 0.50 (1.74) 0.4 53 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Subsample |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| obs |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| –84.75*** (26.16) 24.7 –2.67*** (0.85) 12.3 159 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0$| –42.46** (19.65) 9.2 –1.58 (1.01) 4.3 105 |$J_t \geq \bar J$| –87.49*** (26.26) 26.8 –3.08*** (0.98) 13.0 132 |$J_t < \bar J$| –33.80* (17.93) 6.0 –1.47* (0.81) 5.6 132 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –114.11*** (42.65) 32.4 –3.55*** (1.19) 14.2 80 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t < \bar J$| –53.19*** (18.61) 16.3 –1.95** (0.91) 12.1 79 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –60.98*** (22.39) 20.8 –2.36** (1.16) 10.5 52 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t < \bar J$| 17.53 (37.12) 1.3 0.50 (1.74) 0.4 53 This table reports the subsample results of the 3-month return forecasting regressions. Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 5 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠: Subsample results |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Subsample |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| obs |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| –84.75*** (26.16) 24.7 –2.67*** (0.85) 12.3 159 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0$| –42.46** (19.65) 9.2 –1.58 (1.01) 4.3 105 |$J_t \geq \bar J$| –87.49*** (26.26) 26.8 –3.08*** (0.98) 13.0 132 |$J_t < \bar J$| –33.80* (17.93) 6.0 –1.47* (0.81) 5.6 132 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –114.11*** (42.65) 32.4 –3.55*** (1.19) 14.2 80 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t < \bar J$| –53.19*** (18.61) 16.3 –1.95** (0.91) 12.1 79 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –60.98*** (22.39) 20.8 –2.36** (1.16) 10.5 52 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t < \bar J$| 17.53 (37.12) 1.3 0.50 (1.74) 0.4 53 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b_{r} \ \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Subsample |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| obs |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| –84.75*** (26.16) 24.7 –2.67*** (0.85) 12.3 159 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0$| –42.46** (19.65) 9.2 –1.58 (1.01) 4.3 105 |$J_t \geq \bar J$| –87.49*** (26.26) 26.8 –3.08*** (0.98) 13.0 132 |$J_t < \bar J$| –33.80* (17.93) 6.0 –1.47* (0.81) 5.6 132 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –114.11*** (42.65) 32.4 –3.55*** (1.19) 14.2 80 |$b_{VP,t} < 0, J_t < \bar J$| –53.19*** (18.61) 16.3 –1.95** (0.91) 12.1 79 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t \geq \bar J$| –60.98*** (22.39) 20.8 –2.36** (1.16) 10.5 52 |$b_{VP,t} \geq 0, J_t < \bar J$| 17.53 (37.12) 1.3 0.50 (1.74) 0.4 53 This table reports the subsample results of the 3-month return forecasting regressions. Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. We then further split the full sample into 4 subsample periods based on the two criteria (⁠|$b_{VP,t} < (\geq) 0$|⁠, |$J_t < (\geq) \bar J$|⁠).13Table 5 shows that for both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, the predictive power is the strongest when |$b_{VP,t} < 0$| and the level of jump risk is high. If |$b_{\textit{VP}} \geq 0$| and jump risk is low, then the coefficient |$b_r$| becomes positive and insignificant for both measures, and the |$R^2$| drops to near zero. In summary, the subsample results suggest that our strategy based on the price-quantity relation does a good job identifying those periods when |$\textit{PNBO}$| are connected to variations in intermediary constraints and in turn the conditional market risk premia. For the remainder of the paper, we use the regression specification (5), which summarizes the subsample results succinctly. To investigate whether the predictability results above are useful in forming real-time forecasts, we follow Welch and Goyal (2008) and compute the out-of-sample |$R^2$| for |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| based on various sample-split dates, starting in January 1996 (implying a minimum estimation period of 5 years) and ending in December 2007 (with a minimum evaluation period of 5 years). We consider the wide range of sample-split dates because recent studies suggest that sample splits themselves can be data-mined (Hansen and Timmermann (2012)). In forming the return forecasts, we first estimate the predictability regression (5) during the estimation period (from date |$1$| to |$t$|⁠), and then use the estimated coefficients to forecast the 3-month future market excess return for |$t+1$|⁠. After obtaining all the return forecasts, we then compute the mean squared forecast errors for the predictability model (⁠|$MSE_A$|⁠) and the historical mean model (⁠|$MSE_N$|⁠) in various evaluation periods that begin at the sample-split dates and end at the end of the full sample. The out-of-sample |$R^2$| is given by \[ \widehat{R}^2 = 1 - \frac{\textit{MSE}_A}{\textit{MSE}_N}. \] Panel A of Figure 3 shows the results. |$\textit{PNBO}$| achieves an out-of-sample |$R^2$| above 10% for all the sample splits and remains above 20% from 2003 onward. |$\textit{PNBON}$| has an an out-of-sample |$R^2$| above 5% for all the sample splits and remains above 10% in the later period. All of the out-of-sample |$R^2$| are significant at the 5% level (1% level since 2000) based on the MSE-F statistic by McCracken (2007). Figure 3 View largeDownload slide Out-of-sample |$R^{2}$| and |$R^{2}$| from 5-year moving-window regressions This figures plots the out-of-sample |$R^2$| and |$R^{2}$| of 5-year moving windows from forecasting 3-month market excess returns based on the specification of (5). Panel A plots the out-of-sample |$R^{2}$| as a function of the sample split date. Panel B plots the in-sample |$R^2$| as a function of the end of 5-year moving windows. Figure 3 View largeDownload slide Out-of-sample |$R^{2}$| and |$R^{2}$| from 5-year moving-window regressions This figures plots the out-of-sample |$R^2$| and |$R^{2}$| of 5-year moving windows from forecasting 3-month market excess returns based on the specification of (5). Panel A plots the out-of-sample |$R^{2}$| as a function of the sample split date. Panel B plots the in-sample |$R^2$| as a function of the end of 5-year moving windows. Panel B of Figure 3 plots the in-sample |$R^2$| from the predictive regressions of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| using 5-year moving windows. The two |$R^2$|s vary significantly over time. They are low at the beginning of the sample. Both |$R^2$| rise to near 18% in the period around the Asian financial crisis and Russian default in 1997–1998. During the 2008–2009 financial crisis period, the |$R^2$| rise above 40%. These high |$R^2$| for the return-forecasting regressions would translate into striking Sharpe ratios for investment strategies that try to exploit such predictability. For example, Cochrane (1999) shows that the best unconditional Sharpe ratio |$s^{\ast}$| for a market timing strategy is related to the predictability regression |$R^2$| by \begin{align*} s^{\ast} =\frac{\sqrt{s_0^2 +R^2}}{\sqrt{1-R^2}}, \end{align*} where |$s_0$| is the unconditional Sharpe ratio of a buy-and-hold strategy. Assuming the Sharpe ratio of the market portfolio is 0.5, then an |$R^2$| of 40% implies a Sharpe ratio for the market timing strategy that exceeds 1. Such high Sharpe ratios could persist during the financial crisis because of the presence of severe financial constraints that prevent arbitrageurs from taking advantage of the investment opportunities. Theories of intermediary constraints argue that variations in the constraints not only affect the risk premium of the market portfolio but also the risk premia on any financial assets for which the financial intermediaries are the marginal investor. Having examined the ability of |$\textit{PNBO}$| to predict future market excess returns, we now apply the predictability regressions to other asset classes. Among the assets we consider are (1) high-yield corporate bonds (based on the Barclays U.S. Corporate High Yield total return index), (2) hedge funds (based on the HFRI fund-weighted average return index), (3) carry trade (constructed by Lustig, Roussanov, and Verdelhan 2011 using the exchange rates of 15 developed countries), (4) commodity (based on the Goldman Sachs commodity index excess return series), (5) the 10-year U.S. Treasury, and (6) variance swap for the S&P 500 index returns (with the excess return defined as the log ratio of the realized annualized return variance over the swap rate; see, e.g., Carr and Wu 2009).14 As benchmark, the first row of Table 6 restates the predictability results for equity (market excess returns). It then shows that, our constraint measures predict the future excess returns for a variety of assets besides equity. In periods with |$b_{VP,t}<0$|⁠, |$\textit{PNBO}$| predicts negatively and statistically significantly (at least at the 10% level) the future 3-month returns of high yield bonds, hedge funds, carry trade, and commodity (for |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, the coefficient |$b_r^-$| for carry trade and commodity returns are still negative but insignificant). Thus, like the market portfolio, the risk premia on these assets tend to rise when the intermediary constraints tighten. The predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| on these asset returns is also economically significant. For example, in a supply environment, a one-standard-deviation decrease of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is associated with a 2.8% and 1.6% increase in the subsequent 3-month expected excess returns of the high-yield bond index and the hedge fund index, respectively. Table 6 Return forecasts for various financial assets |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| Asset class |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Equity –84.75*** –42.46** 19.8 –2.67*** –1.58 9.9 (26.16) (19.65) (0.85) (1.01) High yield –55.23*** –35.26** 22.2 –1.37*** –1.99*** 11.0 (21.37) (15.55) (0.50) (0.66) Hedge fund –32.48*** –18.98* 11.6 –1.01*** –0.40 5.4 (10.67) (9.82) (0.33) (0.44) Carry trade –38.34** –23.10 9.1 –0.47 –0.88 2.0 (18.13) (14.20) (0.43) (0.62) Commodity –71.54* –43.70 8.1 –1.30 –1.80 2.3 (42.26) (30.19) (0.94) (1.34) 10-year Treasury 20.57** 10.76 5.5 0.79** 0.37 3.8 (8.92) (10.65) (0.33) (0.45) Variance swap (⁠|$\times 1{\%}$|⁠) 13.64*** 4.82** 21.2 0.38*** 0.25** 9.5 (4.02) (2.16) (0.11) (0.11) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| Asset class |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Equity –84.75*** –42.46** 19.8 –2.67*** –1.58 9.9 (26.16) (19.65) (0.85) (1.01) High yield –55.23*** –35.26** 22.2 –1.37*** –1.99*** 11.0 (21.37) (15.55) (0.50) (0.66) Hedge fund –32.48*** –18.98* 11.6 –1.01*** –0.40 5.4 (10.67) (9.82) (0.33) (0.44) Carry trade –38.34** –23.10 9.1 –0.47 –0.88 2.0 (18.13) (14.20) (0.43) (0.62) Commodity –71.54* –43.70 8.1 –1.30 –1.80 2.3 (42.26) (30.19) (0.94) (1.34) 10-year Treasury 20.57** 10.76 5.5 0.79** 0.37 3.8 (8.92) (10.65) (0.33) (0.45) Variance swap (⁠|$\times 1{\%}$|⁠) 13.64*** 4.82** 21.2 0.38*** 0.25** 9.5 (4.02) (2.16) (0.11) (0.11) This table reports the results of forecasting future excess returns on a variety of assets. All excess returns are in percentages except those for variance swap, which are divided by 100 for scaling. Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 6 Return forecasts for various financial assets |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| Asset class |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Equity –84.75*** –42.46** 19.8 –2.67*** –1.58 9.9 (26.16) (19.65) (0.85) (1.01) High yield –55.23*** –35.26** 22.2 –1.37*** –1.99*** 11.0 (21.37) (15.55) (0.50) (0.66) Hedge fund –32.48*** –18.98* 11.6 –1.01*** –0.40 5.4 (10.67) (9.82) (0.33) (0.44) Carry trade –38.34** –23.10 9.1 –0.47 –0.88 2.0 (18.13) (14.20) (0.43) (0.62) Commodity –71.54* –43.70 8.1 –1.30 –1.80 2.3 (42.26) (30.19) (0.94) (1.34) 10-year Treasury 20.57** 10.76 5.5 0.79** 0.37 3.8 (8.92) (10.65) (0.33) (0.45) Variance swap (⁠|$\times 1{\%}$|⁠) 13.64*** 4.82** 21.2 0.38*** 0.25** 9.5 (4.02) (2.16) (0.11) (0.11) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| Asset class |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Equity –84.75*** –42.46** 19.8 –2.67*** –1.58 9.9 (26.16) (19.65) (0.85) (1.01) High yield –55.23*** –35.26** 22.2 –1.37*** –1.99*** 11.0 (21.37) (15.55) (0.50) (0.66) Hedge fund –32.48*** –18.98* 11.6 –1.01*** –0.40 5.4 (10.67) (9.82) (0.33) (0.44) Carry trade –38.34** –23.10 9.1 –0.47 –0.88 2.0 (18.13) (14.20) (0.43) (0.62) Commodity –71.54* –43.70 8.1 –1.30 –1.80 2.3 (42.26) (30.19) (0.94) (1.34) 10-year Treasury 20.57** 10.76 5.5 0.79** 0.37 3.8 (8.92) (10.65) (0.33) (0.45) Variance swap (⁠|$\times 1{\%}$|⁠) 13.64*** 4.82** 21.2 0.38*** 0.25** 9.5 (4.02) (2.16) (0.11) (0.11) This table reports the results of forecasting future excess returns on a variety of assets. All excess returns are in percentages except those for variance swap, which are divided by 100 for scaling. Standard errors in parentheses are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Next, both for |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, the predictive coefficient |$b_r^-$| is positive and significant for the 3-month excess returns of the 10-year Treasury and the S&P 500 variance swap. Here, a one-standard-deviation decrease of |$\textit{PNBO}$| in a supply environment is associated with a 1% and 68% decrease in the subsequent 3-month expected excess returns of 10-year Treasuries and variance swaps, respectively. The result on Treasuries is consistent with Fontaine and Garcia (2012), who find the deterioration in funding liquidity predicts lower risk premia for Treasuries. Intuitively, when financial intermediaries become constrained, Treasury values tend to rise (“flight to quality”) as does the volatility in the market. Thus, Treasuries and (pay-fix) variance swaps provide a hedge against negative shocks to intermediary constraints. 2.4 An alternative hypothesis The above return predictability results have two alternative interpretations. It is possible that financial intermediaries become more constrained when the market risk premium rises (e.g., due to higher aggregate uncertainty in the real economy), which in turn reduces their capacity to provide market crash insurance to public investors. As a result, a low |$\textit{PNBO}$| today would be associated with high future market returns, even though a tighter intermediary constraint does not cause the market risk premium to rise in this case. Alternatively, it is possible that intermediary constraints directly affect the aggregate market risk premium, which is a central prediction in intermediary asset pricing theories. To distinguish between these two interpretations, we compare |$\textit{PNBO}$| against a number of financial and macro variables that have been shown to predict market returns. If |$\textit{PNBO}$| is merely correlated with the standard risk factors and does not directly affect the risk premium, then the inclusion of the proper risk factors into the predictability regression should drive away the predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. The variables we consider include the difference between implied and historical volatility used in Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) (⁠|$IVRV$|⁠), the log dividend yield (⁠|$d-p$|⁠) of the market portfolio, the log net payout yield (lcrspnpy) by Boudoukh, Michaely, Richardson, and Roberts (2007), the Baa-Aaa credit spread (DEF), the 10-year minus 3-month Treasury term spread (TERM), the tail risk measure (Tail) by Kelly and Jiang (2014), the slope of the implied volatility curve (IVSlope), and the consumption-wealth ratio measure (⁠|$\widehat{cay}$|⁠) by Lettau and Ludvigson (2001). All the variables are available monthly except for |$\widehat{cay}$|⁠, which is at quarterly frequency. Table 7 shows that, with the inclusion of the various competing variables, the predictive coefficient |$b_r^-$| remains significantly negative and remarkably stable in magnitude for both |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠. Comparing the |$R^2$| from the regressions in Table 7 and the regression with only |$\textit{PNBO}$| (or |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) (first row, Table 6), we see that the incremental explanatory power for future market excess returns mostly comes from |$\textit{PNBO}$| (⁠|$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) interacted with the price-quantity relation indicator.15 Table 7 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and other predictors |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t}<0\}} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| A. PNBO |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –77.22*** –82.44*** –94.46*** –85.81*** –87.33*** –90.86*** –75.80*** –80.13*** –62.70*** (26.09) (26.66) (30.95) (26.61) (26.96) (31.35) (24.59) (31.40) (22.71) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –18.50 –37.81* –47.38** –44.73** –46.26** –47.54** –36.40* –14.42 –59.22 (20.16) (20.21) (22.76) (21.02) (20.32) (22.94) (19.84) (27.59) (37.45) IVRV 0.10*** 0.13*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.54 11.39 (3.20) (7.75) lcrspnpy 6.19 7.75 (4.89) (8.10) DEF –1.58 –5.96 (3.03) (3.83) Term –0.63 –0.63 (0.71) (0.83) Tail 30.56 –52.06 (35.02) (47.76) IVSlope 0.29 0.17 (0.26) (0.29) |$\widehat{cay}$| 92.71** (46.30) |$R^2$| 25.2 21.3 22.9 20.4 20.6 20.8 22.4 39.2 19.9 B. PNBON |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –2.50*** –2.42*** –2.47*** –2.70 *** –2.65*** –2.56*** –2.63*** –2.06*** –2.07** (0.85) (0.85) (0.89) (0.86) (0.85) (0.89) (1.00) (1.08) (0.86) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –0.85 –1.20 –1.41 –1.78 –1.61 –1.60 –1.17 0.06 –4.81* (1.01) (1.05) (1.12) (1.08) (1.02) (1.11) (1.08) (1.32) (2.60) IVRV 0.13*** 0.15*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.13 13.63 (3.17) (7.42) lcrspnpy 3.13 1.51 (5.02) (7.92) DEF –1.71 –5.57 (3.03) (3.89) Term –0.27 –0.10 (0.67) (0.85) Tail 26.94 –38.27 (34.87) (46.84) IVSlope 0.36 0.33 (0.28) (0.31) |$\widehat{cay}$| 108.03** (46.11) |$R^2$| 19.2 10.7 9.7 10.3 9.7 9.7 14.5 32.5 17.7 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t}<0\}} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| A. PNBO |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –77.22*** –82.44*** –94.46*** –85.81*** –87.33*** –90.86*** –75.80*** –80.13*** –62.70*** (26.09) (26.66) (30.95) (26.61) (26.96) (31.35) (24.59) (31.40) (22.71) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –18.50 –37.81* –47.38** –44.73** –46.26** –47.54** –36.40* –14.42 –59.22 (20.16) (20.21) (22.76) (21.02) (20.32) (22.94) (19.84) (27.59) (37.45) IVRV 0.10*** 0.13*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.54 11.39 (3.20) (7.75) lcrspnpy 6.19 7.75 (4.89) (8.10) DEF –1.58 –5.96 (3.03) (3.83) Term –0.63 –0.63 (0.71) (0.83) Tail 30.56 –52.06 (35.02) (47.76) IVSlope 0.29 0.17 (0.26) (0.29) |$\widehat{cay}$| 92.71** (46.30) |$R^2$| 25.2 21.3 22.9 20.4 20.6 20.8 22.4 39.2 19.9 B. PNBON |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –2.50*** –2.42*** –2.47*** –2.70 *** –2.65*** –2.56*** –2.63*** –2.06*** –2.07** (0.85) (0.85) (0.89) (0.86) (0.85) (0.89) (1.00) (1.08) (0.86) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –0.85 –1.20 –1.41 –1.78 –1.61 –1.60 –1.17 0.06 –4.81* (1.01) (1.05) (1.12) (1.08) (1.02) (1.11) (1.08) (1.32) (2.60) IVRV 0.13*** 0.15*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.13 13.63 (3.17) (7.42) lcrspnpy 3.13 1.51 (5.02) (7.92) DEF –1.71 –5.57 (3.03) (3.89) Term –0.27 –0.10 (0.67) (0.85) Tail 26.94 –38.27 (34.87) (46.84) IVSlope 0.36 0.33 (0.28) (0.31) |$\widehat{cay}$| 108.03** (46.11) |$R^2$| 19.2 10.7 9.7 10.3 9.7 9.7 14.5 32.5 17.7 The table reports the results of forecasting 3-month market excess returns with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and other predictors, including the difference between implied and historical volatility in Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) (IVRV), log dividend yield (⁠|$d-p$|⁠), log net payout yield (lcrspnpy), Baa-Aaa credit spread (DEF), term spread (TERM), tail risk measure (Tail), implied volatility slope (Slope), and the quarterly consumption-wealth ratio (⁠|$\widehat{cay}$|⁠). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from 1991 to 2012, except for lcrspnpy and Tail, which is from 1991 to 2010, and IVSlope, which is from 1996 to 2012. Table 7 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and other predictors |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t}<0\}} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| A. PNBO |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –77.22*** –82.44*** –94.46*** –85.81*** –87.33*** –90.86*** –75.80*** –80.13*** –62.70*** (26.09) (26.66) (30.95) (26.61) (26.96) (31.35) (24.59) (31.40) (22.71) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –18.50 –37.81* –47.38** –44.73** –46.26** –47.54** –36.40* –14.42 –59.22 (20.16) (20.21) (22.76) (21.02) (20.32) (22.94) (19.84) (27.59) (37.45) IVRV 0.10*** 0.13*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.54 11.39 (3.20) (7.75) lcrspnpy 6.19 7.75 (4.89) (8.10) DEF –1.58 –5.96 (3.03) (3.83) Term –0.63 –0.63 (0.71) (0.83) Tail 30.56 –52.06 (35.02) (47.76) IVSlope 0.29 0.17 (0.26) (0.29) |$\widehat{cay}$| 92.71** (46.30) |$R^2$| 25.2 21.3 22.9 20.4 20.6 20.8 22.4 39.2 19.9 B. PNBON |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –2.50*** –2.42*** –2.47*** –2.70 *** –2.65*** –2.56*** –2.63*** –2.06*** –2.07** (0.85) (0.85) (0.89) (0.86) (0.85) (0.89) (1.00) (1.08) (0.86) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –0.85 –1.20 –1.41 –1.78 –1.61 –1.60 –1.17 0.06 –4.81* (1.01) (1.05) (1.12) (1.08) (1.02) (1.11) (1.08) (1.32) (2.60) IVRV 0.13*** 0.15*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.13 13.63 (3.17) (7.42) lcrspnpy 3.13 1.51 (5.02) (7.92) DEF –1.71 –5.57 (3.03) (3.89) Term –0.27 –0.10 (0.67) (0.85) Tail 26.94 –38.27 (34.87) (46.84) IVSlope 0.36 0.33 (0.28) (0.31) |$\widehat{cay}$| 108.03** (46.11) |$R^2$| 19.2 10.7 9.7 10.3 9.7 9.7 14.5 32.5 17.7 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t}<0\}} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| A. PNBO |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –77.22*** –82.44*** –94.46*** –85.81*** –87.33*** –90.86*** –75.80*** –80.13*** –62.70*** (26.09) (26.66) (30.95) (26.61) (26.96) (31.35) (24.59) (31.40) (22.71) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –18.50 –37.81* –47.38** –44.73** –46.26** –47.54** –36.40* –14.42 –59.22 (20.16) (20.21) (22.76) (21.02) (20.32) (22.94) (19.84) (27.59) (37.45) IVRV 0.10*** 0.13*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.54 11.39 (3.20) (7.75) lcrspnpy 6.19 7.75 (4.89) (8.10) DEF –1.58 –5.96 (3.03) (3.83) Term –0.63 –0.63 (0.71) (0.83) Tail 30.56 –52.06 (35.02) (47.76) IVSlope 0.29 0.17 (0.26) (0.29) |$\widehat{cay}$| 92.71** (46.30) |$R^2$| 25.2 21.3 22.9 20.4 20.6 20.8 22.4 39.2 19.9 B. PNBON |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –2.50*** –2.42*** –2.47*** –2.70 *** –2.65*** –2.56*** –2.63*** –2.06*** –2.07** (0.85) (0.85) (0.89) (0.86) (0.85) (0.89) (1.00) (1.08) (0.86) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBON}_t$| –0.85 –1.20 –1.41 –1.78 –1.61 –1.60 –1.17 0.06 –4.81* (1.01) (1.05) (1.12) (1.08) (1.02) (1.11) (1.08) (1.32) (2.60) IVRV 0.13*** 0.15*** (0.04) (0.04) |$d-p$| 3.13 13.63 (3.17) (7.42) lcrspnpy 3.13 1.51 (5.02) (7.92) DEF –1.71 –5.57 (3.03) (3.89) Term –0.27 –0.10 (0.67) (0.85) Tail 26.94 –38.27 (34.87) (46.84) IVSlope 0.36 0.33 (0.28) (0.31) |$\widehat{cay}$| 108.03** (46.11) |$R^2$| 19.2 10.7 9.7 10.3 9.7 9.7 14.5 32.5 17.7 The table reports the results of forecasting 3-month market excess returns with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and other predictors, including the difference between implied and historical volatility in Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) (IVRV), log dividend yield (⁠|$d-p$|⁠), log net payout yield (lcrspnpy), Baa-Aaa credit spread (DEF), term spread (TERM), tail risk measure (Tail), implied volatility slope (Slope), and the quarterly consumption-wealth ratio (⁠|$\widehat{cay}$|⁠). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from 1991 to 2012, except for lcrspnpy and Tail, which is from 1991 to 2010, and IVSlope, which is from 1996 to 2012. In summary, the results from Table 7 show that the option trading activities of public investors and financial intermediaries contain unique information about the market risk premium that is not captured by the standard macro and financial factors. This result is consistent with the theories of intermediary constraints driving asset prices. Of course, the evidence above does not prove that intermediary constraints actually drive aggregate risk premia. It is possible that |$\textit{PNBO}$| is correlated with other risk factors not considered in our specifications. 2.5 Option volume and measures of funding constraints We have presented evidence linking |$\textit{PNBO}$| negatively with option expensiveness and market risk premium when |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$|⁠, which is consistent with the interpretation that low |$\textit{PNBO}$| is a sign of tight intermediary constraints. Thus, |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBON}_t$| can be viewed as a measure of intermediary constraint. We now compare this measure to several measures of financial intermediary funding constraints proposed in the literature. These measures include the year-over-year change in broker-dealer leverage advocated by Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010) (⁠|$\Delta lev$|⁠), the fixed-income market based funding liquidity measure by Fontaine and Garcia (2012) (FG), the TED spread (TED, the difference between the 3-month LIBOR and the 3-month T-bill rate), and the LIBOR-OIS spread (LIBOR-OIS, the difference between the 3-month LIBOR and the 3-month overnight indexed swap rate).16 TED spread and LIBOR-OIS spread measure the credit risk of banks. We first run OLS regressions of our constraint measure on the funding constraint measures in the literature. As panel A of Table 8 shows, TED spread is significantly positively related to |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t$|⁠, but insignificantly related to |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBON}_t$|⁠. The positive relation between TED spread and |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t$| is mainly due to the fact that |$\textit{PNBO}$| rose significantly along with the TED spread during the early part of the financial crisis. Subsequently, while |$\textit{PNBO}$| becomes lower (and turned significantly negative), the TED spread also fell and then remained at low levels. This result points out a potential weakness of TED spread (and LIBOR-OIS) as a measure of funding constraint. TED spread could become lower due to banks reducing their own credit risk through deleveraging, reducing risk taking, and buying crash insurance, but that does not necessarily imply banks are less constrained (could be the opposite). Table 8 |$\textit{PNBO}$| and measures of funding constraints A.|$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t = a + b \ \mathbf{X}_t + e_t$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| TED 22.04** 0.56 (10.57) (147.30) LIBOR-OIS 0.25 –0.17 (0.16) (2.04) FG –4.89** –200.65*** (2.32) (77.30) |$\Delta lev$| 42.59** 50.86** (16.68) (23.18) |$R^2$| 4.3 2.9 1.5 8.9 0.0 0.0 4.4 3.4 B. |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{b_{VP,t}<0} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t +\epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –79.97*** –75.91*** –83.52*** –53.78** –2.62*** –3.81*** –2.57*** –1.63** (24.66) (23.94) (26.65) (22.47) (0.84) (1.23) (0.85) (0.83) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –34.84* –38.41** –42.00** –37.02 –1.38 –3.07** –1.50 –3.69 (19.34) (19.37) (19.65) (40.89) (1.02) (1.27) (1.01) (2.79) TED –2.44 –4.83 (3.19) (3.25) LIBOR-OIS –0.05 –0.08 (0.05) (0.05) FG 0.50 0.24 (0.88) (0.86) |$\Delta Lev$| –4.76 –5.82* (3.51) (3.41) |$R^2$| 20.4 34.9 19.6 19.9 14.4 33.1 9.6 18.9 A.|$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t = a + b \ \mathbf{X}_t + e_t$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| TED 22.04** 0.56 (10.57) (147.30) LIBOR-OIS 0.25 –0.17 (0.16) (2.04) FG –4.89** –200.65*** (2.32) (77.30) |$\Delta lev$| 42.59** 50.86** (16.68) (23.18) |$R^2$| 4.3 2.9 1.5 8.9 0.0 0.0 4.4 3.4 B. |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{b_{VP,t}<0} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t +\epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –79.97*** –75.91*** –83.52*** –53.78** –2.62*** –3.81*** –2.57*** –1.63** (24.66) (23.94) (26.65) (22.47) (0.84) (1.23) (0.85) (0.83) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –34.84* –38.41** –42.00** –37.02 –1.38 –3.07** –1.50 –3.69 (19.34) (19.37) (19.65) (40.89) (1.02) (1.27) (1.01) (2.79) TED –2.44 –4.83 (3.19) (3.25) LIBOR-OIS –0.05 –0.08 (0.05) (0.05) FG 0.50 0.24 (0.88) (0.86) |$\Delta Lev$| –4.76 –5.82* (3.51) (3.41) |$R^2$| 20.4 34.9 19.6 19.9 14.4 33.1 9.6 18.9 Panel A reports the results of the OLS regressions of |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t$| on measures of funding constraints. Panel B reports the results of return predictability regressions with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and funding constraint measures. TED is the TED spread; LIBOR-OIS is the spread between 3-month LIBOR and overnight indexed swap rates; FG is the funding liquidity measure by Fontaine and Garcia (2012); and |$\Delta lev$| is the broker-dealer balance sheet growth measure by Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Newey and West (1987) with 3 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from 1991 to 2012, except for the regressions with LIBOR-OIS, which is from 2002 to 2012. Table 8 |$\textit{PNBO}$| and measures of funding constraints A.|$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t = a + b \ \mathbf{X}_t + e_t$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| TED 22.04** 0.56 (10.57) (147.30) LIBOR-OIS 0.25 –0.17 (0.16) (2.04) FG –4.89** –200.65*** (2.32) (77.30) |$\Delta lev$| 42.59** 50.86** (16.68) (23.18) |$R^2$| 4.3 2.9 1.5 8.9 0.0 0.0 4.4 3.4 B. |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{b_{VP,t}<0} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t +\epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –79.97*** –75.91*** –83.52*** –53.78** –2.62*** –3.81*** –2.57*** –1.63** (24.66) (23.94) (26.65) (22.47) (0.84) (1.23) (0.85) (0.83) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –34.84* –38.41** –42.00** –37.02 –1.38 –3.07** –1.50 –3.69 (19.34) (19.37) (19.65) (40.89) (1.02) (1.27) (1.01) (2.79) TED –2.44 –4.83 (3.19) (3.25) LIBOR-OIS –0.05 –0.08 (0.05) (0.05) FG 0.50 0.24 (0.88) (0.86) |$\Delta Lev$| –4.76 –5.82* (3.51) (3.41) |$R^2$| 20.4 34.9 19.6 19.9 14.4 33.1 9.6 18.9 A.|$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t = a + b \ \mathbf{X}_t + e_t$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| TED 22.04** 0.56 (10.57) (147.30) LIBOR-OIS 0.25 –0.17 (0.16) (2.04) FG –4.89** –200.65*** (2.32) (77.30) |$\Delta lev$| 42.59** 50.86** (16.68) (23.18) |$R^2$| 4.3 2.9 1.5 8.9 0.0 0.0 4.4 3.4 B. |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}= a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{b_{VP,t}<0} + d_{r} \ \mathbf{X}_t +\epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –79.97*** –75.91*** –83.52*** –53.78** –2.62*** –3.81*** –2.57*** –1.63** (24.66) (23.94) (26.65) (22.47) (0.84) (1.23) (0.85) (0.83) |$I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t$| –34.84* –38.41** –42.00** –37.02 –1.38 –3.07** –1.50 –3.69 (19.34) (19.37) (19.65) (40.89) (1.02) (1.27) (1.01) (2.79) TED –2.44 –4.83 (3.19) (3.25) LIBOR-OIS –0.05 –0.08 (0.05) (0.05) FG 0.50 0.24 (0.88) (0.86) |$\Delta Lev$| –4.76 –5.82* (3.51) (3.41) |$R^2$| 20.4 34.9 19.6 19.9 14.4 33.1 9.6 18.9 Panel A reports the results of the OLS regressions of |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0} \times \textit{PNBO}_t$| on measures of funding constraints. Panel B reports the results of return predictability regressions with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and funding constraint measures. TED is the TED spread; LIBOR-OIS is the spread between 3-month LIBOR and overnight indexed swap rates; FG is the funding liquidity measure by Fontaine and Garcia (2012); and |$\Delta lev$| is the broker-dealer balance sheet growth measure by Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Newey and West (1987) with 3 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from 1991 to 2012, except for the regressions with LIBOR-OIS, which is from 2002 to 2012. Next, our constraint measure is significantly negatively related to the measure FG. This is consistent with FG’s interpretation that financial intermediaries are more constrained (low |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) in periods when the value of funding liquidity is high (high FG). In the quarterly regression, our constraint measure is significantly positively related to the growth rate in broker-dealer leverage |$\Delta lev$|⁠. That is, intermediary constraint tends to be tight (low |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) when broker-dealers are deleveraging (low |$\Delta lev$|⁠).17 In panel B of Table 8, we further examine the ability of the various funding constraint measures to predict aggregate market returns. Adrian, Moench, and Shin (2010) show that |$\Delta lev$| has strong predictive power for excess returns on stocks, corporate bonds, and treasuries. In a univariate regression (unreported) with |$\Delta lev$|⁠, we find similar results in our sample period. When joint with our constraint measure, the coefficient on |$\Delta lev$| becomes insignificant in the case of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and marginally significant in the case of |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, while |$b_r^-$| remains significant. Similarly, when the other funding constraint measures are used in place of |$\Delta lev$|⁠, the coefficient |$b_r^-$| is always highly significant. These results suggest that relative to other funding constraint measures, our intermediary constraint measure contains unique information about conditional market risk premia. 