TY - JOUR AU - Vincent,, Nicolas AB - Abstract Macroeconomists traditionally ignore temporary price markdowns (“sales”) under the assumption that they are unrelated to aggregate phenomena. We revisit this view. First, we provide robust evidence from the U.K. and U.S. CPI micro data that the frequency of sales is strongly countercyclical, as much as doubling during the Great Recession. Second, we build a general equilibrium model in which cyclical sales arise endogenously as retailers try to attract bargain hunters. The calibrated model fits well the business cycle co-movement of sales with consumption and hours worked, and the strong substitution between market work and shopping time documented in the time-use literature. The model predicts that after a monetary contraction, the heightened use of discounts by firms amplifies the fall in the aggregate price level, attenuating by a third the one-year response of real consumption. 1. Introduction Price discounts, or “sales,” are an essential feature of retail price behaviour and an important factor for households’ consumption decisions. A typical sale is associated with a large but temporary price drop that returns close to its pre-sale level. In the past decade and a half, macroeconomists have extensively employed detailed weekly and monthly price data for a broad variety of retail goods to study the implications of retail pricing for aggregate price flexibility.1 The prevalent view has emerged that retail price discounts do not play a significant role in inflation and business cycle dynamics, and therefore should be ignored by macroeconomists.2 In this article, we revisit this view by providing new evidence from consumer micro-price data for the U.K. and the U.S. and developing a model that can account for these facts. In the first part of the article, we provide empirical evidence on variations in the incidence of sales over time based on data for the U.K. and the U.S. For the U.K., we use the publicly available micro-data underlying the consumer price index (CPI) constructed by the Office for National Statistics (ONS). The data contain monthly price quotes collected from local retail outlets for a wide range of consumer goods and services over 1996–2013. We find that the frequency of sales in the U.K. is strongly countercyclical: a 1-percentage-point rise in the unemployment rate is associated with a roughly 0.5-percentage-point increase in the fraction of products on sale. For example, during the Great Recession, the fraction of sales more than doubled, from 1.7% to 3.7% of observations for our preferred measure of sales. Unlike the fraction of sales, the average size and duration of sales in the U.K. are mostly acyclical and much less volatile. For the U.S., we use multiple time series constructed from the U.S. CPI micro-data going as far back as 1988 and covering three distinct recessions. The similarities with our results for the U.K. are evident: we again document a very clear positive co-movement between the incidence of sales and unemployment. The strong correlation between the business cycle and the use of temporary discounts by firms is highly robust. First, our conclusions are unaffected when we use alternative empirical specifications to adjust for potential serial correlation in the error term or to account for small sample bias. Second, by exploiting detailed micro data for the U.K., we demonstrate that the correlation is not sensitive to how sales are identified; it applies to both clearance and non-clearance sales; it is common across goods and services, and across regions; and it survives different empirical specifications using multiple controls and alternative macroeconomic indicators. The relationship is also present at a disaggregate level: namely, the frequency of price discounts co-moves negatively with economic activity measures in most CPI categories and in all U.K. regions. We exploit the cross-sectional dimension of the U.K. dataset to gain additional insights into the characteristics of temporary sales. There is little evidence that sales co-vary with unemployment across U.K. regions, a finding that we attribute to the well-documented use of uniform national pricing strategies by large retailers, which account for the bulk of sales in our dataset. Looking across consumption sectors, we find that more durable goods and sectors with more concentrated businesses tend to have more countercyclical sales, in favour of theories in which retailers compete for market share or in which intertemporal demand effects are present. Discounts for goods with smaller mean absolute sizes of price changes or those with more volatile frequencies of price changes tend to be more countercyclical, in accordance with models featuring fixed costs of price adjustment. In the second part of the article, we demonstrate how the cyclical variation in the incidence of sales can significantly impact aggregate price and quantity dynamics at business cycle frequency. To this end, we develop a general equilibrium business cycle model with endogenously cyclical sales. The economy comprises multiple locations. Each location is composed of ex ante identical households and a local shopping mall populated by monopolistically competitive retailers. A retailer is a firm that sells a unit measure of perfectly homogeneous brands of the same variety. Each retailer chooses two different price points: a portion of the brands are sold at the regular price, while the others are discounted. In line with the literature, we assume that regular prices are sticky (Guimaraes and Sheedy, 2011; Kehoe and Midrigan, 2015). The fraction and size of sales, however, are unconstrained. Retailers set prices before households make their decisions. Every household is composed of shoppers, each responsible for purchasing a single variety. The household head is aware of the prices posted by retailers in the location she lives in. In addition, she knows the overall distribution of prices across other locations. Based on this information, she picks a shopper type for each variety: a household member can either be a random shopper, who draws a brand of her assigned variety from a random location; or a bargain hunter, who buys from the local retailer and is more likely to find a discounted brand. Bargain hunters, however, are costly because they spend more time shopping. The household head optimally assigns shopper types according to a cut-off rule: a shopper is designated as bargain hunter if the stochastic shopping cost is below a certain threshold. Even if retailers cannot discriminate between the two types of shoppers, they can use sales to attract bargain hunters and increase their market share. This setup produces two important implications for retailers: (1) the two-price strategy dominates posting a single price and (2) fluctuations in the value of shoppers incentivize variations in the use of sales. We calibrate our model based on the U.S. data and show that it successfully matches salient features of retail discounts and search behaviour highlighted in the literature, including the prevalence of large but temporary sales (“V-shapes”); significant fluctuations in the average fraction of discounts, and only little variation in their average size; the high elasticity of substitution between hours worked and shopping time documented in studies of time-use surveys (Aguiar and Hurst, 2007; Aguiar et al., 2013); a sensitivity of price savings to shopping time that matches evidence from Aguiar et al. (2013); and relative volatilities and correlations between the frequency of sales and aggregate consumption or hours worked that are close to those found in the U.S. data. The model predicts that in response to an unanticipated monetary contraction, the increases in the fractions of sales and bargain hunters lead to a 12-month fall in real consumption that is 34% less than if sales were absent or constant over time. The reason behind this large difference is intuitive: firms use sales to offset some of the rigidity of regular prices. More specifically, we show that the importance of sale prices for aggregate price flexibility comes from the interaction between the retailers’ price discounting and the households’ search for low prices. At the time of the monetary contraction, most regular prices fail to decrease due to constraints on price adjustment, leading to an increase in retail markup. High profit margins make it desirable for retailers to increase their market share. In our model, they do so by raising the fraction of brands on sale. In turn, more aggressive price discounting by retailers increases the return on time spent searching for low prices, leading to a larger number of bargain hunters. The resulting reallocation of consumption toward lower-priced products amplifies the fall of the aggregate price level. We also show that our conclusions are robust to departures from the baseline calibration. We conclude that properly accounting for sales can have important ramifications for our assessment of the cyclical behaviour of aggregate price and real variables. Macroeconomists who calibrate their models using micro- or macro-level price data without properly accounting for the dynamics of sales may be led to underestimate the degree of aggregate price flexibility and overestimate the fluctuations of real variables over the cycle. Our article is closely related to a number of recent studies analysing the importance of price discounts. On the empirical front, Coibion et al. (2015) use a scanner dataset from U.S. grocery stores and provide evidence of consumers switching their spending from high- to low-price retailers during economic slumps. They find that sales for grocery products are acyclical and do not seem to contribute to the effective grocery prices paid by consumers. We exploit additional time series for food and personal care products obtained from the BLS and show that unlike for the majority of products in the BLS basket, the fraction of price discounts for food exhibits a distinct upward trend and only a weak cyclicality around the trend. Since about three quarters of the grocery data in Coibion et al. (2015) come from food products, our findings are consistent with theirs. Our results therefore emphasize that while there are large differences in the degree of cyclicality of sales across products, much of this cyclicality is preserved at the aggregate level. Anderson et al. (2017) analyse micro price data from a U.S. retailer selling general merchandise and groceries. For this specific retailer, they conclude that sales do not respond to identified wholesale and commodity cost shocks or to changes in local unemployment rates. Unlike Anderson et al. (2017), we focus on the