TY - JOUR AU - Hou, Kewei AB - Abstract We study the effect of a bond’s place in its issuer’s maturity structure on credit risk. Using a structural model as motivation, we argue that bonds due relatively late in their issuers’ maturity structure have greater credit risk than do bonds due relatively early. Empirically, we find robust evidence that these later bonds have larger yield spreads and greater comovement with equity and that the magnitude of the effects is consistent with model predictions for investment-grade bonds. Our results highlight the importance of bond-specific credit risk for understanding corporate bond prices. Received January 1, 2016; editorial decision June 6, 2017 by Editor Robin Greenwood. One of the central issues in the corporate bond literature is about measuring credit risk and its effects on prices and returns. In this paper, we will focus on understanding the empirical implications of de facto seniority, the idea that bonds due relatively late in their issuers’ maturity structure are effectively junior even if firms do not have explicit seniority structures. Much of the literature since Merton (1974) has tried to understand the levels and dynamics of corporate bond prices with a focus on more realistic modeling of firms (including bankruptcy costs, endogenizing default decisions, interest rate dynamics, and jumps). Our particular focus is on better understanding how there can be heterogeneity in credit risk for bonds based on de facto seniority, with an emphasis on the impact on bond returns and the cross-section of yield spreads. We control for firm-level credit risk, the actual maturity of a corporate bond, and the average maturity of all of the issuer’s corporate bonds, and find that bonds due relatively late in their issuers’ maturity structure have higher yield spreads and higher hedge ratios.1 Thus, we will argue that, in addition to firm-level credit risk, it is important to consider bond-level credit risk based on the place of a bond in its issuer’s maturity structure. The intuition behind our empirical results is that a bond that matures after most of the other bonds issued by the same firm is potentially de facto junior even if all of the firm’s bonds have the same explicit seniority.2 This arises from the fact that a firm in financial trouble may remain solvent long enough to repay bonds due early in its maturity structure, but not bonds due later. The effect is that bond issues that mature later are more sensitive to underlying firm value. We formalize this intuition in an extension of the Merton (1974) model and present both yield spreads and relative hedge ratios in a numerical exercise that shows that, holding the actual maturity constant, bonds due later in their firms’ maturity structure have higher yield spreads and hedge ratios. Empirically, we find that after controlling for various measures of credit risk (including credit ratings), measures of illiquidity, maturity (both of the bond and the average across the issuer’s bonds), and firm fixed effects, bonds due latest in their issuer’s maturity structure have yield spreads that are 48 basis points higher than bonds due earliest in their issuer’s maturity structure. This is larger than an estimated 21-basis-point increase in yield spreads associated with a one-notch deterioration in credit rating.3 The effect is 47 basis points for investment-grade bonds, compared to 85 basis points for junk-rated bonds. Consistent with model predictions, de facto seniority becomes generally more important as credit quality begins to decline. Our results suggest that the market recognizes the effect of a bond’s place in its issuer’s maturity structure when pricing bonds and that credit ratings agencies should consider notching bonds based on de facto seniority in addition to the explicit priority structure.4 We also test how the magnitudes of our empirical estimates match with the predictions of the extended Merton model. Although the model is largely meant to illustrate intuition and motivate the de facto seniority effect, it is nevertheless useful to understand how well the model fits and identify the types of firms that the model is best able to explain. In our tests, we find that the empirically estimated de facto seniority effect in yield spreads is significantly below the model predicted effect for junk-rated bonds. However, for most specifications, we are unable to reject that model and empirical magnitudes are equal for investment-grade firms. Thus, despite the fact that we find a stronger empirical effect for junk-rated firms, the effects are not as large as the model suggests. Our results are consistent with the fact that junk-rated firms have complex capital structures (Rauh and Sufi 2010) that are not fully incorporated in the extended Merton model. Investment-grade firms, in contrast, have much simpler debt structures, so our extension of the Merton model provides a reasonable approximation. In addition to yield spreads, we also consider hedge ratios, the relative returns of corporate bonds and equities. Intuitively, hedge ratios measure how equity-like a corporate bond is, with bonds with greater credit risk behaving in a more equity-like way. Hedge ratios provide not only an alternative setting to test for the de facto seniority effect but one that structural models have performed better on than yield spreads based on previous literature (Schaefer and Strebulaev 2008). Consistent with the predictions of the extended Merton model, we find that de facto junior bonds have larger hedge ratios than do de facto senior bonds. Hence, our results using hedge ratios confirm our yield spreads results. Our paper is primarily related to two strands of literature. Empirically, our paper is related to the literature that tries to evaluate the pricing of corporate bonds through the lens of structural models of default. Huang and Huang (2003) is the seminal paper showing that a large part of credit spreads cannot be explained by common structural models of default.5 Our paper is also related to the theoretical literature on equilibrium maturity choice, particularly Brunnermeier and Oehmke (2013),6 who show that the incentive to shorten the maturity structure in conjunction with an inability to commit to a maturity structure leads to a maturity rat race for financial firms. The outcome of this maturity rat race is inefficiently short-term financing. In this paper, we do not aim to explain why a firm has chosen a particular maturity structure; instead, we take the outcome of maturity choice as given and focus on the empirical effects of a bond’s position in its firm’s maturity structure on its prices and returns. Corporate bond issuers will have both de facto senior and de facto junior bonds regardless of the equilibrium choice to largely issue short-term versus long-term bonds as de facto seniority is defined relative to bonds from the same issuer, not based on the absolute maturity of the bond. Importantly, we note that our results are robust to controlling for the average firm-level maturity (the outcome of the endogenous choices discussed in the aforementioned papers) and also the actual maturity of the bond. 1. De Facto Seniority and Credit Risk As a simple benchmark model, we consider a Merton model in which firm value follows a geometric Brownian motion under the risk-neutral probability measure \begin{align} d\ln V_t = \left(r-\frac{1}{2}\sigma_v^2\right)dt + \sigma_v dW_t^Q. \end{align}(1) The firm has a single zero-coupon bond issue with face value |$K$| and equity is a call option on the firm. The single bond issue is equivalent to a risk-free bond short a put option on the firm. Its value is \begin{align}\label{eq_merton_bond} B &= V\left(1-N(d_1)\right) + Ke^{-rT}N\left(d_2\right)\text{,}\\\notag \text{where } d_1 &= \frac{\ln\left(\frac{V}{K}\right) + \left(r + \frac{1}{2}\sigma_v^2\right)T}{\sigma_v\sqrt{T}}\text{and} d_2 = d_1 - \sigma_v\sqrt{T}\text{.