2.6 Econometric identification of supply shocks Since equilibrium prices and quantities are jointly determined by supply and demand, a key element in establishing a causal link between supply and risk premia would be a method of identifying exogenous shocks to supply. Rigobon (2003) solves the identification problem in the supply and demand Equations (4a) and (4b) through heteroscedasticity. We implement this method using |$VP$| as the price variable and |$\textit{PNBO}$| (or |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠) as the quantity variable. Following Rigobon (2003) (who uses crisis periods in debt markets to identify movement in bond markets in Latin America), we consider the high supply volatility (relative to demand volatility) regime for our identification as the period from September 2008 (the Lehman default) to November 2011 (cancellation of Greek referendum). The second regime is the remainder of our sample. The results of the estimation are shown in Table 9. We see when using either |$\textit{PNBO}$| or |$\textit{PNBON}$| as the quantity measure, there is a statistically significant positive (negative) slope for the supply (demand) curve. The point estimates indicate that a one-standard-deviation increase in the variance premium (an increase of 21.7) is associated with an increased quantity of 103,000 deep out-of-the-money put contracts, which represents an increase of 2.02 standard deviations to the equilibrium quantity. In terms of the normalized measure |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, a one-standard-deviation increase in the variance premium results in an increased quantity of 5.8% times the trailing 3-month volume of SPX options. Table 9 Supply-demand estimation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b$| 25.9|$^{***}$| (3.96) 55.5* (34.8) |$\beta$| |$-0.0823^{*}$| (0.0541) –4.63** (2.37) |$a$| |$-655^{*}$| |$(340)$| –63.4 (53.5) |$\alpha$| |$0.00477^{**}$| (0.00276) 0.269** (0.12) |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b$| 25.9|$^{***}$| (3.96) 55.5* (34.8) |$\beta$| |$-0.0823^{*}$| (0.0541) –4.63** (2.37) |$a$| |$-655^{*}$| |$(340)$| –63.4 (53.5) |$\alpha$| |$0.00477^{**}$| (0.00276) 0.269** (0.12) This table reports parameter estimates of the estimation of the supply-demand system given by \begin{align*} \textrm{Demand:} VP_t&= b + \beta \cdot \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_t,\\ \textrm{Supply:} \textit{PNBO}_t&= a + \alpha \cdot VP_t + \eta_t, \end{align*} using the econometric identification of Rigobon (2003). The |$\eta$| and |$\epsilon$| are uncorrelated with regime-dependent volatilities. We set the high supply volatility regime to be from September 2009 to November 2011. Standard errors are computed by bootstrap. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively; 1-sided p-values are computed for |$\alpha$| and |$\beta$|⁠. Table 9 Supply-demand estimation |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b$| 25.9|$^{***}$| (3.96) 55.5* (34.8) |$\beta$| |$-0.0823^{*}$| (0.0541) –4.63** (2.37) |$a$| |$-655^{*}$| |$(340)$| –63.4 (53.5) |$\alpha$| |$0.00477^{**}$| (0.00276) 0.269** (0.12) |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| |$b$| 25.9|$^{***}$| (3.96) 55.5* (34.8) |$\beta$| |$-0.0823^{*}$| (0.0541) –4.63** (2.37) |$a$| |$-655^{*}$| |$(340)$| –63.4 (53.5) |$\alpha$| |$0.00477^{**}$| (0.00276) 0.269** (0.12) This table reports parameter estimates of the estimation of the supply-demand system given by \begin{align*} \textrm{Demand:} VP_t&= b + \beta \cdot \textit{PNBO}_t + \epsilon_t,\\ \textrm{Supply:} \textit{PNBO}_t&= a + \alpha \cdot VP_t + \eta_t, \end{align*} using the econometric identification of Rigobon (2003). The |$\eta$| and |$\epsilon$| are uncorrelated with regime-dependent volatilities. We set the high supply volatility regime to be from September 2009 to November 2011. Standard errors are computed by bootstrap. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively; 1-sided p-values are computed for |$\alpha$| and |$\beta$|⁠. Table 10 reproduces the predictability results of Table 4 replacing |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| with the extracted supply shocks and normalized supply shocks.18 The extracted supply shock is strongly related to |$\textit{PNBO}$| with a correlation of |$0.71$|⁠. Overall, the predictability with the extracted shocks is very similar to what we found with |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$|⁠, which reinforces our interpretation of the results. Table 10 Return forecasts with supply shocks |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| PNBO supply shocks PNBON supply shocks |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –5.80* (3.25) 2.7 –0.19** (0.08) 2.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –5.23 (3.30) 2.2 –0.14** (0.07) 1.7 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –7.92*** (2.83) 5.1 –0.06 (0.06) 0.3 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –6.32** (3.02) 3.2 –0.02 (0.06) 0.0 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –18.80** (7.48) 8.8 –0.39** (0.16) 3.8 |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| PNBO supply shocks PNBON supply shocks |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –5.80* (3.25) 2.7 –0.19** (0.08) 2.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –5.23 (3.30) 2.2 –0.14** (0.07) 1.7 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –7.92*** (2.83) 5.1 –0.06 (0.06) 0.3 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –6.32** (3.02) 3.2 –0.02 (0.06) 0.0 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –18.80** (7.48) 8.8 –0.39** (0.16) 3.8 This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using supply shocks extracted using the econometric identification of Rigobon (2003). We set the high supply volatility regime to be from September 2009 to November 2011. |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} $| represents log market excess return from month |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 10 Return forecasts with supply shocks |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| PNBO supply shocks PNBON supply shocks |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –5.80* (3.25) 2.7 –0.19** (0.08) 2.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –5.23 (3.30) 2.2 –0.14** (0.07) 1.7 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –7.92*** (2.83) 5.1 –0.06 (0.06) 0.3 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –6.32** (3.02) 3.2 –0.02 (0.06) 0.0 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –18.80** (7.48) 8.8 –0.39** (0.16) 3.8 |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} = a_{s} + b_{s} \hat \eta_t + \epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| |$b_r$| |$\sigma(b_r)$| |$R^2$| PNBO supply shocks PNBON supply shocks |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –5.80* (3.25) 2.7 –0.19** (0.08) 2.8 |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –5.23 (3.30) 2.2 –0.14** (0.07) 1.7 |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –7.92*** (2.83) 5.1 –0.06 (0.06) 0.3 |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –6.32** (3.02) 3.2 –0.02 (0.06) 0.0 |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –18.80** (7.48) 8.8 –0.39** (0.16) 3.8 This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using supply shocks extracted using the econometric identification of Rigobon (2003). We set the high supply volatility regime to be from September 2009 to November 2011. |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} $| represents log market excess return from month |$t+j$| to |$t+k$| (⁠|$k>j \geq 0$|⁠). Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. However, we temper this evidence with a caveat based on the assumptions of the methodology and its application to our setting. The method used here to identify supply shocks assumes linear and stationary supply/demand relationships, and zero correlation between supply and demand shocks.19 The results are likely sensitive to these assumptions. 3. Robustness Checks In this section, we report the results of several robustness checks for our main results. 3.1 Financial crisis One potential concern regarding the predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is that it might be driven by a small number of outliers, in particular the 2008–09 financial crisis. To address this concern, Table 11 reports the results of the return-forecasting regressions in two subsamples: pre-crisis (January 1991–November 2007) and post-crisis (June 2009–December 2012). The predictive powers of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| remain statistically significant in both subsamples. The economic significance of the predictive power is weaker in the pre-crisis period than in the full sample (in terms of smaller magnitude of |$b_r^-$| and lower |$R^2$|⁠), but it is quite strong in the post-crisis period. Thus, the predictive power of our measure of intermediary constraint is not just a crisis phenomenon. The weaker predictive power for |$\textit{PNBO}$| in the earlier sample period could be due to the fact that intermediary constraints are not as significant and volatile in the first half of the sample. Another reason might be that the SPX options market was less developed in the early periods and did not play as important a role in facilitating risk sharing as it does today. Table 11 Return forecasting outside the financial crisis |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Pre-crisis –66.50** 21.91 3.8 –1.85** –0.12 5.3 (27.53) (22.90) (0.92) (1.12) Post-crisis –50.88** –15.73 17.4 –4.87** –1.02 19.6 (25.72) (33.42) (2.39) (3.61) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Pre-crisis –66.50** 21.91 3.8 –1.85** –0.12 5.3 (27.53) (22.90) (0.92) (1.12) Post-crisis –50.88** –15.73 17.4 –4.87** –1.02 19.6 (25.72) (33.42) (2.39) (3.61) This table reports the 3-month return forecasting results outside the financial crisis. Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The pre-crisis period is from January 1991 to November 2007. The post-crisis period is from June 2009 to December 2012. Table 11 Return forecasting outside the financial crisis |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Pre-crisis –66.50** 21.91 3.8 –1.85** –0.12 5.3 (27.53) (22.90) (0.92) (1.12) Post-crisis –50.88** –15.73 17.4 –4.87** –1.02 19.6 (25.72) (33.42) (2.39) (3.61) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3} = a_{r} + b^-_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + b^+_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}} \, \textit{PNBO}_t + c_{r} \ I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} + \epsilon_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNBO}$| |$\textit{PNBON}$| Pre-crisis –66.50** 21.91 3.8 –1.85** –0.12 5.3 (27.53) (22.90) (0.92) (1.12) Post-crisis –50.88** –15.73 17.4 –4.87** –1.02 19.6 (25.72) (33.42) (2.39) (3.61) This table reports the 3-month return forecasting results outside the financial crisis. Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The pre-crisis period is from January 1991 to November 2007. The post-crisis period is from June 2009 to December 2012. 