unconditional correlation of sales with the business cycle, and we use the BLS dataset that is representative of all U.S. retailers. When Anderson et al. (2017) consider additional evidence from the BLS micro data, they too find substantial countercyclical time variation in sales. They conclude, however, that time variation in sale prices contributes very little to the variance or cyclicality of inflation, or the response of inflation to an identified monetary policy shock. Our point is related but distinct: we argue that the macroeconomic impact of changes in the frequency of sales accrues over the entire duration of the business cycle, and therefore works via its effect on cumulative inflation, i.e., the price level. In addition, we show that expenditure switching between products priced regularly and at a discount can amplify the response of the aggregate price level during recessions, while dampening the response of consumption. The application of the role of price-level dispersion to variation of consumption-weighted price level and consumption spending is akin to the line taken in Coibion et al. (2015). While they focused on consumer switching between high- and low-price-level outlets, we emphasize the consumer switching within outlets, between regular- and sale-price products. The upshot of our work is that the analysis of the full impact of sale prices should not ignore the behaviour of consumption spending associated with temporary discounts. Our work is also closely related to two recent studies that have reached different conclusions. Kehoe and Midrigan (2015), using modified versions of standard sticky-price models, argue that sales are mostly irrelevant for the transmission of monetary shocks, since, due to their temporary nature, they cannot offset persistent aggregate shocks. Guimaraes and Sheedy (2011) reach similar conclusions using a sticky-price model with sales stemming from consumer heterogeneity and incomplete information. In their model, a strong strategic substitutability of sales at the micro level implies that their frequency and size barely respond to monetary shocks. Both models, therefore, predict that the sale margin is not useful for retailers’ price adjustment in response to changes in macroeconomic conditions. Yet, our article shows that introducing a role for price discounts that is compatible with the empirical evidence in an otherwise standard macroeconomic model has quantitatively important implications for its dynamic properties. Finally, there are a few recent studies on the cyclicality of sales for other countries. The closest paper to ours in scope and findings is Sudo et al. (2018), which looks at the behaviour of sales across a wide range of product categories covering around 17% of households’ consumption expenditures in Japan since 1988. The authors find a rise in the frequency of sales in Japan during the 1990s and 2000s at the same time as hours worked were declining and the unemployment rate was rising. This evidence, while dominated by strong trends in all three series during Japan’s “lost decades,” is very much in line with our findings. Berardi et al. (2015), however, find little time variation in sales based on French CPI micro data, a result that may be a reflection of the fact that heavy price discounting is regulated in many EU member states, including France, Belgium, Germany, Greece, Italy, and Spain (Freeman et al., 2008). These regulations may significantly limit the extent to which retailers can adjust their prices in response to economic disturbances and diminish households’ ability to rebalance their spending over the business cycle. The article is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data and basic statistics on sales. Sections 3 and 4 document aggregate and disaggregate evidence on the cyclicality of sales for both the U.S. and U.K. We develop and study the predictions of a general equilibrium model with sales in Sections 5 and 6. Section 7 concludes. 2. Data 2.1. Data sources Throughout the article, we provide evidence from two sources. Most of it is from the CPI micro dataset of the U.K.’s Office for National Statistics. We focus on the U.K. data because they are publicly available, whereas access to CPI micro data in other countries is very limited. We also provide aggregate evidence for the U.S. on the incidence of sales computed for us by the United States’ Bureau of Labor Statistics from their CPI-RDB database.3 We provide below a brief description of the U.K. dataset, while postponing the details to Data Appendix A.1. To construct the CPI, the ONS surveys the prices for goods and services that are included in the household final monetary consumption expenditure component of the U.K. National Accounts. The survey includes prices for more than 1,100 individual goods or services a month, collected locally from more than 14,000 retail stores across the U.K. It excludes the housing portion of consumer prices, such as mortgage interest payments, house depreciation, insurance, and other house purchase fees. Goods and services in the CPI are classified into classes that represent basic group categories, such as “Meat,” “Garments,” or “New Cars”; and each CPI class is divided into finer categories, “items.” For each item and stratum (given by region and shop type pairing in the U.K. data), the ONS dataset provides sampling weights that reflect products’ relative importance in households’ consumption expenditures. These weights exhibit small variation over time due to annual revisions to capture permanent changes in the expenditure composition of households’ consumption baskets. Unless otherwise noted, all weighted statistics are constructed using the CPI consumption expenditure weights. The sample period in the ONS dataset includes 212 months, from February 1996 till September 2013. We make some adjustments to make the dataset suitable for our analysis. First, we delete observations that are not used for CPI construction by the ONS. Second, we deal with product substitutions by splitting the price time series of a given item every time we encounter a substitution flag. The resulting benchmark dataset contains a total of 20.7 million observations across about 2.3 million unique products, covering about 57% of the U.K. CPI basket. For our empirical analysis, we will mostly focus on items that have at least ten price quotes (17.1 million observations). 2.2. Sales filters The first challenge when studying temporary sales in micro price data is to identify them. Ideally, we want to discriminate between price drops that are temporary and drops in regular prices. We use three main ways of identifying sales in our dataset. First, we apply a V-shaped sales filter on the U.K. data, similar to the one used by Nakamura and Steinsson (2008), among many others. In this instance, a “sale episode” begins with a price drop and ends as soon as a price increase is registered, as long as this price increase occurs within three months. Under this definition, we do not require the price at the end of the sale to be at or above the price at the beginning of the sale. Second, for both the U.K. and the U.S., we present results using the “sales flag” available in the respective datasets. The ONS indicates that “sale prices are recorded if they are temporary reductions on goods likely to be available again at normal prices or end-of-season reductions.” Despite the advantage of being made directly available by the statistical agency, there are some issues with the sales flag that require us to make some adjustments. For example, there are a few instances in which the occurrence of a sales flag is accompanied by zero change in the posted price or even, in some rare instances, by a price increase. One possible explanation is that the retailer uses some advertising features to gain or retain customers despite not actually changing the price; another is misreporting or a coding error. In what follows, we adopt a conservative approach and present results based only on sale flags that correspond to price decreases.4 For both the V-shaped and sales-flag filters, the unobserved regular price during a sale is assumed to be equal to the last observed regular price.5 Finally, we compute a reference price similar to the one in Eichenbaum et al. (2011), using a seven-month window. For a given month |$t,$| we set the reference price equal to the modal price observed between |$t-3$| and |$t+3$|⁠, as long as there are at least four price observations within that window. To avoid identifying spurious sales that arise from a lag or a lead in the adjustment of reference prices, we then apply a procedure similar to Kehoe and Midrigan (2015) to ensure that a change in the reference price coincides with an actual price change. A price observation corresponds to a sale price whenever the posted price is below the reference price. 2.3. Basic statistics In Table 1, we report some basic statistics on price dynamics in our dataset. Unless otherwise stated, all moments are weighted using the official CPI weights. The fraction of price changes is 15.8% over the sample period, and the average size of a price change is 11.9% in absolute terms. Price increases are more likely than price decreases (9.8% versus 6.0% of observations, respectively). Not surprisingly, we find lower price change frequencies if we focus on regular prices, i.e., price series that were purged of observations for which the posted price differs from the regular price. The probabilities of observing a price change are 10.9%, 13.2%, and 7.5%, based on the V-shaped, sales flag, and reference price filters, respectively. Hence, the reference price filter generates significantly stickier price series, largely because it filters out both upward and downward temporary price deviations. Overall, our basic statistics show that prices are stickier in the U.K. than in the U.S., but more flexible than in Europe.6 Table 1. Summary statistics for posted and regular price changes . Frequency of . Frequency of . Frequency of . Abs. size of . . price changes . price increases . price decreases . price changes . All prices 15.8% 9.8% 6.0% 11.9% Regular prices V-shaped 10.9% 7.6% 3.3% 8.6% Sales flag 13.2% 8.6% 4.6% 8.5% Reference price 7.5% 5.4% 2.1% 9.4% . Frequency of . Frequency of . Frequency of . Abs. size of . . price changes . price increases . price decreases . price changes . All prices 15.8% 9.8% 6.0% 11.9% Regular prices V-shaped 10.9% 7.6% 3.3% 8.6% Sales flag 13.2% 8.6% 4.6% 8.5% Reference price 7.5% 5.4% 2.1% 9.4% Notes: CPI data are from the U.K. Office for National Statistics; sample period is from February 1996 to September 2013. “V-shaped”, “Sales Flag” and “Ref.” refer to the sales filters described in the main