} \end{align}(2) Bond yields can be directly inferred from |$B = K e^{-yT}$|⁠, and the yield spread equals |$y-r$|⁠. In addition to yield spreads, we also consider hedge ratios, the relative returns of corporate bonds and equities. As illustrated by Schaefer and Strebulaev (2008), the relative returns of the bond and equity (the hedge ratio) under the Merton model is \begin{align}\label{eq_merton_hedge} &h_E \equiv \frac{\partial \ln B}{\partial \ln E} = \left(\frac{1}{N(d_1)} - 1\right)\left(\frac{V}{B} -1\right). \end{align}(3) The Merton model formalizes the important insight that corporate bonds and equities are linked through their exposures to the underlying firm value.7 Intuitively, safe corporate bonds will be similar to Treasuries and have low hedge ratios. Corporate bonds with significant credit risk will have higher exposures to underlying firm values and will tend to have larger hedge ratios. We extend the Merton model to analyze how the position of a bond in its issuer’s maturity structure affects its yield spread and hedge ratio. The intuition behind why a bond’s position affects its credit risk is that a firm in financial distress may remain solvent long enough to repay bond issues that mature early. However, the firm is then likely to suffer solvency issues when the bonds due later eventually mature. This creates a de facto seniority effect.8 Our extension of the Merton model includes three zero-coupon bond issues, which have the same explicit seniority, but mature at different times. The three bond issues have face values |$K_i$| and maturities |$T_i$| where |$T_1 < T_2 < T_3$|⁠. At |$T_i$|⁠, a firm remains solvent if |$V_i > K_i$|⁠.9 Otherwise the firm defaults, |$V_i$| is discounted by a proportional bankruptcy cost (⁠|$L$|⁠), and the remaining bond issues share the remaining firm value in proportion to their face values.10|$^,$|11 This model, although a simplification of the complex capital structure typical in large U.S. corporations, allows us to examine the yield spread and hedge ratio, while varying the bond’s position in the firm’s maturity structure. By including three bonds, we are able to focus on the bond with the intermediate maturity, |$T_2$|⁠, and adjust the relative amounts of debt due before and after it.12 This changes the de facto seniority of the intermediate maturity bond, holding all else constant, allowing us to gauge the impact of de facto seniority on yield spreads and hedge ratios. In this extended Merton model, equity remains a call option on the firm, but has intermediate monitoring points at each bond maturity \begin{align} E = E_0^Q\left[e^{-rT_3}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_1 > K_1}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_2>K_2}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_3>K_3}\left(V_3 - K_3\right)\right]\text{.} \end{align}(4) Though there is no closed-form solution for equity value, it can be simplified to a function of normal cumulative distribution functions (CDFs) and integrals by noting that firm value returns are lognormal. Similarly, the value of the bond maturing at |$T_2$| is \begin{align}\label{eq_int_bond} B &= E_0^Q\left[e^{-rT_2}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_1 > K_1}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_2>K_2}K_2\right] + E_0^Q\left[e^{-rT_1}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_1 < K_1}(1-L)V_1\frac{K_2}{K_1+K_2+K_3}\right]\nonumber\\ &\quad + E_0^Q\left[e^{-rT_2}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_1 > K_1}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_2 K_1}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_2>K_2}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_3>K_3}\left(V_3 - K_3\right)\right] \end{align*} The firm value process is lognormal \begin{align} &V_1 = V_0 \exp\left[\left(r-\frac{1}{2}\sigma_v^2\right)T_1 + \sigma_v\sqrt{T_1} w_1\right],\\ \notag & \text{where} w_1 \sim N(0,1). \end{align}(A.1) Similarly, \begin{align*} &V_2 = (V_1-K_1) \exp\left[\left(r-\frac{1}{2}\sigma_v^2\right)(T_2-T_1) + \sigma_v\sqrt{T_2 - T_1} w_2\right]\\\notag & \text{if} V_1 > K_1\\ \notag & \text {and}\\ \notag &V_3 = (V_2-K_2) \exp\left[\left(r-\frac{1}{2}\sigma_v^2\right)(T_3-T_2) + \sigma_v\sqrt{T_3 - T_2} w_3\right]\\\notag & \text{if} V_2 > K_2\text{.} \end{align*} In particular, note that if the firm is solvent at |$T_i$|⁠, then |$K_i$| is paid out of firm value for the maturing bond. After some algebra, it can be shown that \begin{align} E &= \frac{e^{-rT_2}}{2\pi}\int_{-d_2}^{\infty} \int_{-\tilde{d}_2}^{\infty} \exp\left(-\frac{1}{2}z_2^2 - \frac{1}{2}z_1^2\right)(V_2 - K_2)N\left(\tilde{\tilde{d}}_1\right) dz_2 dz_1\\\notag &-K_3\frac{-e^{-rT_3}}{2\pi}\int_{-d_2}^{\infty} \int_{-\tilde{d}_2}^{\infty}\exp\left(-\frac{1}{2}z_2^2 - \frac{1}{2}z_1^2\right)N\left(\tilde{\tilde{d}}_2\right)dz_2 dz_1,\\ \notag & \text{where} \tilde{\tilde{d}}_2 = \frac{\ln\left(\frac{V_2-K_2}{K_3}\right)+\left(r-\frac{1}{2}\sigma_v^2\right)(T_3-T_2)}{\sigma_v\sqrt{T_3 - T_2}}, \tilde{\tilde{d}}_1 = \tilde{\tilde{d}}_2 + \sigma_v\sqrt{T_3 - T_2}\\\notag &\text{and }\tilde{d}_2 = \frac{\ln\left(\frac{V_1-K_1}{K_2}\right)+\left(r-\frac{1}{2}\sigma_v^2\right)(T_2-T_1)}{\sigma_v\sqrt{T_2 - T_1}}. \end{align}(A.2) A.2 Bond Value Our focus is on the intermediate bond with maturity |$T_2$| and face value |$K_2$|⁠. The price of this bond can be written as the sum of three expectations, which correspond to (1) solvency at |$T_2$|⁠, (2) default at |$T_1$|⁠, and (3) default at |$T_2$|⁠. The value of each of these pieces corresponds to |$E_0^Q\left[e^{-rT_2}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_1 > K_1}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_2>K_2}K_2\right]$|⁠; |$E_0^Q\left[e^{-rT_1}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_1 < K_1}(1-L)V_1\frac{K_2}{K_1+K_2+K_3}\right]$|⁠; and |$E_0^Q\left[e^{-rT_2}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_1 > K_1}{\rm 1}\kern-0.24em{\rm I}_{V_2 K_t$|⁠, whereas in the Geske model, equityholders sometimes choose to default even if |$V_t > K_t$| because the pay-in to continue the firm is too high relative to the value of their potential future payoff. Whether decreasing the equity pay-in significantly increases the likelihood of equityholders continuing the firm is unclear as the decreased pay-in comes at the cost of decreasing firm value. To illustrate the point, suppose that a firm has a zero-coupon bond maturing at time |$T_2$| with a face value of 20 and another zero-coupon bond maturing at time |$T_3 = T_2+3$| with a face value of 30. Suppose that the firm value is 45 at |$T_2$| and it only has these two bond issues outstanding. Naturally, at |$\alpha = 1$|⁠, equityholders always continue the firm. If |$\alpha = 0$|⁠, equityholders need to decide whether to pay 20 in exchange for a call option maturing in three years with a strike of 30 and a current underlying asset value of 45. In this case, the value of the call option is 17.25 and equityholders choose to let the firm default. Consider instead |$\alpha = 0.5$|⁠. In this case, equityholders only need to pay |$(1-\alpha)\times20=10$| to continue the firm. However, the other 10 is paid out of firm value, so equityholders are deciding whether to buy a call option with a strike of 30 and an underlying asset value of 35. Despite the decreased pay-in, equityholders still choose to let the firm default because the value of the call option is only worth 8.52 because the option is less in-the-money than before. In Figure A.2, we plot the value of the call option and the cost to equityholders to continue the firm. By definition, between