3.2 Moneyness Next, we examine how the predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| changes based on option moneyness. Our baseline definition of DOTM puts uses a simple cutoff rule |$K/S \leq 0.85$|⁠. Panel A of Figure 4 plots the coefficient |$b_r^-$| and the confidence intervals as we change this cutoff value for SPX puts. The coefficient |$b_r^-$| in the return forecast regression is significantly negative for a wide range of moneyness cutoffs. The point estimate of |$b_r^-$| does become more negative as the cutoff becomes smaller. Because DOTM puts are more difficult to hedge than ATM puts, they expose financial intermediaries to more inventory risks. Hence, |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure based on DOTM puts should be more informative about intermediary constraints and in turn the aggregate risk premium than |$\textit{PNBO}$| based on ATM puts. At the same time, because far out-of-money options are less liquid, the |$\textit{PNBO}$| series becomes more noisy when we further reduce the cutoff, which widens the confidence interval on |$b_r^-$|⁠. In contrast, panel B shows that for essentially all moneyness cutoffs, |$\textit{PNBO}$| based on SPX call options does not predict market returns. Figure 4 View largeDownload slide Predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| at different moneyness This figure plots the point estimate and 95% confidence interval (based on standard errors computed using the method of Hodrick 1992) for the coefficient |$b_r^-$| from regression (5) forecasting 3-month market excess returns. In panels A and B, option moneyness is measured by the level of strike-to-price ratio |$K/S$|⁠. In panels C and D, option moneyness is measured by |$K/S$| relative to daily volatility of S&P returns scaled by the square root of days to maturity (see Section 3.2). Figure 4 View largeDownload slide Predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| at different moneyness This figure plots the point estimate and 95% confidence interval (based on standard errors computed using the method of Hodrick 1992) for the coefficient |$b_r^-$| from regression (5) forecasting 3-month market excess returns. In panels A and B, option moneyness is measured by the level of strike-to-price ratio |$K/S$|⁠. In panels C and D, option moneyness is measured by |$K/S$| relative to daily volatility of S&P returns scaled by the square root of days to maturity (see Section 3.2). A feature of our definition of DOTM puts above is that a constant strike-to-price cutoff implies different actual moneyness (e.g., as measured by option delta) for options with different maturities. A 15% drop in price over 1 month might seem very extreme in calm periods, but it is more likely when market volatility is high. For this reason, we also examine a maturity-adjusted moneyness definition. Specifically, we classify a put option as DOTM when |$K/S \leq 1+k \sigma_t \sqrt{T},$| where |$k$| is a constant, |$\sigma_t$| is the daily S&P return volatility in the previous 30 trading days, and |$T$| is the days to maturity for the option. This is similar to using option delta to define moneyness, but does not require a particular pricing model to compute the delta. Panel C of Figure 4 shows that this alternative classification of DOTM puts produces qualitatively similar results as our simple cutoff rule. Panel D shows again that |$\textit{PNBO}$| based on SPX calls and this alternative moneyness cutoff does not predict returns. 3.3 Volume versus open interest In our construction of |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, we focus on the net amount of new DOTM index puts that public investors buy in a period. An alternative way to gauge the economic exposure for public investors and financial intermediaries is to examine the net open interest for the two groups. Between new volume and open interest, which one better represents the degree of intermediary constraints? We use the volume-based measure in our main analysis for a few reasons. The first reason is data limitation, as CBOE does not provide daily long and short open interest data after 2001. Second, when financial intermediaries become constrained, it is likely easier (e.g., due to transaction costs) to adjust the quantity of new DOTM puts traded than to change their established positions. That would make the volume-based measure more sensitive to changes in intermediary constraints than open interest-based measure. Third, taking on an option position that is originally near the money but later becomes DOTM due to market movements is different from taking on a new DOTM option. In the former case, the intermediaries can put on hedges against tail risk over time, which again means these positions are less sensitive to changes in intermediary constraints. Nonetheless, we provide two robustness checks. First, we examine an alternative measure based on the end-of-month public net open interest for DOTM SPX puts (⁠|$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠). The results are discussed below. Second, we construct a |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure using only 1-month options, for which the monthly measures of net volume and open interest are equivalent. We find that the main results hold for the measure based on short-dated options (see Table IA4 in the Online Appendix). For the period of 1991 to 2001, we use daily long and short open interest provided by CBOE to compute |$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠. From 2001 onward, we compute daily net open interest from the volume information as follows: \begin{equation}\label{Eqoi} \textit{NOI}_d^{K,T}=\textit{NOI}_{d-1}^{K,T} +\rm openBuy_d^{K,T}-openSell_d^{K,T}+closeBuy_d^{K,T}-closeSell_d^{K,T}, \end{equation} (7) where |$NOI_d^{K,T}$| is the public investor net open interest of options with strike price |$K$| and maturity |$T$| on day |$d$|⁠, openBuy is the public investor buying volume from initiating long positions, openSell is the selling volume from initiating short, closeBuy is the buying volume from closing existing short positions, and closeSell is the selling volume from closing existing long positions. We then aggregate |$NOI_d^{K,T}$| to compute daily net open interest of DOTM puts (⁠|$\textit{PNOI}$|⁠). We also consider a normalized version of |$\textit{PNOI}$| (⁠|$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠), which is |$\textit{PNOI}$| divided by the sum of public long and short open interest for all SPX options. Table 1 shows that the end-of-month |$\textit{PNOI}$| is around 29,000 contracts on average, and |$\textit{PNOI}$| has higher autocorrelation than |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. Table 12 shows that, like |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, |$\textit{PNOI}$| predicts future market excess returns negatively in the periods with |$b_{VP,t} < 0$|⁠, with significant coefficient |$b_r^-$| up to 3 months in the future. The |$R^2$| of the regressions are also similar to |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠. Additional subsample results for |$\textit{PNOI}$| are provided in Table IA5 of the Online Appendix. Table 12 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} =a_{r}+b^-_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, PNOI_t+b^+_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}}\,PNOI_t+c_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}}+\epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –25.10*** –11.72 8.1 –3.71*** –1.23 5.6 (8.65) (7.93) (1.11) (1.17) |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.79** –1.65 5.3 –2.11* –0.25 2.7 (9.59) (4.72) (1.17) (0.99) |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –19.34** –4.67 4.5 –2.21** –0.26 2.0 (7.73) (7.66) (0.97) (1.19) |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –9.75 –17.17* 4.2 –1.32 –2.32* 2.4 (6.85) (9.18) (0.96) (1.29) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –64.22*** –18.05 14.7 –8.03*** –1.74 7.8 (23.47) (13.50) (2.68) (2.28) |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} =a_{r}+b^-_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, PNOI_t+b^+_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}}\,PNOI_t+c_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}}+\epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –25.10*** –11.72 8.1 –3.71*** –1.23 5.6 (8.65) (7.93) (1.11) (1.17) |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.79** –1.65 5.3 –2.11* –0.25 2.7 (9.59) (4.72) (1.17) (0.99) |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –19.34** –4.67 4.5 –2.21** –0.26 2.0 (7.73) (7.66) (0.97) (1.19) |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –9.75 –17.17* 4.2 –1.32 –2.32* 2.4 (6.85) (9.18) (0.96) (1.29) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –64.22*** –18.05 14.7 –8.03*** –1.74 7.8 (23.47) (13.50) (2.68) (2.28) This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using |$\textit{PNOI}$| and |$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠. Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. Table 12 Return forecasts with |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} =a_{r}+b^-_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, PNOI_t+b^+_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}}\,PNOI_t+c_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}}+\epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –25.10*** –11.72 8.1 –3.71*** –1.23 5.6 (8.65) (7.93) (1.11) (1.17) |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.79** –1.65 5.3 –2.11* –0.25 2.7 (9.59) (4.72) (1.17) (0.99) |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –19.34** –4.67 4.5 –2.21** –0.26 2.0 (7.73) (7.66) (0.97) (1.19) |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –9.75 –17.17* 4.2 –1.32 –2.32* 2.4 (6.85) (9.18) (0.96) (1.29) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –64.22*** –18.05 14.7 –8.03*** –1.74 7.8 (23.47) (13.50) (2.68) (2.28) |$r_{t+j \rightarrow t+k} =a_{r}+b^-_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}} \, PNOI_t+b^+_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} \geq 0\}}\,PNOI_t+c_{r}I_{\{b_{VP,t} < 0\}}+\epsilon_{t+j \rightarrow t+k}$| Horizon |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$b_r^-$| |$b_r^+$| |$R^2$| |$\textit{PNOI}$| |$\textit{PNOIN}$| |$r_{t \rightarrow t+1}$| –25.10*** –11.72 8.1 –3.71*** –1.23 5.6 (8.65) (7.93) (1.11) (1.17) |$r_{t+1 \rightarrow t+2}$| –19.79** –1.65 5.3 –2.11* –0.25 2.7 (9.59) (4.72) (1.17) (0.99) |$r_{t+2 \rightarrow t+3}$| –19.34** –4.67 4.5 –2.21** –0.26 2.0 (7.73) (7.66) (0.97) (1.19) |$r_{t+3 \rightarrow t+4}$| –9.75 –17.17* 4.2 –1.32 –2.32* 2.4 (6.85) (9.18) (0.96) (1.29) |$r_{t \rightarrow t+3}$| –64.22*** –18.05 14.7 –8.03*** –1.74 7.8 (23.47) (13.50) (2.68) (2.28) This table reports the results of the return forecasting regressions using |$\textit{PNOI}$| and |$\textit{PNOIN}$|⁠. Standard errors (in parentheses) are computed based on the method of Hodrick (1992). ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The sample period is from January 1991 to December 2012. 3.4 Public investors: Retail versus institutional As Figure 1 shows, while financial intermediaries typically sell DOTM SPX puts to public investors during normal times, the roles are often reversed during crisis times, most notably during the 2008-09 financial crisis. To understand the risk sharing mechanism between financial intermediaries and public investors, it is informative to find out who among the public investors are the “liquidity providers,” reducing the demand for crash insurance or even providing insurance to the intermediaries when the latter become constrained. The SPX volume data from CBOE do not provide further information about the types of public investors behind a given transaction (e.g., retail vs. institutional investors). We tackle this question by comparing the trading activities of the public investors in SPX options with those in SPY options. While SPX and SPY options have essentially identical underlying asset, it is well known among practitioners that institutional investors account for a significantly higher percentage of the trading volume of SPX options than do SPY options. Compared to retail investors, institutional investors prefer SPX options due to a larger contract size (10 times as large as SPY), cash settlement, more favorable tax treatment, as well as being more capable of trading in between the relatively wide bid-ask spreads of SPX options due to stronger bargaining power. We construct |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| for SPY options using the same procedure as |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, which covers the period from May 2005 to December 2012. While SPX options trade exclusively on the CBOE, SPY options are cross-listed at several option exchanges. |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| aggregates the volume from the CBOE and International Securities Exchange (ISE), which account for about half of the total trading volume for SPY options. Figure 5 compares the |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| and |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPX}$| (equivalent to |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠) series. During the period of May 2005 to January 2012, |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| is positive in