text. Open in new tab Table 1. Summary statistics for posted and regular price changes . Frequency of . Frequency of . Frequency of . Abs. size of . . price changes . price increases . price decreases . price changes . All prices 15.8% 9.8% 6.0% 11.9% Regular prices V-shaped 10.9% 7.6% 3.3% 8.6% Sales flag 13.2% 8.6% 4.6% 8.5% Reference price 7.5% 5.4% 2.1% 9.4% . Frequency of . Frequency of . Frequency of . Abs. size of . . price changes . price increases . price decreases . price changes . All prices 15.8% 9.8% 6.0% 11.9% Regular prices V-shaped 10.9% 7.6% 3.3% 8.6% Sales flag 13.2% 8.6% 4.6% 8.5% Reference price 7.5% 5.4% 2.1% 9.4% Notes: CPI data are from the U.K. Office for National Statistics; sample period is from February 1996 to September 2013. “V-shaped”, “Sales Flag” and “Ref.” refer to the sales filters described in the main text. Open in new tab Table 2 reports several basic statistics for sales. The first row shows that the frequency of sales varies significantly depending on the definition used, from 2.9% for the ONS sales flag to 5.2% for the sales based on the reference price filter.7 Differences are also visible for both the mean and median sale sizes: they are much higher for the sales flag (between 20% and 22%) than the three other filters (between 8% and 14%). Table 2. Summary statistics for temporary sales . V-shaped . Sales flag . Reference price . All sales Frequency 4.6% 2.9% 5.2% Mean size -13.9% -22.0% -12.4% Median size -10.0% -20.0% -8.0% Sales of at least 10% Frequency 2.3% 2.3% 2.3% Mean size -23.6% -25.6% -23.1% Median size -20.1% -21.9% -20.0% Observations 12,002,135 11,928,745 11,943,528 . V-shaped . Sales flag . Reference price . All sales Frequency 4.6% 2.9% 5.2% Mean size -13.9% -22.0% -12.4% Median size -10.0% -20.0% -8.0% Sales of at least 10% Frequency 2.3% 2.3% 2.3% Mean size -23.6% -25.6% -23.1% Median size -20.1% -21.9% -20.0% Observations 12,002,135 11,928,745 11,943,528 Notes: CPI data are from the U.K. Office for National Statistics, sample period is from February 1996 to September 2013. “V-shaped,” “Sales Flag,” and “Ref.” refer to the sales filters described in the main text. Open in new tab Table 2. Summary statistics for temporary sales . V-shaped . Sales flag . Reference price . All sales Frequency 4.6% 2.9% 5.2% Mean size -13.9% -22.0% -12.4% Median size -10.0% -20.0% -8.0% Sales of at least 10% Frequency 2.3% 2.3% 2.3% Mean size -23.6% -25.6% -23.1% Median size -20.1% -21.9% -20.0% Observations 12,002,135 11,928,745 11,943,528 . V-shaped . Sales flag . Reference price . All sales Frequency 4.6% 2.9% 5.2% Mean size -13.9% -22.0% -12.4% Median size -10.0% -20.0% -8.0% Sales of at least 10% Frequency 2.3% 2.3% 2.3% Mean size -23.6% -25.6% -23.1% Median size -20.1% -21.9% -20.0% Observations 12,002,135 11,928,745 11,943,528 Notes: CPI data are from the U.K. Office for National Statistics, sample period is from February 1996 to September 2013. “V-shaped,” “Sales Flag,” and “Ref.” refer to the sales filters described in the main text. Open in new tab To understand why this is the case, we show in Figure 1 the truncated distribution of the size of sales across all observations in our dataset. The discount size in a specific month is given by (the absolute value of) the difference between log sale price and log regular prices in that month. We set the bound of the histogram at 60%, since larger sales are rare. Reassuringly, there are spikes in the distribution at the familiar discount points: 10% off, 20% off, 25% off, 33% off, and 50% off. Second, the three distributions exhibit striking differences between –10% and 0%: the mass closer to zero is significant for the V-shaped and reference price filters, while there are very few small sales according to the ONS indicator. This suggests that the sales filters commonly used in the literature have a tendency to pick up small price drops that are not advertised as sales by retailers. On the other hand, the three distributions are much more similar for sales larger than 10%, a sensible threshold. For this reason, we focus on sales of at least 10% in our analysis. Under this condition, summary statistics is very similar across filters, as can be seen from the bottom portion of Table 2: the frequency of sales is equal to 2.3% for all three, and the size statistics are much more comparable. Figure 1 Open in new tabDownload slide Distribution of the size of sales for the three main filters Notes: Histograms of the size of discounts for the sales flag, V-shaped sales and sales from reference price. Sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Figure 1 Open in new tabDownload slide Distribution of the size of sales for the three main filters Notes: Histograms of the size of discounts for the sales flag, V-shaped sales and sales from reference price. Sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. 3. Aggregate time-series behaviour of sales We now turn our attention to the main objective of our empirical work and study the aggregate behaviour of temporary sales over time. 3.1. Evidence from the U.K. First, we look at the behaviour of the frequency of sales over the 1996:02–2013:09 period in the U.K. For each category and month, we compute the proportion of items with a sale of at least 10% as identified by the V-shaped filter, and then aggregate them using CPI weights. In the left plot of Figure 2, we show the raw constructed series as well as the U.K. unemployment rate for civilians aged 16 and over. Because of the strong seasonal patterns of sales, we also report on the right-hand plot the 12-month moving average centred around each month. Clearly, the fraction of items on sale is far from being constant over time: it is around 2.5% at the beginning of the sample in 1997, then declines to a trough of about 1.6% in 2006 before rising back to about 3.7% by 2011. Also, it is strongly countercyclical: the fraction of sales moves very closely with the unemployment rate, rising as the economy is slowing down. Neither series seems to exhibit a time trend that may bias our conclusions; we formally control for this potential issue in our regression analysis. Figure 2 Open in new tabDownload slide Frequency of V-shaped sales (raw and 12-month moving average) and unemployment rate Notes: Monthly proportion of products at discounted price based on the V-shape filter. Aggregation is done using CPI quote weights. Sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Figure 2 Open in new tabDownload slide Frequency of V-shaped sales (raw and 12-month moving average) and unemployment rate Notes: Monthly proportion of products at discounted price based on the V-shape filter. Aggregation is done using CPI quote weights. Sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Figure 3 compares the evidence from the V-shaped sales filter to that of the sales flag and reference-price filters described earlier. First, the top-right panel demonstrates that the cyclicality of aggregate sales frequency is not due to larger weights on sales-heavy items during recessions: using time-invariant CPI weights makes no noticeable difference. Second, overall patterns are very similar across sales filters: all give rise to a highly cyclical sales frequency. Figure 3 Open in new tabDownload slide The evolution of the frequency of sales (alternative filters) Notes: Monthly proportion of products on sale using the three types of filters. Aggregation is done using CPI quote weights. For the top-right plots, the product-level weights are time invariant and correspond to their time-series average. Sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Figure 3 Open in new tabDownload slide The evolution of the frequency of sales (alternative filters) Notes: Monthly proportion of products on sale using the three types of filters. Aggregation is done using CPI quote weights. For the top-right plots, the product-level weights are time invariant and correspond to their time-series average. Sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Conceivably, retailers could use different sales-related margins in response to aggregate shocks. First, the cyclicality of the fraction of products on sale could be driven by fluctuations in the incidence of new sales and by changes in the average length of existing sales over time. We find no evidence of the latter in the data: the average duration of sale spells remained very stable around 1.6 months over our sample period, with no discernible cyclicality or trend.8 Second, retailers could vary the size of price discounts over the business cycle. Figure 4 shows the evolution over our sample period of the average absolute size of sales, conditioning on sales of at least 10%. Under the three definitions, there is a noticeable increase in the absolute size of sales over the sample period. Nonetheless, in relative terms, the variation is largely contained, unlike fluctuations in the frequency of sales. For example, using the V-shaped filter, we find that the average size of sales fluctuates between roughly 22% and 25%. But most importantly, there is no clear cyclical pattern for this margin of adjustment: at the height of the Great Recession, sales tended to become a little smaller based on the sales flag filter, but slightly larger according to the other two definitions.9 Figure 4 Open in new tabDownload slide The evolution of the size of sales Notes: Weighted average of the size of discounts using the three types of filters. Aggregation is done using CPI quote weights. Data are monthly and the sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Figure 4 Open in new tabDownload slide The evolution of the size of sales Notes: Weighted average of the size of discounts using the three types of filters. Aggregation is done using CPI quote weights. Data are monthly and the sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. 