the two extreme cases of |$\alpha = 0$| and |$\alpha = 1$|⁠, there is an |$\alpha \in [0,1]$| where equityholders are indifferent. In this example, this |$\alpha$| is slightly less than 0.8. Figure A.2 Open in new tabDownload slide Dashed line is the amount that equityholders need to pay-in to continue the firm for different levels of |$\alpha$| in the extended Geske model. Solid curve is the value of the call option that equityholders would hold if they choose to continue the firm. In Figures A.3 and A.4, we plot the difference between the yield spreads and hedge ratios of the intermediate maturity bond when most of the firm’s debt is due before the bond and when most of the firm’s debt is due after the bond for different levels of |$\alpha$|⁠, using the same parameters from Section 1. For low values of |$\alpha$|⁠, the difference in yield spreads and hedge ratios between the two scenarios is close to 0. At |$\alpha = 0.8$|⁠, we begin to see some evidence of de facto seniority, as the yield spread and hedge ratio of the intermediate maturity bond when most of the firm’s debt is due before it becomes higher. What drives the relatively high |$\alpha$| needed to generate de facto seniority is that there is typically a wide set of asset values where |$V_i$| is not much larger than |$K_i$| and the continuation value of equity is low. Significant required pay-in by equityholders would result in equityholders choosing default, whereas a zero pay-in (⁠|$\alpha = 1$|⁠) would lead to continuation. Figure A.3 Open in new tabDownload slide Yield spreads for the the extended Geske model. The panels plot differences in yield spreads between bonds due late in a firm’s maturity structure and bonds due early in a firm’s maturity structure. |$\alpha$| represents the proportion of maturing debt that is paid by liquidating firm assets. Figure A.4 Open in new tabDownload slide Hedge Ratios for the the extended Geske model. The panels plot differences in hedge ratios between bonds due late in a firm’s maturity structure and bonds due early in a firm’s maturity structure. |$\alpha$| represents the proportion of maturing debt that is paid by liquidating firm assets. B.3 Leland-Toft Model As a final alternative model, we consider a Leland and Toft (1996) model where equityholders continuously rollover maturing debt. All debt is rolled over at a prespecified (exogenously given) maturity. An exogenously specified fraction |$\delta$| of firm value is paid out to debtholders and equityholders. If the sum of proceeds from newly issued debt and |$\delta V$| is not large enough to cover coupons to debtholders and the face value of maturing debt, equityholders may choose to inject capital to continue the firm. The decision about whether or not to inject capital to continue leads to an endogenously determined default boundary. Compared to the previously explored models in this paper, the Leland-Toft model adds a number of layers of complexity. First, debt is rolled over rather than allowed to mature like in the extended Merton, Geske, and extended Geske models explored earlier. Second, although default is endogenous like in the Geske model, injections of capital do not always occur. In the Geske model, shareholders always pay to retire existing debt. In the Leland-Toft model, shareholder payments only occur if there is a cash shortfall. Third, shareholder injections of cash (when necessary) tend to be small and continuous in the Leland-Toft model, rather than large and discrete like in the Geske model. Fourth, the default boundary is endogenously determined in the Leland-Toft model, in contrast to all of the models previously examined in this paper. While such dynamics are interesting and potentially more realistic, they also complicate the intuition due to the large number of simultaneously moving parts. To implement the Leland and Toft (1996) model, we follow equation (13) in their paper to determine the optimal default boundary. Bond pricing follows from equation (3) of their paper and we also choose the coupon rate so that newly issued debt sells at par (equation (14) in their paper). We choose |$r = 0.03$|⁠, a firm-level payout ratio |$\delta = 0.05$|⁠, |$\alpha=0.5$| (the deadweight loss of bankruptcy) and |$\tau=0.35$| (tax rate). We try a number of asset volatility (⁠|$\sigma_v$|⁠) and book leverage combinations. Our analysis focuses on a comparison of a 5-year bond in two examples. First, we consider a firm where all newly issued debt has a 5-year maturity. In particular, 20% of the firm’s debt is rolled over each year. Next, we consider a firm where all newly issued debt has a 15-year maturity. In the former case, the 5-year bond is due late in its firm’s maturity structure (i.e., is de facto junior) and in the latter, it is due relatively early. In Figure A.5, we plot the yield spreads and hedge ratios of the two scenarios. We find that yield spreads are higher when a bond is de facto junior. Our results on hedge ratios show that for asset volatilities and leverages at levels consistent with typical firms in our sample (asset volatility around 0.2 and leverage around 0.4), bonds that are due relatively late in their firm’s maturity structure have higher hedge ratios. The intuition behind these results is somewhat more complicated than the previous models due to the additional moving parts. Like the extended Merton model, equityholders will tend to continue the firm when possible, making the bonds due early in the maturity structure safer than bonds due later in the maturity structure. However, there is occasionally the need for equityholders to pay-in, making equityholders more likely to default than in the extended Merton model. The intuition is similar to the extended Geske model. Pay-ins are less frequent than the Geske model, but more frequent than the extended Merton model (which has no equity pay-in), making the gap in yield spreads an intermediate case between the Geske and extended Merton cases. Figure A.5 Open in new tabDownload slide Yield spreads and hedge ratios for the Leland and Toft (1996) model. Yield spreads are reported in basis points and hedge ratios in percentage. The cyan surfaces with circular markers represent cases where a bond is due late in its issuer’s maturity structure and the white surfaces with point markers represent cases where a bond is due early in its issuer’s maturity structure. The intuition for hedge ratios in the Leland-Toft model is significantly more complicated. A bond that is due relatively early in its firm’s maturity structure is less sensitive to asset value because it is safer. In particularly, its hedge ratio relative to firm assets, |$\frac{\partial \ln B}{\partial \ln V}$| is lower if it is early in its firm’s maturity structure. However, the sensitivity of equity to firm value also decreases when we move from a firm rolling over 5-year bonds to a firm rolling over 15-year bonds. This arises from the fact that the firm rolling over 15-year bonds chooses a lower default boundary than a firm rolling over 5-year bonds. This causes |$\frac{\partial \ln E}{\partial \ln V}$| to be significantly lower in some cases with higher leverage and for |$\frac{\partial \ln B}{\partial \ln E}$| to be higher for the 5-year bond issued by a firm rolling over 15-year bonds than the 5-year bond issued by a firm rolling over 5-year bonds. The general prediction of the Leland-Toft model is that a bond that is later in its issuer’s maturity structure will tend to have higher yield spreads and higher hedge ratios, though the effect is not as uniform as the extended Merton model predicts. C. Alternative Controls In Sections 3.1 and 3.2, we present empirical results showing that yield spreads and hedge ratios are higher for bonds that are de facto junior. Here, we consider the