the majority of the months. From September 2008 to December 2010, |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPX}$| is negative in 22 out of 28 months, whereas |$\textit{PNBO}_{SPY}$| is negative in just 7 of the 28 months. Figure 5 View largeDownload slide Comparing |$\textit{PNBO}$| for SPX and SPY options This figure plots the public net buying-to-open volume for deep out-of-the-money (with |$K/S\leq0.85$|⁠) puts in the market for SPX options and SPY options for the period of May 2005 to December 2012. Figure 5 View largeDownload slide Comparing |$\textit{PNBO}$| for SPX and SPY options This figure plots the public net buying-to-open volume for deep out-of-the-money (with |$K/S\leq0.85$|⁠) puts in the market for SPX options and SPY options for the period of May 2005 to December 2012. A systematic way to examine the difference in how the equilibrium quantities of trading in the two markets are connected to the intermediary constraints and market risk premium is through the regressions of (3) and (5). These results are reported in the Online Appendix, and we summarize the main findings here. Unlike SPX, the |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure based on SPY is insignificantly (positively) related to the variance premium on average, and does not predict future market excess returns. The contrast between SPX and SPY suggests that institutional investors and retail investors respond differently to the changes in intermediary constraints. In particular, when constrained financial intermediaries start buying crash insurance, they appear to be buying the insurance from the public (institutional) investors in the SPX market and not from the public (retail) investors in the SPY market.20 3.5 Comparison with GPP Our results on the price-quantity relation in the DOTM SPX puts market is related to Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2009). However, our results differ from GPPÕs along several aspects. First, we have a longer sample period, from 1991 to 2012, whereas theirs is from 1996 to 2001. Second, our |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure uses contemporaneous public net-buying volume, whereas GPP use public net open interest,21 which is the accumulation of past net-buying volumes. Third, our |$\textit{PNBO}$| measure focuses on DOTM SPX puts, whereas GPP use options of all moneyness (which is similar to the sum of |$\textit{PNBO}$| and |$\textit{PNBO}_{ND}$| in this regard). In this section, we first replicate the main results of GPP (in table 2, p. 4287) and then examine the differences between the two studies. The dependent variable in Table 13, option expensiveness, is the same as the one used in GPP Table 2, that is, the average implied volatility of ATM options minus a reference model-implied volatility used in Bates (2006).22 GPP regress the option expensiveness on several measures of SPX non-market-maker demand pressure, including the equal-weighted public open interest (NetDemand), and public open interest weighted by jump risk (JumpRisk). They find the regression coefficients to be positive in the period from October 1997 to December 2001. Table 13 Comparison with GPP Table 2 Net open interest Net volume Replicated results GPP results NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk Jan. 1996– 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 4.5|$\times 10^{-6}$| 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 6.4|$\times 10^{-6}$| 1.6|$\times 10^{-8}$| –5.1|$\times 10^{-6}$| Oct.1996 |$t$|-stat (0.72) (0.49) (0.87) (0.79) (0.10) (–0.23) Oct. 1997– 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$|** 2.6|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$| 3.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 4.7|$\times 10^{-6}$|** 4.9|$\times 10^{-5}$|** Dec.2001 |$t$|-stat (2.17) (2.80) (1.55) (3.68) (2.25) (2.57) Jan. 2002– –9.9|$\times 10^{-8}$|*** –7.8|$\times 10^{-6}$|** –6.7|$\times 10^{-7}$|** –5.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** Dec. 2012 |$t$|-stat (–3.13) (–2.40) (–2.35) (–3.32) Net open interest Net volume Replicated results GPP results NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk Jan. 1996– 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 4.5|$\times 10^{-6}$| 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 6.4|$\times 10^{-6}$| 1.6|$\times 10^{-8}$| –5.1|$\times 10^{-6}$| Oct.1996 |$t$|-stat (0.72) (0.49) (0.87) (0.79) (0.10) (–0.23) Oct. 1997– 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$|** 2.6|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$| 3.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 4.7|$\times 10^{-6}$|** 4.9|$\times 10^{-5}$|** Dec.2001 |$t$|-stat (2.17) (2.80) (1.55) (3.68) (2.25) (2.57) Jan. 2002– –9.9|$\times 10^{-8}$|*** –7.8|$\times 10^{-6}$|** –6.7|$\times 10^{-7}$|** –5.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** Dec. 2012 |$t$|-stat (–3.13) (–2.40) (–2.35) (–3.32) The table reports the results from regressing option expensiveness, measured by the average implied volatility of ATM options minus a reference model-implied volatility used in Bates (2006), on measures of option demand. NetDemand and JumpRisk are the equally and vega-weighted public net open interest (or net volume) for all SPX options. |$t$|-stats are computed based on Newey and West (1987) standard errors with 10 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Table 13 Comparison with GPP Table 2 Net open interest Net volume Replicated results GPP results NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk Jan. 1996– 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 4.5|$\times 10^{-6}$| 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 6.4|$\times 10^{-6}$| 1.6|$\times 10^{-8}$| –5.1|$\times 10^{-6}$| Oct.1996 |$t$|-stat (0.72) (0.49) (0.87) (0.79) (0.10) (–0.23) Oct. 1997– 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$|** 2.6|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$| 3.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 4.7|$\times 10^{-6}$|** 4.9|$\times 10^{-5}$|** Dec.2001 |$t$|-stat (2.17) (2.80) (1.55) (3.68) (2.25) (2.57) Jan. 2002– –9.9|$\times 10^{-8}$|*** –7.8|$\times 10^{-6}$|** –6.7|$\times 10^{-7}$|** –5.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** Dec. 2012 |$t$|-stat (–3.13) (–2.40) (–2.35) (–3.32) Net open interest Net volume Replicated results GPP results NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk NetDemand JumpRisk Jan. 1996– 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 4.5|$\times 10^{-6}$| 2.1|$\times 10^{-7}$| 6.4|$\times 10^{-6}$| 1.6|$\times 10^{-8}$| –5.1|$\times 10^{-6}$| Oct.1996 |$t$|-stat (0.72) (0.49) (0.87) (0.79) (0.10) (–0.23) Oct. 1997– 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$|** 2.6|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 3.8|$\times 10^{-7}$| 3.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** 4.7|$\times 10^{-6}$|** 4.9|$\times 10^{-5}$|** Dec.2001 |$t$|-stat (2.17) (2.80) (1.55) (3.68) (2.25) (2.57) Jan. 2002– –9.9|$\times 10^{-8}$|*** –7.8|$\times 10^{-6}$|** –6.7|$\times 10^{-7}$|** –5.2|$\times 10^{-5}$|*** Dec. 2012 |$t$|-stat (–3.13) (–2.40) (–2.35) (–3.32) The table reports the results from regressing option expensiveness, measured by the average implied volatility of ATM options minus a reference model-implied volatility used in Bates (2006), on measures of option demand. NetDemand and JumpRisk are the equally and vega-weighted public net open interest (or net volume) for all SPX options. |$t$|-stats are computed based on Newey and West (1987) standard errors with 10 lags. ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. In Table 13, we obtain very similar results to GPP for the two subsamples January 1996–October 1996 and October 1997–December 2001 for the open interest-based measures. We also construct two net volume-based measures and again find that they are positively related to option expensiveness in the period from October 1997 to December 2001. Next, for the period 2002–2012, we use daily volume data to extend the net open interest measures (constructed using the procedure described in Section 3.3). In this subsample, we find that the coefficients on both the open interest and volume-based measures become negative and statistically significant. This finding is consistent with our finding of a negative price-quantity relation in the full sample (see Table 3). The changing signs of the price-quantity relation in different subsamples suggest that the effects of demand shocks and supply shocks are both present in the SPX option market. 4. Conclusion We provide evidence that the trading activities of financial intermediaries in the market of DOTM SPX put options are informative about the degree of intermediary constraints. In periods when supply shocks are likely to be the main force behind the variations in the price-quantity relation in the DOTM SPX put market, our public investor net-buying volume measure, |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠, has strong predictive power for future market excess returns and the returns for a range of other financial assets. The predictive power of |$\textit{PNBO}$| is stronger during periods when the market jump risk is high, and it is stronger for DOTM puts. |$\textit{PNBO}$| is also associated with several funding liquidity measures in the literature. Moreover, the information that |$\textit{PNBO}$| contains about the market risk premium is not captured by the standard financial and macro variables. These results suggest that time-varying intermediary constraints are driving the supply of crash insurance by financial intermediaries and the risk premia in financial markets. We thank Tobias Adrian, David Bates, Robert Battalio, Geert Bekaert, Harjoat Bhamra, Ken French, Nicolae Garleanu, Zhiguo He, Boris Ilyevsky, Gary Katz, Bryan Kelly, Lei Lian, Andrew Lo, Dmitriy Muravyev, Jun Pan, Lasse Pedersen, Steve Ross, Paul Stephens, Ken Singleton, Emil Siriwardane, Moto Yogo, and Hao Zhou and participants at numerous conferences and seminars for comments. We thank Ernest Liu for excellent research assistance. Ni acknowledges the financial support from Hong Kong RGC (644311). Supplementary data can be found on The Review of Financial Studies Web site. Appendix A1. Physical Jump Risk The construction of the jump risk measure |$J$|⁠, which we briefly outline here, follows Bekaert and Hoerova (2014) and Corsi, Pirino, and Reno (2010). The monthly jump |$J$| is the average of daily jump |$J^d$|⁠, which is defined as \begin{equation} J^d_t=\max[RV^d_t - TBPV^d_t, 0], \end{equation} (A1) where |$RV^d_t$| is the S&P 500 daily realized variance (based on 5-minute returns), and |$TBPV^d_t$| stands for threshold bipower variation, which is defined as follows (see Corsi, Pirino, and Reno, 2010, equation (2.14)): \begin{equation} TBPV^d_t=\frac{1}{0.7979^2}\sum^{N}_{j=2}\left |r_{j-1}\cdot r_j \right |\cdot I_{r^2_{j-1}\leq \vartheta_{j-1}}\cdot I_{r^2_{j}\leq \vartheta_{j}}. \end{equation} (A2) Here, |$r_j$| is the |$j$|th 5-minute return on day |$t$|⁠; |$\vartheta_{j}$| is a stochastic threshold, \begin{equation} \vartheta_{j}=c_{\vartheta}^2\cdot \hat{V_j}, \end{equation} (A3) where |$c_{\vartheta}$| is a scale-free constant (set to 3), and |$\hat{V_j}$| is an auxiliary estimator of variance, which is estimated through the following iteration, \begin{equation} \hat{V}^Z_j=\frac{\sum^L_{i=-L,i\neq-1,0,1} K \left( \frac{i}{L} \right) r^2_{j+i} I_{ \left \{ r^2_{j+i} \leq c_{\vartheta}^2 \cdot \hat {V}_{j+i}^{Z-1} \right \}}} { \sum^L_{i=-L,i \neq-1,0,1} K \left( \frac{i}{L} \right) I_{\left \{ r_{j+i}^2 \leq c_{\vartheta}^2 \cdot \hat{V}^{Z-1}_{j+i}\right \}}}, \quad Z=1,2,... \end{equation} (A4) The starting value is |$\hat{V}_j^0=+\infty$|⁠. In each iteration step, large returns are eliminated based on the condition |$r_{j}^2>c^2_{\vartheta}\cdot \hat{V}^{Z-1}_{j}$|⁠, and the iteration stops when there are no more large returns to remove. The bandwidth parameter |$L$| determines the number of adjacent returns included in the estimation of the local variance around point |$j$| (with the observation at |$j$| and the two adjacent ones excluded). We set |$L$| = 25 and use a Gaussian kernel |$K(y)= (1/\sqrt{2\pi}) \exp(-y^2/2)$|⁠. A2. Additional Empirical Results To check whether our supply-environment indicator |$I_{b_{VP,t} < 0}$| does a good job identifying important events of supply shocks, Table A1 shows the value of our indicator during a set of months in which significant events have occurred in the financial markets, and which are likely associated with either positive or negative supply shocks for financial intermediaries. In addition, Table A1 also reports the value of the indicators based on sign of |$b_{VP,t}$| and the CDM method from November 2007 to June 2009, the period of the 2008 financial crisis. Outside the 2008 crisis, the strategy based on the sign of |$b_{VP,t}$| identifies the major events seven times out of ten, whereas the CDM strategy identifies two events. Inside the 2008 crisis, the two indicators both pick up 12 out of 20 months. Table A1 Indicators of supply environment Month and Year |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$| CDM Events Oct. 1997 0 0 Asian financial crisis Nov. 1998 1 0 Russian financial crisis Apr. 2003 1 0 Start of the Iraq War Aug. 2007 0 1 Quant crisis Nov. 2007 1 1 Liquidity deterioration in interbank funding market Dec. 2007 1 0 Creation of TAF Jan. 2008 1 0 Bank of America acquisition of Countrywide Feb. 2008 0 0 Northern Rock taken into state ownership Mar. 2008 0 1 Sale of Bear Sterns to J. P. Morgan Apr. 2008 1 1 FOMC rate cut May 2008 0 1 FOMC expands the list of eligible collateral for TSLF Jun. 2008 1 0 S&P downgrade of AMBAC and MBIA Jul. 2008 1 1 Failure of IndyMac Aug. 2008 1 1 FOMC maintains federal funds rate target Sept. 2008 1 1 Lehman Bankruptcy Oct. 2008 0 0 Establishment of TARP Nov. 2008 1 0 Creation of TALF Dec. 2008 1 1 Fed extension of liquidity facility Jan. 2009 0 1 Treasury, Fed, FDIC assistance to BofA Feb. 2009 1 1 Increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion Mar. 2009 0 1 Apr. 2009 0 0 May 2009 1 1 Jun. 2009 0 0 Large banks’ repayments of bailout funds Dec. 2009 1 0 Escalation of Greek debt crisis Apr. 2010 0 0 Greece seeks financial support May 2010 1 0 Establishment of EFSM and EFSF Sept. 2010 1 1 Second Greek bailout installment Jun. 2011 1 0 Merkel agrees to Greece bondholder role Oct. 2011 1 0 Call for a Greek referendum Month and Year |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$| CDM Events Oct. 1997 0 0 Asian financial crisis Nov. 1998 1 0 Russian financial crisis Apr. 2003 1 0 Start of the Iraq War Aug. 2007 0 1 Quant crisis Nov. 2007 1 1 Liquidity deterioration in interbank funding market Dec. 2007 1 0 Creation of TAF Jan. 2008 1 0 Bank of America acquisition of Countrywide Feb. 2008 0 0 Northern Rock taken into state ownership Mar. 2008 0 1 Sale of Bear Sterns to J. P. Morgan Apr. 2008 1 1 FOMC rate cut May 2008 0 1 FOMC expands the list of eligible collateral for TSLF Jun. 2008 1 0 S&P downgrade of AMBAC and MBIA Jul. 2008 1 1 Failure of IndyMac Aug. 2008 1 1 FOMC maintains federal funds rate target Sept. 2008 1 1 Lehman Bankruptcy Oct. 2008 0 0 Establishment of TARP Nov. 2008 1 0 Creation of TALF Dec. 2008 1 1 Fed extension of liquidity facility Jan. 2009 0 1 Treasury, Fed, FDIC assistance to BofA Feb. 2009 1 1 Increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion Mar. 2009 0 1 Apr. 2009 0 0 May 2009 1 1 Jun. 2009 0 0 Large banks’ repayments of bailout funds Dec. 2009 1 0 Escalation of Greek debt crisis Apr. 2010 0 0 Greece seeks financial support May 2010 1 0 Establishment of EFSM and EFSF Sept. 2010 1 1 Second Greek bailout installment Jun. 2011 1 0 Merkel agrees to Greece bondholder role Oct. 2011 1 0 Call for a Greek referendum This table reports the indicators of supply environment based on the sign of |$b_{VP,t}$| and based on the Cohen, Diether, and Malloy (2007) (CDM) method. The months listed include those associated with major events in the global financial markets. They also include the period of November 2007 to June 2009, the period of the 2008 financial crisis. For more details of the events during the 2008 financial crisis, see the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Web page (https://www.stlouisfed.org/financial-crisis/full-timeline). Table A1 Indicators of supply environment Month and Year |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$| CDM Events Oct. 1997 0 0 Asian financial crisis Nov. 1998 1 0 Russian financial crisis Apr. 2003 1 0 Start of the Iraq War Aug. 2007 0 1 Quant crisis Nov. 2007 1 1 Liquidity deterioration in interbank funding market Dec. 2007 1 0 Creation of TAF Jan. 2008 1 0 Bank of America acquisition of Countrywide Feb. 2008 0 0 Northern Rock taken into state ownership Mar. 2008 0 1 Sale of Bear Sterns to J. P. Morgan Apr. 2008 1 1 FOMC rate cut May 2008 0 1 FOMC expands the list of eligible collateral for TSLF Jun. 2008 1 0 S&P downgrade of AMBAC and MBIA Jul. 2008 1 1 Failure of IndyMac Aug. 2008 1 1 FOMC maintains federal funds rate target Sept. 2008 1 1 Lehman Bankruptcy Oct. 2008 0 0 Establishment of TARP Nov. 2008 1 0 Creation of TALF Dec. 2008 1 1 Fed extension of liquidity facility Jan. 2009 0 1 Treasury, Fed, FDIC assistance to BofA Feb. 2009 1 1 Increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion Mar. 2009 0 1 Apr. 2009 0 0 May 2009 1 1 Jun. 2009 0 0 Large banks’ repayments of bailout funds Dec. 2009 1 0 Escalation of Greek debt crisis Apr. 2010 0 0 Greece seeks financial support May 2010 1 0 Establishment of EFSM and EFSF Sept. 2010 1 1 Second Greek bailout installment Jun. 2011 1 0 Merkel agrees to Greece bondholder role Oct. 2011 1 0 Call for a Greek referendum Month and Year |$I_{b_{VP,t}<0}$| CDM Events Oct. 1997 0 0 Asian financial crisis Nov. 1998 1 0 Russian financial crisis Apr. 2003 1 0 Start of the Iraq War Aug. 2007 0 1 Quant crisis Nov. 2007 1 1 Liquidity deterioration in interbank funding market Dec. 2007 1 0 Creation of TAF Jan. 2008 1 0 Bank of America acquisition of Countrywide Feb. 2008 0 0 Northern Rock taken into state ownership Mar. 2008 0 1 Sale of Bear Sterns to J. P. Morgan Apr. 2008 1 1 FOMC rate cut May 2008 0 1 FOMC expands the list of eligible collateral for TSLF Jun. 2008 1 0 S&P downgrade of AMBAC and MBIA Jul. 2008 1 1 Failure of IndyMac Aug. 2008 1 1 FOMC maintains federal funds rate target Sept. 2008 1 1 Lehman Bankruptcy Oct. 2008 0 0 Establishment of TARP Nov. 2008 1 0 Creation of TALF Dec. 2008 1 1 Fed extension of liquidity facility Jan. 2009 0 1 Treasury, Fed, FDIC assistance to BofA Feb. 2009 1 1 Increase of TALF to |${\$}$|1 trillion Mar. 2009 0 1 Apr. 2009 0 0 May 2009 1 1 Jun. 2009 0 0 Large banks’ repayments of bailout funds Dec. 2009 1 0 Escalation of Greek debt crisis Apr. 2010 0 0 Greece seeks financial support May 2010 1 0 Establishment of EFSM and EFSF Sept. 2010 1 1 Second Greek bailout installment Jun. 2011 1 0 Merkel agrees to Greece bondholder role Oct. 2011 1 0 Call for a Greek referendum This table reports the indicators of supply environment based on the sign of |$b_{VP,t}$| and based on the Cohen, Diether, and Malloy (2007) (CDM) method. The months listed include those associated with major events in the global financial markets. They also include the period of November 2007 to June 2009, the period of the 2008 financial crisis. For more details of the events during the 2008 financial crisis, see the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Web page (https://www.stlouisfed.org/financial-crisis/full-timeline). Additional empirical results and robustness checks are provided in the Online Appendix. They include (1) a table of correlations between |$\textit{PNBO}$| and various macroeconomic and financial variables (Table IA2); (2) systematic analysis of the statistical significance for the return-forecasting regressions using |$PBNO$| and |$\textit{PNBON}$| (Table IA3); (3) return-forecasting regression with |$\textit{PNBO}_{1month}$| (and |$\textit{PNBON}_{1month}$|⁠), which is |$\textit{PNBO}$| constructed using only options with 1 month or less to maturity (Table IA4); (4) subsample return-forecasting regressions with |$\textit{PNOI}$| (Table IA5); (5) return-forecasting regression with |$PNB$| (and |$PNBN$|⁠), which is the public net buy volume for DOTM SPX puts including both open and close transactions (Table IA6); (6) return-forecasting regression using a modified CDM method (Table IA7); (7) return-forecasting regression using |$b_{\textit{VP}}+c_{\textit{VP}} J_t$| as indicator (Table IA8); and (8) subsample return-forecasting regressions with the log dividend-price ratio (Table IA9). Footnotes 1 We assume public investors’ demand curve is downward sloping and financial intermediaries’ supply curve is upward sloping. These assumptions apply when both groups are (effectively) risk averse and cannot fully unload their inventory risks through hedging. Notice that the presence of one type of shock does not rule out the presence of the other. 2 We present a general equilibrium model in the Online Appendix that captures time-varying intermediary constraints in reduced form and is quite tractable. 3 For example, Johnson, Liang, and Liu (2016) estimate that the change in value of index options outstanding is on the order of trillions of dollars following a severe market crash and the majority of which is contributed by out-of-money SPX puts. 4 For a robustness check, we also define |$\textit{PNBON}$| using past 12-month average public trading volume in the denominator. Doing so generates similar results. 5 The expected physical variance 1-month ahead (22 trading days) is computed using model 8 in Bekaert and Hoerova (2014): |$E_d\left [ RV_{d+1}^{(22)} \right] = 3.730+0.108\frac{VIX^2_d}{12} +0.199RV_{d}^{(-22)}+0.33\frac{22}{5}RV_{d}^{(-5)}+0.107\cdot22RV_{d}^{(-1)}$|⁠, where |$RV_{d}^{(-j)}$| is the sum of daily realized variances from day |$d-j+1$| to day |$d$|⁠. The daily realized variance sums squared 5-minute intraday S&P 500 returns and the squared close-to-open return. 6 We thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion. 7 The GM and Ford downgrades in May 2005 might have been related to the negative |$\textit{PNBO}$| in 2005. 8 One potential concern is that the volatility of |$\textit{PNBO}$| may be nonstationary. If we apply the structural break test of Andrews (1993) to the monthly realized volatility (computed from daily |$\textit{PNBO}$|⁠), we find evidence for a break in the time trend in volatility at |$\tau=$| March 2007 (⁠|$F_{max} = 50.4> F_{crit, 1{\%}} = 15.56$|⁠). Subsequent to this break, the point estimate of the time trend is negative, indicating that volatilities declined (or at least didn’t continue to increase) from this point. 9 We restrict the options to be between 15 and 90 days to maturity to ensure liquidity. For delta-gamma hedging, we use at-the-money puts expiring in the following month in addition to the S&P 500 index. 10 Table A1 in the appendix provides more details, as well as a comparison between our strategy and a direct application of the CDM method to identify supply environments. 11 The standard errors for the return-forecasting regressions are based on the method of Hodrick (1992). We provide additional results on statistical inference in Table IA2 in the Online Appendix, including Newey and West (1987) standard errors with long lags, bootstrapped confidence intervals, and the test statistic of Muller (2014). See Ang and Bekaert (2007) for a further discussion on long-horizon statistical inference. 