3.2. Evidence from the U.S. We next ask whether the strong countercyclicality of sales is also present in the U.S. We have obtained evidence from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics CPI micro data via three sources. First, the BLS provided us with the monthly fraction of items with a sales flag from January 2000 to May 2014, unweighted and weighted using the CPI expenditure weights used by BLS.10 The weighted time series, smoothed out using a 12-month centred moving average, is presented in the top left-hand plot of Figure 5, alongside the U.S. civilian unemployment rate over the same period. The similarities with our results for the U.K. are striking: there is a very clear positive co-movement between the incidence of sales and unemployment, with a correlation coefficient of 0.88. The turning points in the two series coincide very closely, with two clear spikes in the frequency of sales in the midst of the 2001 and 2008–09 recessions. Figure 5 Open in new tabDownload slide Frequency of sales in the U.S. CPI data and unemployment rate Notes: Data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Vavra (2014) and Anderson et al. (2017). All sales frequency series are 12-month moving averages. Monthly weighted fraction of products with a sales flag (top left) and sales flag or substitution (top right), using BLS expenditure weights. Series in bottom plots: “BLS weights, Sales flag” (green line) is constructed by taking the weighted mean of the frequency of the sales flag and using the weights from the BLS; “Fixed weights” (blue line) is constructed using fixed category-level weights, with alternative definition of sales, and restricting their sample; “BLS weights” (red line) provides an intermediate case with variable BLS weights and Anderson et al.’s sales measure. Series in the bottom-right plot are HP filtered. Sample periods are 2000:01–2011:12 (top left), 1988:01–2011:12 (top right), 1988:07–2014:11 (bottom). Figure 5 Open in new tabDownload slide Frequency of sales in the U.S. CPI data and unemployment rate Notes: Data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Vavra (2014) and Anderson et al. (2017). All sales frequency series are 12-month moving averages. Monthly weighted fraction of products with a sales flag (top left) and sales flag or substitution (top right), using BLS expenditure weights. Series in bottom plots: “BLS weights, Sales flag” (green line) is constructed by taking the weighted mean of the frequency of the sales flag and using the weights from the BLS; “Fixed weights” (blue line) is constructed using fixed category-level weights, with alternative definition of sales, and restricting their sample; “BLS weights” (red line) provides an intermediate case with variable BLS weights and Anderson et al.’s sales measure. Series in the bottom-right plot are HP filtered. Sample periods are 2000:01–2011:12 (top left), 1988:01–2011:12 (top right), 1988:07–2014:11 (bottom). Second, the top right-hand plot in Figure 5 depicts a series derived from Vavra (2014). For his analysis, Vavra filtered out both temporary sales and product substitutions to focus on regular prices.11 Despite the fact that the series is somewhat more volatile, possibly due to the behaviour of substitutions, the results visually appear to confirm our findings based on the data provided directly by the BLS. Moreover, Vavra’s series spans an additional 12 years of data, from 1988 to 1999, showing a clear rise in the fraction of sales and substitutions during the 1990–91 recession, similar to those in two subsequent downturns. Third, the bottom-left plot in Figure 5 replicates the series from Figure A2 in the Appendix for Anderson et al. (2017) (hereafter, AMNSS).12 The underlying micro data are also taken from the BLS CPI database, and the series span the period 1988–2014. The figure compares three alternative measures of the aggregate frequency of sales. The series closest to ours is constructed by taking the weighted mean of the frequency of the sales flag, using the weights from the BLS (“BLS weights, Sales flag”). The series used by AMNSS is constructed using fixed category-level weights, using a refined definition of sales, and by dropping observations that are out-of-season, do not have a lagged regular price, or have a discount that is larger than an 80% (“Fixed weights”). The third line provides an intermediate case with variable BLS weights and AMNSS’ preferred sales measure (“BLS weights”).13 While some of the time series exhibit a pronounced upward trend, the countercyclical pattern is shared by all: for every series, the frequency of sales rises in the wake of recessions and falls during recoveries. The only exception is the fixed-weights series, which seems to “miss” the recovery following the recession in the early 1990s.14 This pattern is confirmed if we focus on the cyclical component of the time series: the last plot (bottom right) of Figure 5 depicts the sames sales and unemployment series from AMNSS once they have been detrended using a Hodrick–Prescott filter with the smoothing parameter set at 129,600. All BLS series unequivocally point toward a strong countercyclicality of price discounts. Nonetheless, AMNSS conclude that time variation in sale prices contributes very little to the variance or cyclicality of inflation, or its response to an identified monetary policy shock. This may be explained by the fact that inflation fluctuations over this period are quite transient, while sales exhibit business-cycle-like persistence. Hence, the macroeconomic impact of changes in the frequency of sales accrues over the entire duration of the business cycle, and therefore works via its effect on the cumulative inflation, i.e., the price level. Our subsequent analysis using a quantitative general equilibrium model with sales in Sections 5 and 6 confirms this intuition. In addition, we show in Section 6.3 that expenditure switching between products priced regularly and at a discount can amplify the response of prices to recessions while dampening the response of consumption, a margin not accounted for by standard CPI indices. Our application is related to the work of Coibion et al. (2015), henceforth CGH. They use the Symphony IRI scanner dataset, which covers multiple grocery stores in 50 U.S. metropolitan areas over the 2001–11 sample period. CGH find that the relationship between unemployment and the frequency of sales becomes small or non-significant once they include a linear time trend or time fixed effects in their panel regressions. Instead, CGH document substantial consumer switching from high- to low-price-level outlets during region-specific slumps, amplifying the decline of the consumption-weighted price level. We reconcile our findings by observing that the U.S. grocery products studied by CGH display a different behaviour than most consumption products. We obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics the frequency of sales for food from the CPI micro data, both weighted and unweighted. Figure 6 demonstrates that the behaviour of sales frequency for food products is indeed markedly different from that at the economy-wide level that we documented in Figure 2. For both groups—all products in the BLS sample and only food—the frequency of sales exhibits rapid increases in the wake of the 2001 and 2008–09 recessions. However, as the U.S. unemployment rate declines in the middle of the 2000s, sales become less prevalent at the aggregate level, while the weighted (unweighted) sales frequency for food products is instead rising (flat). Hence, the cyclical fluctuations in the time series for sales in the food category are difficult to distinguish from an upward trend. Indeed, we show in Data Appendix A.2 that controlling for a linear time trend in the regression of sales frequency on unemployment, as it is done in CGH, yields only a weak relationship for food products, but does not alter the strong positive correlation at the aggregate level.15 Figure 6 Open in new tabDownload slide Frequency of sales for food products, U.S. CPI Notes: Monthly proportion of products with a sales flag. For the plots in the left column, aggregation is done using CPI quote weights. Sample period is 2000:01–2011:12. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics data. Figure 6 Open in new tabDownload slide Frequency of sales for food products, U.S. CPI Notes: Monthly proportion of products with a sales flag. For the plots in the left column, aggregation is done using CPI quote weights. Sample period is 2000:01–2011:12. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics data. In all, CGH focused on consumer switching between high- and low-price-level outlets, while we emphasize the consumer switching within outlets, between regular- and sale-price products. The upshot from both studies is that the analysis of the full impact of sale prices should not ignore the behaviour of consumption spending associated with sales. 3.3. Regression analysis and robustness In the previous two sections, we have shown that for both the U.K. and the U.S., and at least since the late 1980s, sales exhibit a clear countercyclical pattern. Next, we turn to a regression analysis to verify that this graphical evidence is statistically significant and robust. As a starting point, we run OLS time-series regressions for the U.K. (all three sales filters) and the U.S. (BLS, Vavra, and AMNSS) data, using the following empirical specification: |$\gamma_{t}=\alpha+\beta u_{t}+X_{t}^{'}\varPhi+error$|⁠, where |$\gamma_{t}$| is the fraction of sales in month |$t$|⁠, |$u_{t}$| is an aggregate business cycle indicator, usually the unemployment rate, and |$X_{t}$| is a set of controls, which includes calendar month dummies and also a linear time trend or a lagged sales frequency. For every regression involving sales in Table 3, the coefficient on the unemployment rate is statistically significant at the 1% level, even if we include a time trend or one lag of the dependent variable. The elasticity of the frequency of sales to fluctuations in the unemployment rate is higher in the U.K. than in the U.S., varying between 0.358 and 0.544, depending on the measure of mean sales frequency and whether or not the trend is included (Panel A in Table 3). These effects are economically large: for example, a 5-percentage-point (ppt) increase in the unemployment rate is associated with a 2.7-ppt higher probability of observing a V-shaped sale, which is more than double the unconditional sales frequency of 2.3%. When we use the median instead of mean sales frequency across sectors (last two columns of Panel A), conclusions are unaffected: the coefficients are lower but so are the unconditional frequencies, at about 1.5%. Table 3. Regressions at the aggregate level Panel A . U.K. . . . V-shaped . V-shaped . V-shaped . . Flag . Ref. . . . V-shaped - median . Flag - median . . |$u_{t}$| 0.544*** 0.194*** 0.464*** 0.358*** 0.424*** 0.267*** 0.328*** (0.024) (0.036) (0.023) (0.025) (0.024) (0.028) (0.029) |$sales_{t-1}$| 0.647*** (0.055) Linear time trend N N Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 209 210 210 210 210 210 |$R^{2}$| 0.73 0.84 0.80 0.67 0.77 0.62 0.50 Panel B U.S.—BLS U.S.—Vavra (2014) Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Median |$u_{t}$| 0.177*** 0.152*** 0.233*** 0.338*** 0.320*** 0.440*** (0.017) (0.023) (0.025) (0.032) (0.033) (0.060) |$sales_{t-1}$| 0.148 (0.092) Linear time trend N N Y N Y Y Observations 144 143 144 288 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.51 0.52 0.54 0.54 0.55 0.32 Panel C U.S.