robustness of our results to alternative control variables. Our primary empirical analysis uses equity volatility and BE/ME as two simple credit controls that are meant to aggregate market information about credit risk. In the results that follow, we replace equity volatility and BE/ME with |$\frac{K}{V}$| and asset volatility (⁠|$\sigma_v$|⁠), two credit variables that are directly motivated by structural models of default. To calculate |$\frac{K}{V}$| and asset volatility, we follow Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008) and calculate them from two equations, \begin{align}\label{eq:call_option} E = V N(d_1) - K e^{-rT} N(d_2) \end{align}(A.4) and \begin{align}\label{eq:mer_eq_vol} \sigma_E = N(d_1)\frac{V}{E}\sigma_v. \end{align}(A.5) Furthermore, we also augment our empirical analysis to allow for a number of nonlinear controls. In addition to controlling for both firm and time fixed effects like in panel B of Table 5, we include ratings fixed effects (rather than numerically coded ratings). We also allow for squared terms for time-to-maturity (T), |$\frac{K}{V}$|⁠, and asset volatility. In Table A.1, we find that the effect of de facto seniority on yield spreads is largely similar to Table 5. Table A.1 Yield spreads with nonlinear controls . Full . IG . Junk . Proportion due prior 0.46 0.39 0.77 [8.16] [9.04] [5.41] T 0.0113 0.0137 0.0111 [4.56] [5.64] [1.30] T|$^2$| –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0001 [–2.31] [–3.03] [–0.71] K/V 1.87 2.22 2.37 [3.07] [3.69] [1.90] (K/V)|$^2$| 3.48 2.28 2.98 [3.35] [1.76] [2.13] Asset vol –0.0020 0.0046 0.0033 [–0.33] [0.78] [0.18] Asset vol|$^2$| 0.0003 0.0002 0.0002 [3.99] [2.40] [0.75] Firm T –0.01 –0.01 0.03 [–1.86] [–1.07] [1.90] Amihud 0.03 0.03 0.03 [3.13] [5.11] [3.02] IRC 0.50 0.46 0.37 [8.55] [7.44] [4.26] Amihud vol 0.02 0.02 0.05 [6.31] [5.57] [5.65] IRC vol –0.02 –0.04 0.17 [–0.70] [–1.52] [2.66] |$R^2$| 0.83 0.78 0.81 Observations 205,822 177,311 28,511 . Full . IG . Junk . Proportion due prior 0.46 0.39 0.77 [8.16] [9.04] [5.41] T 0.0113 0.0137 0.0111 [4.56] [5.64] [1.30] T|$^2$| –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0001 [–2.31] [–3.03] [–0.71] K/V 1.87 2.22 2.37 [3.07] [3.69] [1.90] (K/V)|$^2$| 3.48 2.28 2.98 [3.35] [1.76] [2.13] Asset vol –0.0020 0.0046 0.0033 [–0.33] [0.78] [0.18] Asset vol|$^2$| 0.0003 0.0002 0.0002 [3.99] [2.40] [0.75] Firm T –0.01 –0.01 0.03 [–1.86] [–1.07] [1.90] Amihud 0.03 0.03 0.03 [3.13] [5.11] [3.02] IRC 0.50 0.46 0.37 [8.55] [7.44] [4.26] Amihud vol 0.02 0.02 0.05 [6.31] [5.57] [5.65] IRC vol –0.02 –0.04 0.17 [–0.70] [–1.52] [2.66] |$R^2$| 0.83 0.78 0.81 Observations 205,822 177,311 28,511 The dependent variable in this table is yield spread in percentage. All regressions include three sets of fixed effects: time fixed effects, firm fixed effects, and ratings fixed effects (by notch). Proportion due prior is the proportion of the face value of an issuer’s debt due before a bond, expressed in decimals. T is the time-to-maturity in years. K/V (in decimals) and Asset vol (in percentage) are calculated following Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008). Firm T is the weighted-average time-to-maturity of all of the issuer’s bonds outstanding, weighted by amount outstanding. Amihud, Amihud vol, IRC, and IRC vol are the Amihud measure, the volatility of the Amihud measure, implied round-trip cost, and the volatility of implied round-trip cost, respectively. All four are calculated following Dick-Nielsen, Feldhutter, and Lando (2012), but scaled by 100. t-stats are in brackets and use standard errors two-way clustered by firm and time. Open in new tab Table A.1 Yield spreads with nonlinear controls . Full . IG . Junk . Proportion due prior 0.46 0.39 0.77 [8.16] [9.04] [5.41] T 0.0113 0.0137 0.0111 [4.56] [5.64] [1.30] T|$^2$| –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0001 [–2.31] [–3.03] [–0.71] K/V 1.87 2.22 2.37 [3.07] [3.69] [1.90] (K/V)|$^2$| 3.48 2.28 2.98 [3.35] [1.76] [2.13] Asset vol –0.0020 0.0046 0.0033 [–0.33] [0.78] [0.18] Asset vol|$^2$| 0.0003 0.0002 0.0002 [3.99] [2.40] [0.75] Firm T –0.01 –0.01 0.03 [–1.86] [–1.07] [1.90] Amihud 0.03 0.03 0.03 [3.13] [5.11] [3.02] IRC 0.50 0.46 0.37 [8.55] [7.44] [4.26] Amihud vol 0.02 0.02 0.05 [6.31] [5.57] [5.65] IRC vol –0.02 –0.04 0.17 [–0.70] [–1.52] [2.66] |$R^2$| 0.83 0.78 0.81 Observations 205,822 177,311 28,511 . Full . IG . Junk . Proportion due prior 0.46 0.39 0.77 [8.16] [9.04] [5.41] T 0.0113 0.0137 0.0111 [4.56] [5.64] [1.30] T|$^2$| –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0001 [–2.31] [–3.03] [–0.71] K/V 1.87 2.22 2.37 [3.07] [3.69] [1.90] (K/V)|$^2$| 3.48 2.28 2.98 [3.35] [1.76] [2.13] Asset vol –0.0020 0.0046 0.0033 [–0.33] [0.78] [0.18] Asset vol|$^2$| 0.0003 0.0002 0.0002 [3.99] [2.40] [0.75] Firm T –0.01 –0.01 0.03 [–1.86] [–1.07] [1.90] Amihud 0.03 0.03 0.03 [3.13] [5.11] [3.02] IRC 0.50 0.46 0.37 [8.55] [7.44] [4.26] Amihud vol 0.02 0.02 0.05 [6.31] [5.57] [5.65] IRC vol –0.02 –0.04 0.17 [–0.70] [–1.52] [2.66] |$R^2$| 0.83 0.78 0.81 Observations 205,822 177,311 28,511 The dependent variable in this table is yield spread in percentage. All regressions include three sets of fixed effects: time fixed effects, firm fixed effects, and ratings fixed effects (by notch). Proportion due prior is the proportion of the face value of an issuer’s debt due before a bond, expressed in decimals. T is the time-to-maturity in years. K/V (in decimals) and Asset vol (in percentage) are calculated following Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008). Firm T is the weighted-average time-to-maturity of all of the issuer’s bonds outstanding, weighted by amount outstanding. Amihud, Amihud vol, IRC, and IRC vol are the Amihud measure, the volatility of the Amihud measure, implied round-trip cost, and the volatility of implied round-trip cost, respectively. All four are calculated following Dick-Nielsen, Feldhutter, and Lando (2012), but scaled by 100. t-stats are in brackets and use standard errors two-way clustered by firm and time. Open in new tab We next turn to hedge ratio in Table A.2. To allow for additional variation in hedge ratios, we interact ratings fixed effects with equity returns and also allow for interactions between equity returns and |$T$|⁠, |$T^2$|⁠, asset volatility, asset volatility|$^2$|⁠, |$\frac{K}{V}$|⁠, and |$\left(\frac{K}{V}\right)^2$|⁠. Even with these controls, we continue to find an economically and statistically significant effect of de facto seniority, though the magnitudes are somewhat smaller than in Table 8. Table A.2 Hedge ratios with nonlinear controls . Full . IG . Junk . |$r_E \times \text{Prop due prior}$| 0.0590 0.0556 0.0823 [2.89] [2.39] [4.15] |$r_E \times T$| 0.0034 0.0038 0.0011 [5.00] [4.52] [1.04] |$r_E \times T^2$| –0.0000 –0.0000 –0.0000 [–4.40] [–3.59] [–0.70] |$r_E \times \text{Asset vol}$| 0.0044 0.0045 0.0041 [1.78] [1.65] [1.35] |$r_E \times \text{Asset vol}^2$| –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0001 [–1.88] [–1.72] [–1.57] |$r_E \times \text{K/V}$| 0.1069 0.0571 0.2576 [0.91] [0.53] [2.01] |$r_E \times \text{(K/V)}^2$| –0.0102 0.0554 –0.1484 [–0.12] [0.46] [–1.54] |$r_E \times \text{Firm T}$| 0.0060 0.0045 0.0114 [2.66] [2.13] [2.63] Prop due prior 0.0018 0.0018 0.0011 [1.77] [1.76] [0.71] |$T$| –0.0000 –0.0001 0.0000 [–0.71] [–0.74] [0.46] |$T^2$| 0.0000 0.0000 –0.0000 [0.88] [0.84] [–0.32] Asset vol 0.0003 0.0002 0.0006 [1.24] [0.98] [1.38] Asset vol|$^2$| 0.0000 0.0000 –0.0000 [0.91] [1.21] [–0.39] K/V 0.0210 0.0250 0.0223 [2.33] [2.51] [1.45] (K/V)|$^2$| 0.0037 0.0011 0.0009 [0.36] [0.08] [0.08] Firm T –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0002 [–0.69] [–0.60] [–0.44] |$R^2$| 0.32 0.34 0.28 Observations 238,449 207,067 31,382 . Full . IG . Junk . |$r_E \times \text{Prop due prior}$| 0.0590 0.0556 0.0823 [2.89] [2.39] [4.15] |$r_E \times T$| 0.0034 0.0038 0.0011 [5.00] [4.52] [1.04] |$r_E \times T^2$| –0.0000 –0.0000 –0.0000 [–4.40] [–3.59] [–0.70] |$r_E \times \text{Asset vol}$| 0.0044 0.0045 0.0041 [1.78] [1.65] [1.35] |$r_E \times \text{Asset vol}^2$| –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0001 [–1.88] [–1.72] [–1.57] |$r_E \times \text{K/V}$| 0.1069 0.0571 0.2576 [0.91] [0.53] [2.01] |$r_E \times \text{(K/V)}^2$| –0.0102 0.0554 –0.1484 [–0.12] [0.46] [–1.54] |$r_E \times \text{Firm T}$| 0.0060 0.0045 0.0114 [2.66] [2.13] [2.63] Prop due prior 0.0018 0.0018 0.0011 [1.77] [1.76] [0.71] |$T$| –0.0000 –0.0001 0.0000 [–0.71] [–0.74] [0.46] |$T^2$| 0.0000 0.0000 –0.0000 [0.88] [0.84] [–0.32] Asset vol 0.0003 0.0002 0.0006 [1.24] [0.98] [1.38] Asset vol|$^2$| 0.0000 0.0000 –0.0000 [0.91] [1.21] [–0.39] K/V 0.0210 0.0250 0.0223 [2.33] [2.51] [1.45] (K/V)|$^2$| 0.0037 0.0011 0.0009 [0.36] [0.08] [0.08] Firm T –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0002 [–0.69] [–0.60] [–0.44] |$R^2$| 0.32 0.34 0.28 Observations 238,449 207,067 31,382 The dependent variable in this table is log corporate bond returns in decimals. |$r_E$| is the log equity return of the same issuer as the corporate bond and |$r_T$| is the log Treasury bond return of a Treasury bond with the same maturity as the corporate bond. Both |$r_E$| and |$r_T$| are expressed in decimals. Proportion due prior is the proportion of the face value of an issuer’s debt due before a bond, expressed in decimals. T is the time-to-maturity in years. K/V (in decimals) and Asset vol (in percentage) are calculated following Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008). Firm T is the weighted-average time-to-maturity of all of the issuer’s bonds outstanding, weighted by amount outstanding. All regressions contain firm fixed effects, ratings fixed effects (by notch), firm fixed effects interacted with |$r_E$|⁠, and ratings fixed effects interacted with |$r_E$| and |$r_T$| separately. t-stats are in brackets and use standard errors two-way clustered by firm and time. Open in new tab Table A.2 Hedge ratios with nonlinear controls . Full . IG . Junk . |$r_E \times \text{Prop due prior}$| 0.0590 0.0556 0.0823 [2.89] [2.39] [4.15] |$r_E \times T$| 0.0034 0.0038 0.0011 [5.00] [4.52] [1.04] |$r_E \times T^2$| –0.0000 –0.0000 –0.0000 [–4.40] [–3.59] [–0.70] |$r_E \times \text{Asset vol}$| 0.0044 0.0045 0.0041 [1.78] [1.65] [1.35] |$r_E \times \text{Asset vol}^2$| –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0001 [–1.88] [–1.72] [–1.57] |$r_E \times \text{K/V}$| 0.1069 0.0571 0.2576 [0.91] [0.53] [2.01] |$r_E \times \text{(K/V)}^2$| –0.0102 0.0554 –0.1484 [–0.12] [0.46] [–1.54] |$r_E \times \text{Firm T}$| 0.0060 0.0045 0.0114 [2.66] [2.13] [2.63] Prop due prior 0.0018 0.0018 0.0011 [1.77] [1.76] [0.71] |$T$| –0.0000 –0.0001 0.0000 [–0.71] [–0.74] [0.46] |$T^2$| 0.0000 0.0000 –0.0000 [0.88] [0.84] [–0.32] Asset vol 0.0003 0.0002 0.0006 [1.24] [0.98] [1.38] Asset vol|$^2$| 0.0000 0.0000 –0.0000 [0.91] [1.21] [–0.39] K/V 0.0210 0.0250 0.0223 [2.33] [2.51] [1.45] (K/V)|$^2$| 0.0037 0.0011 0.0009 [0.36] [0.08] [0.08] Firm T –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0002 [–0.69] [–0.60] [–0.44] |$R^2$| 0.32 0.34 0.28 Observations 238,449 207,067 31,382 . Full . IG . Junk . |$r_E \times \text{Prop due prior}$| 0.0590 0.0556 0.0823 [2.89] [2.39] [4.15] |$r_E \times T$| 0.0034 0.0038 0.0011 [5.00] [4.52] [1.04] |$r_E \times T^2$| –0.0000 –0.0000 –0.0000 [–4.40] [–3.59] [–0.70] |$r_E \times \text{Asset vol}$| 0.0044 0.0045 0.0041 [1.78] [1.65] [1.35] |$r_E \times \text{Asset vol}^2$| –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0001 [–1.88] [–1.72] [–1.57] |$r_E \times \text{K/V}$| 0.1069 0.0571 0.2576 [0.91] [0.53] [2.01] |$r_E \times \text{(K/V)}^2$| –0.0102 0.0554 –0.1484 [–0.12] [0.46] [–1.54] |$r_E \times \text{Firm T}$| 0.0060 0.0045 0.0114 [2.66] [2.13] [2.63] Prop due prior 0.0018 0.0018 0.0011 [1.77] [1.76] [0.71] |$T$| –0.0000 –0.0001 0.0000 [–0.71] [–0.74] [0.46] |$T^2$| 0.0000 0.0000 –0.0000 [0.88] [0.84] [–0.32] Asset vol 0.0003 0.0002 0.0006 [1.24] [0.98] [1.38] Asset vol|$^2$| 0.0000 0.0000 –0.0000 [0.91] [1.21] [–0.39] K/V 0.0210 0.0250 0.0223 [2.33] [2.51] [1.45] (K/V)|$^2$| 0.0037 0.0011 0.0009 [0.36] [0.08] [0.08] Firm T –0.0001 –0.0001 –0.0002 [–0.69] [–0.60] [–0.44] |$R^2$| 0.32 0.34 0.28 Observations 238,449 207,067 31,382 The dependent variable in this table is log corporate bond returns in decimals. |$r_E$| is the log equity return of the same issuer as the corporate bond and |$r_T$| is the log Treasury bond return of a Treasury bond with the same maturity as the corporate bond. Both |$r_E$| and |$r_T$| are expressed in decimals. Proportion due prior is the proportion of the face value of an issuer’s debt due before a bond, expressed in decimals. T is the time-to-maturity in years. K/V (in decimals) and Asset vol (in percentage) are calculated following Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008). Firm T is the weighted-average time-to-maturity of all of the issuer’s bonds outstanding, weighted by amount outstanding. All regressions contain firm fixed effects, ratings fixed effects (by notch), firm fixed effects interacted with |$r_E$|⁠, and ratings fixed effects interacted with |$r_E$| and |$r_T$| separately. t-stats are in brackets and use standard errors two-way clustered by firm and time. Open in new tab D. Fitting the Model In Section 1, we examine the implications of the extended Merton model using a case in which 10% of a firm’s debt is due prior (10/10/80) and one where 80% of a firm’s debt is due prior (80/10/10). Here, we extend our numerical calculations to allow for 5%, 20%, 30%, 40%, 50%, 60%, 70%, and 85% of a firm’s debt to be due prior to the intermediate bond in addition to the 10% and 80% cases. For each proportion due prior, our goal is to calculate a surface that determines yield spreads and hedge ratios as a function of a firm’s asset volatility and market leverage. To do this, we perform numerical calculations over 546 grid points for each value of proportion due prior, intersecting asset volatilities that range from 2.5% to 65% and market leverage ranging from 2.5% to 90%. All of the grid points are also checked using simulations to verify accuracy. Once we have 546 grid points, each surface is generated by using Matlab to interpolate grid points. With the surfaces, we are able to calculate yield spreads and hedge ratios for |$(\sigma_v, \text{market leverage}, \text{proportion due prior})$| triplets. For each observation in our empirical sample, we determine its asset volatility using the calculations described in Equations (A.4) and (A.5) and its market leverage as (DLC |$+$| DLTT)/(DLC |$+$| DLTT |$+$| market equity). We then use the closest proportion due prior surface pair to calculate the marginal effect of yield spreads and hedge ratios for an observation, analogous to a numerical derivative. For example, the effect of de facto seniority estimated for a bond with a proportion due prior of 0.35 is estimated using the 30% and 40% proportion due prior grids as \begin{align} \frac{f(\sigma_v,\text{market leverage},0.4) - f(\sigma_v,\text{market leverage},0.3)}{0.4 - 0.3}, \end{align}(A.6) where f(.) is the function for the model yield spread or hedge ratio. Some of the results in this paper were previously reported in a working paper titled “Comovement of Corporate Bonds and Equities.” For helpful comments and discussions, we thank Robin Greenwood (the editor), Manuel Adelino, Geert Bekaert, Markus Brunnermeier, Sergey Chernenko, Alex Edmans, Jean Helwege, Jingzhi Huang, Rainer Jankowitsch, Adam Kolasinski, Martin Oehmke, Jun Pan, Eric Powers, Marco Rossi, Ilya Strebulaev, Rene Stulz, Mathijs van Dijk, Yuhang Xing, Wei Xiong, and Xing Zhou; two anonymous referees; seminar participants at Baruch, BI Norwegian Business School, Boston University, Dimensional Fund Advisors, Drexel, Erasmus, the Federal Reserve Board, INSEAD, Norges Bank Investment Management, North Carolina State, Ohio State, Rutgers, Seoul National, Texas A&M, University of Hong Kong, University of Illinois at Chicago, and University of South Carolina; and conference participants at the EFA Meetings, Inquire UK, and the South Carolina Fixed Income Conference. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Board or its staff. All remaining errors are our own. References Amihud, Y. 2002 . Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-section and time-series effects. Journal of Financial Markets 5 : 31 – 56 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Asness, C., and Frazzini. A. 2013 . The devil in HML’s details. Journal of Portfolio Management 39 : 48 – 68 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Baele, L., Bekaert, G. and Inghelbrecht. K. 2010 . The determinants of stock and bond return comovements. Review of Financial Studies 23 : 2374 – 428 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Baker, M., and Wurgler. J. 2012 . Comovement and predictability relationships between bonds and the cross-section of stocks. Review of Asset Pricing Studies 2 : 57 – 87 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Bao, J., Chen, J. Hou, K. and Lu. L. 2014 . Prices and volatilities in the corporate bond market. Working Paper, Federal Reserve Board, Peking University, and Ohio State . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Bao, J., and Pan. J. 2013 . Bond illiquidity and excess volatility. Review of Financial Studies 26 : 3068 – 103 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Brunnermeier, M. K., and Oehmke. M. 2013 . The maturity rat race. Journal of Finance 68 : 483 – 521 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Cameron, A. C., Gelbach, J. B. and Miller. D. L. 2011 . Robust inference with multiway clustering. Journal of Business & Economics Statistics 29 : 238 – 49 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Campbell, J. Y., Hilscher, J. and Szilagyi. J. 2008 . In search of distress risk. Journal of Finance 63 : 2899 – 939 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Campbell, J. Y., Pflueger, C. and Viciera. L. M. 2013 . Monetary policy drivers of bond and equity risks. Working Paper, Harvard and UBC . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Campbell, J. Y., and Taksler. G. B. 2003 . Equity volatility and corporate bond yields. Journal of Finance 58 : 2321 – 49 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Chava, S., and Roberts. M. R. 2008 . How does financing impact investment? The role of debt covenants. Journal of Finance 63 : 2085 – 121 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Chen, H., Xu, Y. and Yang. J. 2012 . Systematic risk, debt maturity, and the term structure of credit spreads. Working Paper, MIT and Bank of Canada . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Collin-Dufresne, P., Goldstein, R. S. and Martin. S. 2001 . The determinants of credit spread changes. Journal of Finance 56 : 2177 – 207 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Cox, J. C., Ross, S. A. and Rubinstein. M. 1979 . Option pricing: A simplified approach. Journal of Financial Economics 7 : 229 – 63 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Daniel, K., and Titman. S. 1997 . Evidence on the characteristics of cross sectional variation in stock returns. Journal of Finance 52 : 1 – 33 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Dick-Nielsen, J., Feldhutter, P. and Lando. D. 2012 . Corporate bond liquidity before and after the onset of the subprime crisis. Journal of Financial Economics 103 : 471 – 92 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Eisdorfer, A. 2008 . Empirical evidence of risk shifting in financially distressed firms. Journal of Finance 63 : 609 – 37 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Eom, Y. H., Helwege, J. and Huang. J. Z. 2004 . Structural models of corporate bond pricing: An empirical analysis. Review of Financial Studies 17 : 499 – 544 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Fama, E. F., and French. K. R. 1992 . The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance 47 : 427 – 65 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Fama, E. F., and French. K. R. 1993 . Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33 : 3 – 56 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Fama, E. F., and French. K. R. 1995 . Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. Journal of Finance 50 : 131 – 55 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Fama, E. F., and French. K. R. 1996 . Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies. Journal of Finance 51 : 55 – 84 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Feldhutter, P. 2012 . The same bond at different prices: identifying search frictions and selling pressures. Review of Financial Studies 25 : 1155 – 206 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Feldhutter, P., and Schaefer. S. 2015 . The credit spread puzzle in the Merton model – Myth or reality? Working Paper , London Business School . Google Scholar Fons, J., Havlicek, B. Fanger, D. Gates, D. de Bodard, E. and Exton. L. 2007 . Updated summary guidelines for notching bonds, preferred stocks and hybrid securities of corporate issuers. Moody’s Investor Services . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Geske, R. 1977 . The valuation of corporate liabilities as compound options. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 12 : 541 – 52 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Greene, W. H. 2003 . Econometric analysis , 5th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ : Prentice Hall . Google Scholar Google Preview OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat COPAC Guha, R. 2002 . Recovery of face value at default: Theory and empirical evidence. Working Paper , London Business School . Google Scholar Haugen, R. A. 1995 . The new finance – The case against efficient markets . Upper Saddle River, NJ : Prentice-Hall . Google Scholar Google Preview OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat COPAC He, Z., and Milbradt. K. 2014 . Endogenous liquidity and defaultable bonds. Econometrica 82 : 1443 – 508 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat He, Z., and Milbradt. K. 2016 . Dynamic debt maturity. Review of Financial Studies 29 : 2677 – 736 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat He, Z., and Xiong. W. 2012 . Rollover risk and credit risk. Journal of Finance 67 : 391 – 429 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Hotchkiss, E. H., and Ronen. T. 2002 . The informational efficiency of the corporate bond market: An intraday analysis. Review of Financial Studies 15 : 1325 – 54 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Huang, J. Z. 1997 . Default risk, renegotiation, and the valuation of corporate claims. PhD thesis, NYU . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Huang, J. Z., and Huang. M. 2003 . How much of the corporate-treasury yield spread is due to credit risk? Working Paper, Penn State and Stanford . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Huang, J. Z., and Huang. M. 2012 . How much of the corporate-treasury yield spread is due to credit risk? Review of Asset Pricing Studies 2 : 153 – 202 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Kennedy, P. 1998 . A guide to econometrics , 4th ed. Cambridge, MA : MIT Press . Google Scholar Google Preview OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat COPAC Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A. and Vishny. R. W. 1994 . Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk. Journal of Finance 49 : 1541 – 78 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Leland, H. E. 1994 . Corporate debt value, bond covenants, and optimal capital structure. Journal of Finance 49 : 157 – 96 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Leland, H. E., and Toft. K. 1996 . Optimal capital structure, endogenous bankruptcy, and the term structure of credit spreads. Journal of Finance 51 : 987 – 1019 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat MacKinlay, A. C. 1995 . Multifactor models do not explain deviations from the CAPM. Journal of Financial Economics 38 : 3 – 28 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Masulis, R. W., and Korwar. A. N. 1986 . Seasoned equity offerings: An empirical investigation. Journal of Financial Economics 15 : 91 – 118 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Maxwell, W. F., and Rao. R. 2003 . Do spin-offs expropriate wealth from bondholders? Journal of Finance 58 : 2087 – 108 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Maxwell, W. F., and Shenkman. M. R. 2010 . Leveraged financial markets . New York : McGraw-Hill . Google Scholar Google Preview OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat COPAC Maxwell, W. F., and Stephens. C. 2003 . The wealth effects of repurchases on bondholders. Journal of Finance 58 : 895 – 919 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Merton, R. C. 1974 . On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance 29 : 449 – 70 . Google Scholar OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat Powers, E. A., and Tsyplakov. S. 2008 . What is the cost of financial flexibility? Theory and evidence from make-whole call provisions. Financial Management 37 : 485 – 512 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Rauh, J. D., and Sufi. A. 2010 . Capital structure and debt structure. Review of Financial Studies 23 : 4242 – 80 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Schaefer, S. M., and Strebulaev. I. A. 2008 . Structural models of credit risk are useful: Evidence from hedge ratios on corporate bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 90 : 1 – 19 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Shimko, D. C., Tejima, N. and van Deventer. D. R. 1993 . The pricing of risky debt when interest rates are stochastic. Journal of Fixed Income 3 : 58 – 65 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat Footnotes 1 Hedge ratios are the ratio of corporate bond to equity returns. Schaefer and Strebulaev (2008) argue that hedge ratios are a measure of credit risk less confounded by noncredit components, such as illiquidity. 2 A de facto junior bond is not explicitly junior. Although it is straightforward to extend the Merton model to allow for explicitly junior and senior bonds, it is difficult to empirically examine the effect of explicit seniority on corporate bond prices because most corporate bond issues in the United States are senior unsecured. Furthermore, though bank debt is often senior to corporate bonds, firms with significant amounts of corporate bonds outstanding often do not have significant bank debt. Rauh and Sufi (2010) report that more than 50% of the firms in their sample with significant amounts of corporate bonds have less than 10% of their debt in bank debt. Our sample, which is at the bond-month level, is even more extreme, with a median of approximately 2% of debt in bank debt. 3 As another benchmark, consider that Dick-Nielsen, Feldhutter, and Lando (2012) find a 1-4 basis point liquidity effect precrisis and a 5-92 basis point liquidity effect post-crisis for investment-grade bonds. Thus, a 48 basis point effect for a bond’s place in its firm’s maturity structure is economically large. 4 Explicit seniority structure is considered by Moody’s when rating bonds (Fons et al. 2007), but de facto seniority is not. In our sample, a regression of ratings on proportion due prior (our measure of de facto seniority) and firm fixed effects has a within group |$R^2$| of only 0.0001. 5 In a recent paper, Feldhutter and Schaefer (2015) use a long history to estimate default probabilities and find a smaller credit spread puzzle. Another facet of the credit spread puzzle, the difficulty in explaining changes in yield spreads is illustrated by Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein, and Martin (2001). Other relevant papers focused on understanding yield spreads, returns, and their moments include Schaefer and Strebulaev (2008), who focus on hedge ratios and Campbell and Taksler (2003), Campbell and Taksler (2003), and Bao et al. (2014), who focus on yield spreads and volatilities. There is also an extensive literature focusing on the comovement between Treasury bonds and equities. Recent papers include Baele, Bekaert, and Inghelbrecht (2010), Baker and Wurgler (2012), and Campbell, Pflueger, and Viciera (2013). In addition, a line of literature examines bond and equity returns over corporate announcement windows, including Hotchkiss and Ronen (2002), Maxwell and Stephens (2003), and Maxwell and Rao (2003). 6 See also Chen, Xu, and Yang (2012), and He and Milbradt (2016). 7 Stochastic interest rates, an important source of variation in bond prices, are not modeled here as the tie between bonds and equities through interest rates is indirect and less important than the tie through firm value. See Shimko, Tejima, and van Deventer (1993) for an extension of the Merton model to stochastic interest rates and Schaefer and Strebulaev (2008) and Campbell and Taksler (2003) for applications of this model. 8Brunnermeier and Oehmke (2013) use similar intuition in their theoretical analysis to motivate an incentive to shorten maturities, which, in turn, leads to a maturity rat race for financial firms. They posit that nonfinancial firms are better able to commit to a maturity structure and avoid a rat race. 9 If the firm is solvent at |$T_i$|⁠, firm value drops to |$V_i - K_i$| and the firm value process follows a geometric Brownian motion between |$T_i$| and |$T_{i+1}$|⁠. 10 We do not formally model the decision to rollover debt, but the states where |$V_i$| is barely larger than |$K_i$| are the states where the rollover of debt would be particularly expensive, if not impossible. These states are primarily responsible for driving the wedge between bond issues that creates de facto seniority. See He and Xiong (2012) and He and Milbradt (2014) for recent papers that examine the issue of rollover risk. 11 The way that we model default is akin to assuming that all defaults are resolved in bankruptcy courts. We abstract away from complexities such as out-of-court settlements and exchange offers where some bondholders may receive larger recoveries than other bondholders. Firms that decide to try to avoid bankruptcy by making exchange offers have incentives to make these exchange offers to debt that is maturing soon since this is the debt for which they will have to service a significant face value in the near future. To the extent that firms need to make favorable offers to bondholders to convince bondholders to accept exchange offers, this also makes earlier maturing debt de facto senior. 12 Our set-up essentially maps all bonds maturing prior to |$T_2$| into a single bond that matures at |$T_1$| and all bonds maturing after |$T_2$| into a single bond that matures at |$T_3$|⁠. 13 The maturity |$T$|⁠, in the Merton model, is set to 7 years to be in line with typical medium-term bonds. 14 The proportion of debt due prior to the intermediate bond (10% in the first scenario and 80% in the second scenario) thus measures how de facto senior the intermediate bond is in these numerical examples. We will use the same variable to measure the de facto seniority of a bond in our empirical tests. 