12 Note that the predictability in returns in Table 4 is not accounted for by variation in |$VP$|⁠, showing that |$\textit{PNBO}$| represents a risk source that drives returns independent incrementally to its effect of prices (seen in Table 3). Thus, |$\textit{PNBO}$| represents an unspanned risk similar to those found in the term structure literature like in Joslin, Priebsch, and Singleton (2014), Joslin (2017), or Joslin, and Konchitchki (Forthcoming), among others. 13 While using the level of jump risk to split the sample is motivated by the difficulty to hedge tail risk, the correlation between the two dummy variables of whether |$J_t$| and |$VP_t$| are above their respective sample medians is 0.97 (the correlation between |$J_t$| and |$VP_t$| is 0.54), meaning that the same results apply if we split the samples based on |$VP_t$|⁠. 14 Data for the returns on high-yield bonds, commodity, and hedge funds are from Datastream. Government bond return data are from Global Financial Data. 15 In theory, variation in the risk premium due to intermediary constraints should affect variables such as the dividend-price ratio. The reason that |$d-p$| does not show significant predictive power in Table 7 in the presence of |$\textit{PNBO}$| could be that |$d-p$| is affected by both the variation in discount rates and in expected dividend growth, and that transitory fluctuations in the discount rate caused by fluctuations in intermediary constraints have limited effects on prices. 16 We also examine the funding constraint measure by Hu, Pan, and Wang (2013) and the CBOE VIX index (VIX). Neither of them is statistically significantly related to PNBO. 17 He, Kelly, and Manela (2017) show that the leverage of commercial banks became higher during the financial crisis, while that of broker-dealers fell. 18 In the regression, we use the method of Hodrick (1992) to compute standard errors to be consistent with the remainder of the paper. These standard errors do not correct for the error in variables associated with uncertainty in the parameters used to extract the supply shocks. 19 One could easily imagine nonlinear relationships (such as a dependency on the level of jump risk) or slope coefficients that vary with the volatility regime, as well as nonzero correlation between supply and demand shocks due to exogenous factors simultaneously driving supply and demand. 20 Notice that this difference in public investor trading behaviors between the two markets does not necessarily imply arbitrage. 21 GPP aggregate the net demand of both public investors and firm investors, and refer to it as the non-market-maker demand. 22 We thank David Bates for sharing the data on this measure. References Adrian, T. , and Boyarchenko N. . 2012 . Intermediary leverage cycles and financial stability . Staff Reports, Federal Reserve Bank of New York . Adrian, T. , Etula E. , and Muir T. . 2014 . Financial intermediaries and the cross-section of asset returns . Journal of Finance 69 : 2557 – 96 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Adrian, T. , Moench E. , and Shin H. S. . 2010 . Financial intermediation, asset prices, and macroeconomic dynamics . Staff Reports, Federal Reserve Bank of New York . Andersen, T. G. , Bollerslev T. , and Diebold F. X. . 2007 . Roughing it up: Including jump components in the measurement, modeling, and forecasting of return volatility . Review of Economics and Statistics 89 : 701 – 20 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Andrews, Donald W. K. 1993 . Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point . Econometrica 61 : 821 – 56 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Ang, A. , and Bekaert G. . 2007 . Stock return predictability: Is it there? Review of Financial Studies 20 : 651 – 707 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bates, D. S. 2006 . Maximum likelihood estimation of latent affine processes . Review of Financial Studies 19 : 909 – 65 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bates, D. S. 2008 . The market for crash risk . Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32 : 2291 – 321 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bekaert, G. , and Hoerova M. . 2014 . The VIX, the variance premium and stock market volatility . Journal of Econometrics 183 : 181 – 92 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bernanke, B. , and Gertler M. . 1989 . Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations . American Economic Review 79 : 14 – 31 . Bernanke, B. S. , Gertler M. , and Gilchrist S. . 1999 . The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework . In Handbook of macroeconomics . Eds. Taylor, J. B. and Woodford, M. vol. 1 , chap. 21 , pp. 1341 – 93 . Amsterdam : Elsevier . Bollen, N. , and Whaley R. . 2004 . Does net buying pressure affect the shape of implied volatility functions? Journal of Finance 59 : 711 – 53 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Bollerslev, T. , Tauchen G. , and Zhou H. . 2009 . Expected stock returns and variance risk premia . Review of Financial Studies 22 : 4463 – 92 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Boudoukh, J. , Michaely R. , Richardson M. , and Roberts M. R. . 2007 . On the importance of measuring payout yield: Implications for empirical asset pricing . Journal of Finance 62 : 877 – 915 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Brunnermeier, M. K. , and Pedersen L. H. . 2009 . Market liquidity and funding liquidity . Review of Financial Studies 22 : 2201 – 38 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Brunnermeier, M. K. , and Sannikov Y. . 2014 . A macroeconomic model with a financial sector . American Economic Review 104 : 379 – 421 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Buraschi, A. , and Jiltsov A. . 2006 . Model uncertainty and option markets with heterogeneous beliefs . Journal of Finance 61 : 2841 – 97 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Carr, P. , and Wu L. . 2009 . Variance risk premiums . Review of Financial Studies 22 : 1311 – 41 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Chen, H. , Joslin S. , and Tran N.-K. . 2012 . Rare disasters and risk sharing with heterogeneous beliefs . Review of Financial Studies 25 : 2189 – 224 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Cochrane, J. H. 1999 . Portfolio advice for a multifactor world . Economic Perspectives Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 23 : 59 – 78 . Cohen, L. , Diether K. B. , and Malloy C. J. . 2007 . Supply and demand shifts in the shorting market . Journal of Finance 62 : 2061 – 96 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Corsi, F. , Pirino D. , and Reno R. . 2010 . Threshold bipower variation and the impact of jumps on volatility forecasting , Journal of Econometrics 159 : 276 – 88 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Jean-Sebastien, Fontaine, and Rene Garcia. 2012 . Bond liquidity premia . Review of Financial Studies 25 : 1207 – 54 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Garleanu, N. , Pedersen L. H. , and Poteshman A. M. . 2009 . Demand-based option pricing . Review of Financial Studies 22 : 4259 – 99 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Geanakoplos, J. 2009 . The leverage cycle . Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers, Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics, Yale University . Gromb, D. , and Vayanos D. . 2002 . Equilibrium and welfare in markets with financially constrained arbitrageurs . Journal of Financial Economics 66 : 361 – 407 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Hansen, P. R. , and Timmermann A. . 2012 . Choice of sample split in out-of-sample forecast evaluation . Working Paper, Stanford University . He, Z. , Kelly B. , and Manela A. . 2017 . Intermediary asset pricing: New evidence from many asset classes . Journal of Financial Economics . Advance Access published August 12, 2017 , https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2017.08.002 . He, Z. , and Krishnamurthy A. . 2013 . Intermediary asset pricing . American Economic Review 103 : 732 – 70 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Hodrick, R. J. 1992 . Dividend yields and expected stock returns: Alternative procedures for inference and measurement . Review of Financial Studies 5 : 357 – 86 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Hu, G. X. , Pan J. , and Wang J. . 2013 . Noise as information for illiquidity . Journal of Finance 68 : 2341 – 82 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Johnson, T. C. , Liang M. , and Liu Y. . 2016 . What drives index options exposure? Review of Finance . Advance Access published November 13, 2016 , https://doi.org/10.1093/rof/rfw061 . Joslin, S. 2017 . Can unspanned stochastic volatility models explain the cross section of bond volatilities? Management Science . Advance Access published April 18, 2017 , https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2016.2623 . Joslin, S. , and Konchitchki Y. . Forthcoming . Interest rate volatility, the yield curve, and the macroeconomy . Journal of Financial Economics . Joslin, S. , Priebsch M. , and Singleton K. J. . 2014 . Risk premiums in dynamic term structure models with unspanned macro risks . Journal of Finance 69 : 1197 – 233 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Kelly, B. , and Jiang H. . 2014 . Editor’s choice tail risk and asset prices . Review of Financial Studies 27 : 2841 – 71 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Kiyotaki, N. , and Moore J. . 1997 . Credit cycles . Journal of Political Economy 105 : 211 – 48 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Lettau, M. , and Ludvigson S. . 2001 . Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A cross-sectional test when risk premia are time-varying . Journal of Political Economy 109 : 1238 – 87 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Longstaff, F. A. , and Wang J. . 2012 . Asset pricing and the credit market , Review of Financial Studies 25 : 3169 – 215 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Lustig, H. , Roussanov N. , and Verdelhan A. . 2011 . Common risk factors in currency markets . Review of Financial Studies 24 : 3731 – 77 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS McCracken, M. W. 2007 . Asymptotics for out of sample tests of Granger causality . Journal of Econometrics 140 : 719 – 52 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Muller, U. K. 2014 . HAC corrections for strongly autocorrelated time series . Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 32 : 311 – 22 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Newey, W. K. , and West K. D. . 1987 . A simple positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix estimator . Econometrica 55 : 703 – 8 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Pan, J. , and Poteshman A. . 2006 . The information in option volume for future stock prices . Review of Financial Studies 19 : 871 – 908 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Rigobon, R. 2003 . Identification through heteroskedasticity . Review of Economics and Statistics 85 : 777 – 92 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Sentana, E. , and Fiorentini G. . 2001 . Identification, estimation and testing of conditionally heteroskedastic factor models . Journal of Econometrics 102 : 143 – 64 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS Welch, I. , and Goyal A. . 2008 . A comprehensive look at the empirical performance of equity premium prediction . Review of Financial Studies 21 : 1455 – 508 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS © The Author(s) 2018. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com. This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic.oup.com/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)

Journal

The Review of Financial StudiesOxford University Press

Published: Jan 1, 2019

There are no references for this article.