—Anderson et al. (2017) Fixed weights BLS weights BLS weights, sales flag |$u_{t}$| 0.151*** 0.035** 0.177*** 0.067*** 0.073*** 0.171*** 0.219*** 0.152*** 0.166*** (0.021) (0.013) (0.017) (0.013) (0.014) (0.020) (0.016) (0.014) (0.023) Linear time trend N Y N N Y N N Y N HP-detrended N N Y N N Y N N Y Observations 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 |$R^{2}$| 0.29 0.75 0.68 0.42 0.43 0.61 0.54 0.71 0.57 Panel A . U.K. . . . V-shaped . V-shaped . V-shaped . . Flag . Ref. . . . V-shaped - median . Flag - median . . |$u_{t}$| 0.544*** 0.194*** 0.464*** 0.358*** 0.424*** 0.267*** 0.328*** (0.024) (0.036) (0.023) (0.025) (0.024) (0.028) (0.029) |$sales_{t-1}$| 0.647*** (0.055) Linear time trend N N Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 209 210 210 210 210 210 |$R^{2}$| 0.73 0.84 0.80 0.67 0.77 0.62 0.50 Panel B U.S.—BLS U.S.—Vavra (2014) Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Median |$u_{t}$| 0.177*** 0.152*** 0.233*** 0.338*** 0.320*** 0.440*** (0.017) (0.023) (0.025) (0.032) (0.033) (0.060) |$sales_{t-1}$| 0.148 (0.092) Linear time trend N N Y N Y Y Observations 144 143 144 288 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.51 0.52 0.54 0.54 0.55 0.32 Panel C U.S.—Anderson et al. (2017) Fixed weights BLS weights BLS weights, sales flag |$u_{t}$| 0.151*** 0.035** 0.177*** 0.067*** 0.073*** 0.171*** 0.219*** 0.152*** 0.166*** (0.021) (0.013) (0.017) (0.013) (0.014) (0.020) (0.016) (0.014) (0.023) Linear time trend N Y N N Y N N Y N HP-detrended N N Y N N Y N N Y Observations 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 |$R^{2}$| 0.29 0.75 0.68 0.42 0.43 0.61 0.54 0.71 0.57 Notes: Linear regressions of the fraction of products on sale on the unemployment rate (⁠|$u_{t}$|⁠). “Flag,” “V-shaped,” and “Ref.” refer to the sales filters described in the main text. “Mean” and “Median” indicate mean and median frequencies, respectively. “HP-detrended” indicates that a Hodrick-Prescott filter has been applied to both the sales frequency and unemployment series beforehand. All regressions include calendar month dummies. *** p <; 0.01, ** p <; 0.05, * p <; 0.1. The sample periods are February 1996 to September 2013 for the U.K.; January 2000 to December 2011 for “U.S.—BLS”; January 1988 to December 2011 for “U.S.—Vavra (2014)”; and July 1988 to November 2014 for “U.S.—Anderson et al. (2017).” Open in new tab Table 3. Regressions at the aggregate level Panel A . U.K. . . . V-shaped . V-shaped . V-shaped . . Flag . Ref. . . . V-shaped - median . Flag - median . . |$u_{t}$| 0.544*** 0.194*** 0.464*** 0.358*** 0.424*** 0.267*** 0.328*** (0.024) (0.036) (0.023) (0.025) (0.024) (0.028) (0.029) |$sales_{t-1}$| 0.647*** (0.055) Linear time trend N N Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 209 210 210 210 210 210 |$R^{2}$| 0.73 0.84 0.80 0.67 0.77 0.62 0.50 Panel B U.S.—BLS U.S.—Vavra (2014) Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Median |$u_{t}$| 0.177*** 0.152*** 0.233*** 0.338*** 0.320*** 0.440*** (0.017) (0.023) (0.025) (0.032) (0.033) (0.060) |$sales_{t-1}$| 0.148 (0.092) Linear time trend N N Y N Y Y Observations 144 143 144 288 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.51 0.52 0.54 0.54 0.55 0.32 Panel C U.S.—Anderson et al. (2017) Fixed weights BLS weights BLS weights, sales flag |$u_{t}$| 0.151*** 0.035** 0.177*** 0.067*** 0.073*** 0.171*** 0.219*** 0.152*** 0.166*** (0.021) (0.013) (0.017) (0.013) (0.014) (0.020) (0.016) (0.014) (0.023) Linear time trend N Y N N Y N N Y N HP-detrended N N Y N N Y N N Y Observations 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 |$R^{2}$| 0.29 0.75 0.68 0.42 0.43 0.61 0.54 0.71 0.57 Panel A . U.K. . . . V-shaped . V-shaped . V-shaped . . Flag . Ref. . . . V-shaped - median . Flag - median . . |$u_{t}$| 0.544*** 0.194*** 0.464*** 0.358*** 0.424*** 0.267*** 0.328*** (0.024) (0.036) (0.023) (0.025) (0.024) (0.028) (0.029) |$sales_{t-1}$| 0.647*** (0.055) Linear time trend N N Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 209 210 210 210 210 210 |$R^{2}$| 0.73 0.84 0.80 0.67 0.77 0.62 0.50 Panel B U.S.—BLS U.S.—Vavra (2014) Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Median |$u_{t}$| 0.177*** 0.152*** 0.233*** 0.338*** 0.320*** 0.440*** (0.017) (0.023) (0.025) (0.032) (0.033) (0.060) |$sales_{t-1}$| 0.148 (0.092) Linear time trend N N Y N Y Y Observations 144 143 144 288 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.51 0.52 0.54 0.54 0.55 0.32 Panel C U.S.—Anderson et al. (2017) Fixed weights BLS weights BLS weights, sales flag |$u_{t}$| 0.151*** 0.035** 0.177*** 0.067*** 0.073*** 0.171*** 0.219*** 0.152*** 0.166*** (0.021) (0.013) (0.017) (0.013) (0.014) (0.020) (0.016) (0.014) (0.023) Linear time trend N Y N N Y N N Y N HP-detrended N N Y N N Y N N Y Observations 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 317 |$R^{2}$| 0.29 0.75 0.68 0.42 0.43 0.61 0.54 0.71 0.57 Notes: Linear regressions of the fraction of products on sale on the unemployment rate (⁠|$u_{t}$|⁠). “Flag,” “V-shaped,” and “Ref.” refer to the sales filters described in the main text. “Mean” and “Median” indicate mean and median frequencies, respectively. “HP-detrended” indicates that a Hodrick-Prescott filter has been applied to both the sales frequency and unemployment series beforehand. All regressions include calendar month dummies. *** p <; 0.01, ** p <; 0.05, * p <; 0.1. The sample periods are February 1996 to September 2013 for the U.K.; January 2000 to December 2011 for “U.S.—BLS”; January 1988 to December 2011 for “U.S.—Vavra (2014)”; and July 1988 to November 2014 for “U.S.—Anderson et al. (2017).” Open in new tab For the U.S., this elasticity in the regression without the trend is 0.177 in our sample, and equal to 0.067, 0.151, and 0.219 for the AMNSS series (Panels B and C in Table 3). The elasticities are somewhat higher for the Vavra series, possibly reflecting a cyclical pattern in product substitutions. Including a linear time trend in the set of regression controls increases the estimated elasticity in our sample to 0.233, but reduces it in AMNSS’ longer sample to 0.035, 0.073, and 0.152. Given the high persistence of both the sales frequency and unemployment series, it is worth verifying the robustness of our results using alternative detrending methods. Panel C in Table 3 provides the results for the series detrended with the Hodrick-Prescott filter. The resulting elasticities are not only higher but also much more similar in magnitude: 0.177, 0.171, and 0.166. In Data Appendix A.3, we also document the countercyclicality of sales frequency using other business cycle indicators, such as hours worked and real consumption expenditures. Since the sales and unemployment series are quite persistent and the sample periods include a limited number of complete business cycles, we compute alternative standard errors that are robust to potential misspecifications of the base OLS empirical model. In addition to robust, Cochrane-Orcutt, and Newey-West standard errors, we conduct a non-parametric bootstrap exercise to correct for any potential small sample bias in addition to serial correlation of the residuals. In Data Appendix A.4, we provide details of the implementation of the bootstrap procedure and report the alternative standard errors alongside the point estimates and OLS standard errors that were provided in Table 3. All alternative specifications yield highly significant results, except for one case with statistical significance at the 10% level. We complete the aggregate analysis by investigating regular price changes. First, we explore whether the frequency of sales correlates with the frequency of changes in regular prices: retailers may use sales in conjunction with other margins of price adjustments, for example, to offset customers’ response to longer-lived regular price increases. The results in Table 4 indicate that the coefficient on the unemployment rate remains mostly unaffected by the inclusion of the frequency of regular price changes.16 Only for Vavra’s U.S. time series do we find a significant relationship between the frequencies of regular price changes and sales, beyond the impact of the unemployment rate. Nonetheless, this does not alter our finding about the cyclicality of sales, and the coefficients on the unemployment rate are even larger in this case than the coefficients reported in Table 3. Table 4. Sales and regular price changes . Dependent variable: frequency of sales . . U.K. . . U.S.—BLS . . U.S.—Vavra (2014) . . V-shaped . V-shaped . Flag . . Mean . . Mean . Median . |$u_{t}$| 0.459*** 0.457*** 0.363*** 0.208*** 0.357*** 0.529*** (0.033) (0.032) (0.041) (0.033) (0.045) (0.060) |$freg_{t}$| 0.008 -0.008 -0.11*** -0.458*** (0.008) (0.006) (0.042) (0.059) |$freg\_pos_{t}$| 0.004 -0.062* (0.008) (0.032) |$freg\_neg_{t}$| 0.033 -0.029 (0.022) (0.037) Linear time trend Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 210 210 144 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.81 0.81 0.67 0.63 0.57 0.46 Dependent variable: frequency of regular price changes U.K. U.S.—BLS U.S.—Vavra (2014) V-shaped Flag Ref. price Mean Mean Median |$u_{t}$| 0.602*** 0.536 0.305*** 0.160 0.335*** 0.195** (0.212) (0.365) (0.084) (0.219) (0.089) (0.078) Linear time trend Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 210 210 144 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.32 0.19 0.38 0.61 0.57 0.46 . Dependent variable: frequency of sales . . U.K. . . U.S.—BLS . . U.S.—Vavra (2014) . . V-shaped . V-shaped . Flag . . Mean . . Mean . Median . |$u_{t}$| 0.459*** 0.457*** 0.363*** 0.208*** 0.357*** 0.529*** (0.033) (0.032) (0.041) (0.033) (0.045) (0.060) |$freg_{t}$| 0.008 -0.008 -0.11*** -0.458*** (0.008) (0.006) (0.042) (0.059) |$freg\_pos_{t}$| 0.004 -0.062* (0.008) (0.032) |$freg\_neg_{t}$| 0.033 -0.029 (0.022) (0.037) Linear time trend Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 210 210 144 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.81 0.81 0.67 0.63 0.57 0.46 Dependent variable: frequency of regular price changes U.K. U.S.—BLS U.S.—Vavra (2014) V-shaped Flag Ref. price Mean Mean Median |$u_{t}$| 0.602*** 0.536 0.305*** 0.160 0.335*** 0.195** (0.212) (0.365) (0.084) (0.219) (0.089) (0.078) Linear time trend Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 210 210 144 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.32 0.19 0.38 0.61 0.57 0.46 Notes: Linear regressions of the fraction of products on sale on the unemployment rate (⁠|$u_{t}$|⁠) as well as the frequency of regular price changes (⁠|$freg_{t}$|⁠), increases (⁠|$freg\_pos_{t}$|⁠), and decreases (⁠|$freg\_neg_{t}$|⁠). “Mean” and “Median” indicate mean and median frequencies respectively. All regressions include calendar month dummies. Newey-West standard errors allowing for a maximum autocorrelation of four lags are indicated in parentheses. *** p <; 0.01, ** p <; 0.05, * p <; 0.1. Sample periods are described in Table 3. Open in new tab Table 4. Sales and regular price changes . Dependent variable: frequency of sales . . U.K. . . U.S.