15 Within the model, this can be thought of as either |$V_1 - K_1 < K_2$|⁠, in which case the repayment of the first bond has already driven firm value below what |$T_2$| debtholders are owed or a case in which |$V_1 - K_1 > K_2$|⁠, but not by that much. In such a case, |$T_2$| debt has a high probability of not being fully paid if firm performance between |$T_1$| and |$T_2$| is poor. 16 Another possibility is that bankruptcy courts treat bonds with different maturities as different classes in the resolution of bankruptcy. Guha (2002) notes that in most Chapter 11 cases, bonds with the same explicit seniority are put in the same class. But to the extent that bonds are occasionally put into different classes by maturity, this could also generate a de facto seniority effect. 17 Bonds where the only provision is a make whole call provision, which constitutes a significant portion of nonfinancial bonds, are kept. Make whole calls involve redemption at the maximum of par and the present value of all future cash flows using a discount rate of a comparable Treasury plus X basis points, where the most common values of X are 20, 25, and 50. Historically, the average AAA yield spread has been greater than 50 basis points, leaving make whole calls with little chance of being in-the-money. Powers and Tsyplakov (2008) show that theoretically, make whole calls have little effect on bond prices. They also find that by 2002-2004, the empirical effect of make whole calls on bond prices is extremely small. 18 Though some corporate bond studies, primarily those on corporate bond illiquidity, retain financial firms, studies on structural models of default typically drop financial firms because leverage has different implications for financial firms. Furthermore, Brunnermeier and Oehmke (2013) argue that financial firms have incentives to enter a maturity rat race and are unable to commit to a maturity structure. Thus, any measure of maturity structure today for a financial firm is unlikely to reflect bondholders’ expectations of future maturity structure. 19 We also apply standard filters for corrected and canceled trades and eliminate obvious errors. 20 We also require trades to be at least 11 business days apart and no more than 31 business days apart to calculate returns as trades that deviate too much from being monthly could be nonrepresentative. For example, if a bond’s consecutive last trades of the month are on the last day of the first month and the first day of the second month, we would be calculating a daily return and scaling up to a monthly return. This may create an outlier. 21 Note that a firm-month can be represented in both the investment-grade subsample and the speculative-grade subsample if it has some bonds with investment-grade ratings and some bonds with speculative-grade ratings. 22 Directly using market equity from CRSP for May 2010 introduces errors if the firm had significant issuance or repurchases between December 2009 and May 2010 that would be reflected in the market equity for May 2010, but not in the book equity for December 2009. 23 In our sample, the correlation between proportion due prior and T is high at 0.73. We run variance inflation factor (VIF) tests following Kennedy (1998), and find VIFs under four for all of our yield spreads specifications, far under the benchmark of 10 at which point multicollinearity may significantly affect statistical inference. 24 We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this test. 25 We include differences in ratings as a control where a positive difference indicates that bond |$j$| has a poorer credit rating. For the vast majority of cases, the difference in ratings is zero. 26 We separately sort the panel by Amihud and IRC and retain only pairs for which both measures are within 20 percentile points. 27 An alternative would be to simply scale realized corporate bond returns by realized equity returns. Such an estimate would be very imprecise as cases of small equity returns relative to large corporate bond returns would create extreme observations. 28 In these hedge ratio regressions, |$r_E \times \text{proportion due prior}$| is highly correlated with both |$r_E$| and |$r_E \times T$|⁠, which raises the issue of multicollinearity. Variance inflation factor tests confirm this potential concern. To diagnose the possibility that our estimates are significantly affected by multicollinearity, we use the fact that multicollinearity has the symptom of producing wide swings in parameter estimates with even small changes in data (Greene 2003). We randomly drop half of our observations and reestimate our main hedge ratio specification in 1,000 simulations. We find that our results are stable, inconsistent with a significant multicollinearity effect. 29 As our focus is on equity hedge ratios, we allow the equity hedge ratio to vary with firm characteristics. Potentially, Treasury hedge ratios can also vary with these same characteristics. As a robustness check, we add |$r_T\times \text{BE/ME}$| and |$r_T \times \text{Equity vol}$| to our specifications. Furthermore, we include |$r_T \times\text{proportion due prior}$|⁠. The coefficient on |$r_E\times\text{proportion due prior}$| is 0.0850 (⁠|$t$|-stat |$=$| 5.13), little changed from our base specifications. The coefficient on |$r_T\times\text{proportion due prior}$| is |$-$|0.1540 (⁠|$t$|-stat = |$-$|3.48), again consistent with the fact that bonds due later in their issuer’s maturity structure are more equity-like and less Treasury-like. The coefficients on |$r_T\times \text{BE/ME}$| and |$r_T \times \text{Equity vol}$| are both negative and statistically significant, consistent with Treasury hedge ratios being lower for firms with greater credit risk. 30 This contrasts our findings for yield spreads where the de facto seniority effect is stronger for the speculative-grade subsample. We investigate this difference in Section 3.3. 31 Further adding |$r_E\times\text{Amihud vol}$| and |$r_E\times\text{IRC vol}$| has little effect on our results. 32 The only other covenants in at least 20% of our sample are cross acceleration, change of control puts (related to consolidation/merger covenants), and sales leaseback (similar to negative pledge covenants in preventing what is economically similar to secured debt). 33 The empirical effect is |$-$|2 basis points with a |$t$|-stat of |$-$|0.08. 34Masulis and Korwar (1986) find that in a sample of 1,406 announcements of stock offerings, 372 offerings are planned exclusively to refund outstanding debt. This suggests that there is a realistic role for equityholders in paying off debt. 35 See also Leland (1994) and Leland and Toft (1996) for models that incorporate equityholders’ decisions on whether or not to service debt. We discuss the Leland-Toft model in more detail in Appendix B.3. 36 The slightly lower yield spreads and hedge ratios for the case in which the bond is relatively late in the maturity structure is attributable to the fact that we model bonds as zero-coupon bonds and the recovery as being in proportion to the face value. Thus, bonds late in the maturity structure receive a slightly disproportionate recovery relative to market values. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies 2017. This work is written by US Government employees and is in the public domain in the US. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies 2017. TI - De Facto Seniority, Credit Risk, and Corporate Bond Prices JF - The Review of Financial Studies DO - 10.1093/rfs/hhx082 DA - 2017-11-01 UR - https://www.deepdyve.com/lp/oxford-university-press/de-facto-seniority-credit-risk-and-corporate-bond-prices-zhLp3x1Hu3 SP - 4038 EP - 4080 VL - 30 IS - 11 DP - DeepDyve ER -