—BLS . . U.S.—Vavra (2014) . . V-shaped . V-shaped . Flag . . Mean . . Mean . Median . |$u_{t}$| 0.459*** 0.457*** 0.363*** 0.208*** 0.357*** 0.529*** (0.033) (0.032) (0.041) (0.033) (0.045) (0.060) |$freg_{t}$| 0.008 -0.008 -0.11*** -0.458*** (0.008) (0.006) (0.042) (0.059) |$freg\_pos_{t}$| 0.004 -0.062* (0.008) (0.032) |$freg\_neg_{t}$| 0.033 -0.029 (0.022) (0.037) Linear time trend Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 210 210 144 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.81 0.81 0.67 0.63 0.57 0.46 Dependent variable: frequency of regular price changes U.K. U.S.—BLS U.S.—Vavra (2014) V-shaped Flag Ref. price Mean Mean Median |$u_{t}$| 0.602*** 0.536 0.305*** 0.160 0.335*** 0.195** (0.212) (0.365) (0.084) (0.219) (0.089) (0.078) Linear time trend Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 210 210 144 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.32 0.19 0.38 0.61 0.57 0.46 . Dependent variable: frequency of sales . . U.K. . . U.S.—BLS . . U.S.—Vavra (2014) . . V-shaped . V-shaped . Flag . . Mean . . Mean . Median . |$u_{t}$| 0.459*** 0.457*** 0.363*** 0.208*** 0.357*** 0.529*** (0.033) (0.032) (0.041) (0.033) (0.045) (0.060) |$freg_{t}$| 0.008 -0.008 -0.11*** -0.458*** (0.008) (0.006) (0.042) (0.059) |$freg\_pos_{t}$| 0.004 -0.062* (0.008) (0.032) |$freg\_neg_{t}$| 0.033 -0.029 (0.022) (0.037) Linear time trend Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 210 210 144 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.81 0.81 0.67 0.63 0.57 0.46 Dependent variable: frequency of regular price changes U.K. U.S.—BLS U.S.—Vavra (2014) V-shaped Flag Ref. price Mean Mean Median |$u_{t}$| 0.602*** 0.536 0.305*** 0.160 0.335*** 0.195** (0.212) (0.365) (0.084) (0.219) (0.089) (0.078) Linear time trend Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 210 210 210 144 288 288 |$R^{2}$| 0.32 0.19 0.38 0.61 0.57 0.46 Notes: Linear regressions of the fraction of products on sale on the unemployment rate (⁠|$u_{t}$|⁠) as well as the frequency of regular price changes (⁠|$freg_{t}$|⁠), increases (⁠|$freg\_pos_{t}$|⁠), and decreases (⁠|$freg\_neg_{t}$|⁠). “Mean” and “Median” indicate mean and median frequencies respectively. All regressions include calendar month dummies. Newey-West standard errors allowing for a maximum autocorrelation of four lags are indicated in parentheses. *** p <; 0.01, ** p <; 0.05, * p <; 0.1. Sample periods are described in Table 3. Open in new tab Second, we directly investigate the cyclicality of regular price changes. We find that a 5-ppt increase in the unemployment rate is associated with a 3-ppt higher probability of observing a change in the regular price based on the V-shaped filter, compared to an unconditional frequency of 10.9% (see bottom panel of Table 4). The corresponding effect for reference prices is 1.5 ppt (unconditional frequency of 7.5%). When we use the sales flag, the effects of unemployment on regular or reference prices are not statistically significant. The variation of regular price changes, while not negligible, is smaller than for sales frequency: we found earlier that a similar unemployment rate hike about doubled the incidence of sales. The empirical fit is also lower based on the |$R^{2}$|⁠. Conclusions are similar for the U.S. and in line with the findings of Vavra (2014). 4. Disaggregate Evidence Next, we investigate the robustness of our findings at a more disaggregated level. In the process, we document some other salient features of temporary sales in the data. 4.1. Category- and region-level results We start by verifying that the aggregate relationship we found earlier is present at the category and regional level. 4.1.1. Cyclicality of sales across product categories As a first exercise, we verify that the cyclicality of aggregated V-shaped sales is not merely driven by a few large categories and is in fact widespread across product types. We run separate regressions of sales frequency on the unemployment rate and a time trend for the 36 U.K. CPI categories with data for the whole sample and an average frequency of sales of at least 0.5%. The top row of Figure 7 shows histograms of the regression coefficients on the unemployment rate at the category level, for both the V-shaped (left column) and sales flag (right column) filters. They confirm that the countercyclicality of sales is reasonably broad-based: out of 36 categories, only two have a negative coefficient for both filters, and neither is statistically significant based on Newey-West standard errors. Of the 34 for which the coefficient on unemployment is positive, 26 are significant at the 5% level for the V-shaped sales filter, with a mean and median of 0.81 and 0.71, respectively.17 Figure 7 Open in new tabDownload slide Cyclicality of sales at the category level, U.K. CPI data Notes: Distribution of coefficients from two regressions at the category level. Top row: Sales frequency on monthly aggregate unemployment rate and a time trend. Bottom row: Sales frequency on the log of quarterly category-level real consumption and a time trend. Sales are identified using the V-shape (left column) or sales flag (right column) filter and must be at least 10% in size. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Figure 7 Open in new tabDownload slide Cyclicality of sales at the category level, U.K. CPI data Notes: Distribution of coefficients from two regressions at the category level. Top row: Sales frequency on monthly aggregate unemployment rate and a time trend. Bottom row: Sales frequency on the log of quarterly category-level real consumption and a time trend. Sales are identified using the V-shape (left column) or sales flag (right column) filter and must be at least 10% in size. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. We also use real consumption at the category level instead of aggregate unemployment. Because the data are only available at the quarterly frequency, we aggregate the fraction of items on sale accordingly. We then run regressions of category-specific sales frequency on the category-specific log of real consumption and a linear trend. The distribution of coefficients on consumption is reported in the bottom panel of Figure 7. Once again, sales are countercyclical for most sectors (29 out of 36 for V-shaped sales), with a mean and median of –0.004 and –0.003, respectively. 4.1.2. Cyclicality and category characteristics In addition, we explore how the category-level cyclicality of sales changes with observed category characteristics and pricing behaviour, including the data on life expectancy for durable goods, obtained from Bils and Klenow (1998) for the U.S.; 5-firm concentration ratios for the U.K. in 2004 from Mahajan (2006); and category-specific moments for price-adjustment variables (inflation, frequency of price changes, and absolute size of price changes; their means and standard deviations over time, using posted and regular prices); see Data Appendix A.6 for more details. We find that more durable goods and goods with more concentrated businesses tend to have more countercyclical sales, although these correlations are relatively weak due to the small number of observations for which we matched the data for durability (12) and concentration ratios (29). Theories in which retailers compete for market share or in which intertemporal demand effects are present would be favoured by such evidence (e.g.Hendel and Nevo, 2006). In regressions on price-adjustment moments, two of them result in significant correlations across categories. Discounts for goods with smaller mean absolute sizes of price changes or those with more volatile frequencies of price changes (for either posted or regular prices) tend to be more countercyclical. This evidence is consistent with predictions of models with fixed costs of price adjustment, in which goods with smaller fixed costs and more flexible price adjustment, and in particular, more frequent sales, would need smaller price changes on average. 4.1.3. Cyclicality of sales at the regional level Next, we verify whether the cyclicality of sales is present across U.K. regions. To do so, we regress the frequency of V-shaped sales on the monthly regional unemployment rate and a time trend. The coefficients from these regressions are plotted in Figure 8. The frequency of temporary discounts is significantly countercyclical for all 11 regions. The strongest relationship is for East Anglia: a 5-ppt increase in the unemployment rate is associated with a 2.8-ppt increase in the sales frequency, or more than double its unconditional mean. The weakest, on the other hand, is the North, at about 40% of the size. These differences in estimates are directly related to the fact that while the frequency of sales is very similar across regions, unemployment rates vary much more. Additional region-level results can be found in Data Appendix A.7. In Section 4.3, we discuss how uniform national pricing strategies by large retailers can rationalize this finding. Figure 8 Open in new tabDownload slide Cyclicality of sales at the regional level, U.K. CPI data Notes: Distribution of coefficients from regional regressions of sales frequency on the monthly regional unemployment rate and a time trend. Sales are identified using the V-shape filter and must be at least 10% in size. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Figure 8 Open in new tabDownload slide Cyclicality of sales at the regional level, U.K. CPI data Notes: Distribution of coefficients from regional regressions of sales frequency on the monthly regional unemployment rate and a time trend. Sales are identified using the V-shape filter and must be at least 10% in size. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. 4.1.4. The role of clearance sales Finally, we investigate whether the cyclicality of temporary discounts is driven by the higher occurrence of clearance sales during recessions relative to booms, possibly as firms are left with unsold inventories. To this end, we compute the probability of observing a sales flag within the last two months of a quote line.18 We find that in a typical month, clearance sales are much rarer (average probability of 0.7%) than non-clearance sales (3.5%). This is mainly due to the fact that clearance sales can only occur at the end of a quote line; clearance sales in fact account for about 8.2% of price observations within the last two months of a quote line. In other words, while markdowns are particularly frequent towards the end of the life of a typical product, these clearance sales account for only about one-sixth of all sales in the sample. Figure 9 plots the time series of both clearance and non-clearance sales for the aggregate as well as three broad categories. There are wide differences in the prevalence of sales across product categories. For Clothing and Footwear, 18% of the observations in the last two months are flagged as sales by the ONS, compared to a frequency of around 8% for other periods, while the same numbers are 25% and 13%, respectively for Audio and Video. Food products, on the other hand, do not display more sales towards the end of quote lines. Second, for the aggregate as well as the three broad categories, Figure 9 indicates that the frequency of both clearance and non-clearance sales follow the same countercyclical pattern that we documented earlier. In sum, the cyclicality of overall temporary discounts does not appear to be driven by clearance sales. Figure 9 Open in new tabDownload slide Frequency of clearance and non-clearance sales Notes: Clearance sales are defined as sales flags occurring within the last two months of a quote line. CPI quote weights are used for aggregation. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Figure 9 Open in new tabDownload slide Frequency of clearance and non-clearance sales Notes: Clearance sales are defined as sales flags occurring within the last two months of a quote line. CPI quote weights are used for aggregation. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. 4.2. Product-level results To control for composition bias as well as additional factors that may affect our conclusions, we supplement our analysis with a panel regression analysis at the product-store level. The dependent variable is the sale indicator |$\gamma_{ijt}$|⁠, which is equal to 1 if product i at store j is on sale at time t, and 0 otherwise. We run linear probability models (LPM) in order to exploit the panel structure of our dataset and include product-store fixed effects; including a large number of fixed effects with a nonlinear method such as probit would expose us to bias caused by the incidental parameters problem.19 The basic specification is standard and given by $$\begin{equation} \gamma_{ijt}=\alpha_{ij}+\beta u_{t}+X_{t}^{'}\varPhi+error\,,\label{eq:panel_regression} \end{equation}$$(1) where |$u_{t}$| is the unemployment rate, and |$X_{t}$| is a matrix of controls such as calendar month dummies or a time trend. All regressions include dummies for the months in which VAT rate changes occurred, as described in Section 2.1. Table 5 summarizes our results. The unemployment rate is a statistically significant predictor of the occurrence of a temporary sale: a 5-ppt increase in the unemployment rate raises the likelihood of observing a sale by about 2.2 ppt. Adding a time trend or one lag of the dependent variable has little effect on the economic or statistical significance of this relationship. The results are also robust to the use of the two other definitions of sales. Table 5. Panel regression results at the product level—U.K. data . V-shaped . . Sales flag . . Ref. price . . (1) . (2) . (3) . . (4) . . (5) . |$u_{t}$| 0.444|$^{***}$| 0.364|$^{***}$| 0.409 |$^{***}$| 0.402|$^{***}$| 0.351|$^{***}$| |$s_{i,t-1}$| 0.105|$^{***}$| Month dummies Y Y Y Y Y Time trend N Y N N N Fixed effects Y Y Y Y Y Observations 11,950,985 11,950,985 10,977,476 11,859,985 11,892,464 F-stat 11.48 13.02 46.35 3.77 16.26 Alt. macro indicators (normalized) (6) (7) (8) (9) |$u_{t}$| (normalized) 0.0055|$^{***}$| Retail sales vol. -0.0050|$^{***}$| Consumer confidence -0.0026|$^{***}$| Fin. situation next year -0.0039|$^{***}$| Month dummies Y Y Y Y Time trend N N N N Fixed effects Y Y Y Y Observations 11,673,020 11,673,020 11,673,020 11,673,020 F-stat 11.48 11.27 11.11 11.25 . V-shaped . . Sales flag . . Ref. price . . (1) . (2) . (3) . . (4) . . (5) . |$u_{t}$| 0.444|$^{***}$| 0.364|$^{***}$| 0.409 |$^{***}$| 0.402|$^{***}$| 0.351|$^{***}$| |$s_{i,t-1}$| 0.105|$^{***}$| Month dummies Y Y Y Y Y Time trend N Y N N N Fixed effects Y Y Y Y Y Observations 11,950,985 11,950,985 10,977,476 11,859,985 11,892,464 F-stat 11.48 13.02 46.35 3.77 16.26 Alt. macro indicators (normalized) (6) (7) (8) (9) |$u_{t}$| (normalized) 0.0055|$^{***}$| Retail sales vol. -0.0050|$^{***}$| Consumer confidence -0.0026|$^{***}$| Fin. situation next year -0.0039|$^{***}$| Month dummies Y Y Y Y Time trend N N N N Fixed effects Y Y Y Y Observations 11,673,020 11,673,020 11,673,020 11,673,020 F-stat 11.48 11.27 11.11 11.25 Notes: Panel regressions at the item level: |$\gamma_{it}=\alpha_{i}+\beta u_{t}+X_{t}^{'}\varPhi+e_{it}$|⁠, where |$\gamma_{it}$| is a 0/1 sale indicator and |$u_{t}$| is an aggregate business cycle indicator, usually the unemployment rate. For the last panel of the table, the macroeconomic indicators are normalized by their standard deviation to facilitate comparisons. For all regressions, standard errors are clustered at the product category level. *** p <; 0.01, ** p <; 0.05, * p <; 0.1. The sample period is February 1996 to September 2013. Open in new tab Table 5. Panel regression results at the product level—U.K. data . V-shaped . . Sales flag . . Ref. price . . (1) . (2) . (3) . . (4) . . (5) . |$u_{t}$| 0.444|$^{***}$| 0.364|$^{***}$| 0.409 |$^{***}$| 0.402|$^{***}$| 0.351|$^{***}$| |$s_{i,t-1}$| 0.105|$^{***}$| Month dummies Y Y Y Y Y Time trend N Y N N N Fixed effects Y Y Y Y Y Observations 11,950,985 11,950,985 10,977,476 11,859,985 11,892,464 F-stat 11.48 13.02 46.35 3.77 16.26 Alt. macro indicators (normalized) (6) (7) (8) (9) |$u_{t}$| (normalized) 0.0055|$^{***}$| Retail sales vol. -0.0050|$^{***}$| Consumer confidence -0.0026|$^{***}$| Fin. situation next year -0.0039|$^{***}$| Month dummies Y Y Y Y Time trend N N N N Fixed effects Y Y Y Y Observations 11,673,020 11,673,020 11,673,020 11,673,020 F-stat 11.48 11.27 11.11 11.25 . V-shaped . . Sales flag . . Ref. price . . (1) . (2) . (3) . . (4) . . (5) . |$u_{t}$| 0.444|$^{***}$| 0.364|$^{***}$| 0.409 |$^{***}$| 0.402|$^{***}$| 0.351|$^{***}$| |$s_{i,t-1}$| 0.105|$^{***}$| Month dummies Y Y Y Y Y Time trend N Y N N N Fixed effects Y Y Y Y Y Observations 11,950,985 11,950,985 10,977,476 11,859,985 11,892,464 F-stat 11.48 13.02 46.35 3.77 16.26 Alt. macro indicators (normalized) (6) (7) (8) (9) |$u_{t}$| (normalized) 0.0055|$^{***}$| Retail sales vol. -0.0050|$^{***}$| Consumer confidence -0.0026|$^{***}$| Fin. situation next year -0.0039|$^{***}$| Month dummies Y Y Y Y Time trend N N N N Fixed effects Y Y Y Y Observations 11,673,020 11,673,020 11,673,020 11,673,020 F-stat 11.48 11.27 11.11 11.25 Notes: Panel regressions at the item level: |$\gamma_{it}=\alpha_{i}+\beta u_{t}+X_{t}^{'}\varPhi+e_{it}$|⁠, where |$\gamma_{it}$| is a 0/1 sale indicator and |$u_{t}$| is an aggregate business cycle indicator, usually the unemployment rate. For the last panel of the table, the macroeconomic indicators are normalized by their standard deviation to facilitate comparisons. For all regressions, standard errors are clustered at the product category level. *** p <; 0.01, ** p <; 0.05, * p <; 0.1. The sample period is February 1996 to September 2013. Open in new tab We also verify that our findings are robust to the use of alternative business cycle indicators in equation (1) instead of |$u_{t}$|⁠. First, we replace the unemployment rate with monthly retail sales volume, linearly detrended. This is a measure that is arguably a particularly relevant indicator of aggregate economic conditions faced by retailers. Second, to capture the economic outlook of households, we also use consumer confidence indicators for the U.K. as compiled by the company GfK on behalf of the European Commission. In these monthly surveys, various questions are asked to a sample of households. We focus on the aggregate consumer confidence index as well as the question about the personal financial situation over the next 12 months. To facilitate comparisons, we normalize all indicators by dividing them by their respective time-series standard deviations over the sample. The results in Table 5 show responses in the same order of magnitude across all four indicators: a one standard deviation decrease in either measure of consumer confidence leads to a statistically significant increase of between 0.25 and 0.40 ppt in the frequency of sales, and that increase is around 0.5 ppt for a one standard deviation increase (decrease) in the unemployment rate (retail sales volume).20 4.3. Sales across stores and space Finally, we discuss the characteristics of sales in the cross-section, focusing on retailer type and regions. 4.3.1. Retailer type For each price quote, the ONS provides both a store identifier and a flag indicating whether the store belongs to an independent retailer (less than 10 locations) or a chain (10 locations or more), a category labeled “Multiples” by the ONS. Chains account for about 64% of observations and 55% of CPI weights. We find striking differences between the incidence of discounts for both types of stores: sales are much more prevalent and volatile for larger retailers than for smaller retailers, for both the V-shaped and sales flag filters (see Data Appendix A.10). For example, using V-shaped sales and CPI weights, the average frequencies are 3.4% for multiples and 1% for independents (4.5% and 1.5% unweighted), while the time series standard deviations are 1.3% and 0.5%, respectively. Moreover, there is some evidence that sales are more cyclical for larger retailers. Our finding that sales are much more prevalent at large chains could be an indication that there are non-trivial costs and scale effects associated with store discounts. Some of these costs may be monetary, such as the production of displays and flyers or the adoption of specific sales-optimization technologies, but they could also be managerial. For example, it is well known that in some sectors, temporary sales are often negotiated between the retailer and the manufacturer; Anderson et al. (2017), for example, highlight the role of “trade deal budgets” and “trade promotion calendars.” If this coordination is costly, smaller retailers may limit their use, and suppliers may be less inclined to design and finance promotions with independent stores than large retailers. Alternatively, there may be economies of scale in the benefits from temporary sales. For example, consider that retailers use discounted products as loss leaders, in the hope that consumers will also buy other products at higher prices. The benefits from such a strategy are likely to be more limited at smaller stores with less product variety. 4.3.2. Sales and local economic conditions Despite our very robust time-series evidence, we did not find any significant relationship between sales and economic conditions across U.K. regions. In fact, as we discussed in Section 4.1, there is very little regional variation in the frequency of sales. This is in line with the evidence from Anderson et al. (2017) and Coibion et al. (2015), who do not find evidence of economic variation in sales in the U.S. cross-section data.21 Combined with our finding that larger chains account for a disproportionate fraction of discounts, the documented widespread use of uniform pricing may rationalize these findings. Dobson and Waterson (2008) document that since the early 2000s, “the major retailers [...] have eschewed the opportunity to customize prices on a store-by-store basis in favour of national pricing.” In addition, Freeman et al. (2008) provide evidence that the largest U.K. chains with the most widespread store networks, such as Tesco, Sainsbury’s, and Asda, run local price discounts based on centrally determined criteria or as part of national promotional programs. Uniform pricing is also ubiquitous in the U.S. DellaVigna and Gentzkow (2019), for example, find that for a typical U.S. product in a given week, retail chains post almost uniform prices across all their stores, irrespective of local differences in household income. Looking at evidence from a representative chain in the Nielsen dataset, they “[...] see variation across products in the depth and timing of sales, but again no systematic variation in prices across stores [within the chain].” This is in line with the evidence in Hitsch et al. (2019), who find that “the incidence of price promotions is strongly coordinated within retail chains, both at the local market level and nationally.” Nakamura et al. (2011) study the Symphony IRI scanner dataset and conclude that a large portion of the variation in the use of sales across stores is due to chain-level heterogeneity. In the context of home improvement stores, Adams and Williams (2019) document a lot of heterogeneity across products, with a mix of uniform and zone pricing. All in all, in a market dominated by large national chains with uniform pricing strategies, we should therefore not be surprised to find that sales are more reflective of aggregate rather than local economic conditions.22 Possible reasons behind such pricing strategy are numerous, even if direct evidence is relatively scarce in the literature. Based on empirical estimates, Hitsch et al. (2019) suggest that “demand similarity and the inability to distinguish demand across the stores in a local market are likely the primary reason for the similarity in prices and promotions,” which would explain why managers view local pricing as difficult to implement in practice. Similarly, DellaVigna and Gentzkow (2019) “suspect that managerial inertia may be the most important explanation for uniform pricing.” Responses indicate that this inertia may arise from the limited sophistication of pricing teams and organizational barriers at the store level, or rational inattention: faced with limited resources and scarce attention, chains decide to optimize along other dimensions (such as overall sales patterns and price levels). They also highlight brand image concerns: if consumers see different prices across stores as unfair, this may hurt profits in the long run. Faced with these constraints, it may seem that a natural alternative would be for the chain to defer all pricing decisions, including promotions, to store managers. As Adams and Williams (2019) show, however, this can give rise to large losses as individual stores fail to internalize the impact of their pricing decisions on other stores from the same chain. 5. A general equilibrium model with sales To understand the dynamics of temporary sales and their importance for aggregate fluctuations, we build a general equilibrium business cycle model in which discounts arise endogenously. Before delving into the details of the model, we provide a summary of its main components and features. 5.1. Overview of the model The economy is composed of a very large number |$L$| of locations. In each location |$l$|⁠, there lives a measure one of infinitely lived ex ante identical households who derive utility from consuming perishable products of countably many differentiated varieties, indexed by |$j=1,2,...,J$|⁠, where |$J$| is a very large number. Also, in every location, there exists a local shopping mall populated by |$J$| firms, each selling a unit measure of perfectly substitutable brands of specific variety |$j$|⁠. Every firm chooses three objects in its pricing decision: a regular nominal price |$p^{H}$|⁠, a nominal sale price |$p^{L}$|⁠, and the fraction |$\gamma$| of homogenous brands that it sells at the sale price.23 The regular nominal price can only be changed every |$N_{P}$| periods. In contrast, the firm can change its sale price in any period for free, but it incurs the cost of |$\kappa\gamma$| units of labour for the fraction |$\gamma$| of its goods on sale. Firms make their pricing decisions before the households’ shopping decisions. Each household is composed of a household head and |$J$| shoppers, where each shopper is assigned to one and only one variety. Since |$J$| is a large number, a shopper can be interpreted as atomistic for the total consumption of the household. Households living in location |$l^{*}$| know the pricing decisions |$\left\{ p_{j,l^{*}}^{H},p_{j,l^{*}}^{L},\gamma_{j,l^{*}}\right\} $| of every |$j$| retailer at the local shopping mall. In addition, they know the distribution of |$\left\{ p_{j,l}^{H},p_{j,l}^{L},\gamma_{j,l}\right\} $| across all the other locations |$l$|⁠. For each shopper |$j$|⁠, the household head has two options. One is to instruct her to draw a brand from the seller in a random location |$l$|⁠, with (unknown) probability |$\gamma_{j,l}$| of drawing the sale price |$p_{j,l}^{L}$|⁠. Another option is to send the shopper to the local shopping mall, with the instruction of searching for a brand on sale. As a bargain hunter, the known probability that she finds a discounted brand is higher and is given by |$f\gamma_{j,l^{*}}$|⁠, with |$f>1$|⁠. This, however, comes at a cost: the household head commits to paying a random cost |$z$| (in units of time) if she sends the shopper as a bargain hunter to the local shopping mall. Under these assumptions, household |$i$|’s decision for assigning a type to the shopper of variety |$j$| will be in the form of a static cut-off rule: the household head chooses a value |$z_{j}^{\ast}(i)$| such that member |$j$| is designated as bargain hunter for low realizations of the shopping costs, |$z\leq z_{j}^{\ast}(i)$|⁠, and as random shopper when the shopping cost is high, |$z>z_{j}^{\ast}(i)$|⁠. This implies that from the point of view of a firm, shoppers visiting it as bargain hunters have a higher probability of finding a product on sale than do the random shoppers. The firm cannot, however, discriminate between these two types. When setting its pricing policy—|$p_{j,l^{\ast}}^{H},p_{j,l^{\ast}}^{L}$| and |$\gamma_{j,l^{\ast}}$|—the firm thinks through the reactions of local households who are informed about prices in the local shopping mall |$l^{*},$|and those who live in other locations. First, it realizes that it can attract a higher fraction of informed local households by lowering their expected price, |$f\gamma_{j,l^{\ast}}p_{j,l^{\ast}}^{L} $|⁠. Even though its regular price |$p_{j,l^{\ast}}^{H}$| is sticky, this can be achieved by lowering the flexible sale price |$p_{j,l^{\ast}}^{L}$|⁠, or by raising the fraction of brands on sale |$\gamma_{j,l^{\ast}}$|⁠, at a cost |$\kappa\gamma_{j,l^{\ast}}$|⁠. In turn, a lower expected price raises the cutoff cost |$z_{j}^{\ast}$| that these local households are willing to pay to designate shoppers as bargain hunters. By contrast, the firm cannot influence the mass of shoppers from other locations, who visit it randomly. Second, the firm’s pricing policy determines the quantity demanded by each shopper in its store. This quantity is a standard CES function of the specific price she draws. Ultimately, the firm has to trade off the costs and benefits from changing its prices on the profits made from the two types of shoppers. Because prices are sticky, monetary contractions are associated with high average price markups, making it desirable for retailers to expand their market share by posting more discounts. This, in turn, incentivizes households to send more bargain hunters. In Section 6, we show that our model can account quantitatively for countercyclical fluctuations of the fraction of discounts over the business cycle. But first, we lay out the model’s structure and provide its main equilibrium conditions. The presentation of the full framework and a graphical representation of its most important components is relegated to the Model Appendix. 5.2. Households Consider a household |$i$| who lives in location |$l^{*}$|⁠. As mentioned earlier, the household head knows |$p_{j,l^{*}(i)}^{H}$|⁠, |$p_{j,l^{*}(i)}^{L}$|⁠, and |$\gamma_{j,l^{*}(i)}$| on offer for each variety |$j$| sold at the local shopping mall. In addition, she knows the overall distribution of |$\left\{ p_{j,l}^{H},p_{j,l}^{L},\gamma_{j,l}\right\} $| across the other locations, but not which prices are charged in each of those locations. Under the assumption that households are distributed uniformly across locations |$l^{*},$| and given that there is a large number of households and varieties, households and firms are symmetric. Therefore, we will focus on a symmetric equilibrium in which in any given period |$t$|⁠, each household |$i$| sends the same fraction of bargain hunters, and all firms receive the same fraction of bargain hunters, and hence, make the same pricing decisions. Going forward, we will drop variety index |$j$| and use capital letters to identify aggregate variables to simply notation. We will also drop location indices, and distinguish variables pertaining to locations |$l\neq l^{*}(i)$| by a tilde. The sets of varieties and locations are denoted by |$\mathcal{J}$| and |$\mathcal{L,}$| respectively. Aggregate events in this economy up to and including period |$t$| are recorded in the vector |$s^{t}=\left(s_{0},...,s_{t}\right)$|⁠, and |$\pi(s^{t})$| denotes the probability of a particular history |$s^{t}$|⁠. We will use subscript |$t$| to annotate functions of state history |$s^{t}$|⁠. Below, we will use the operator |$E_{t}(X_{\tau})$| to denote expected values of function |$X(s^{\tau})$| conditional on history |$s^{t}$|⁠, i.e., |$E_{t}(X_{\tau})\equiv\sum_{s^{\tau}|s^{t}}\pi(s^{\tau}|s^{t})X(s^{\tau})$|⁠. 5.2.1. Shopper types A shopper for a specific variety can be one of two types: bargain hunter or random shopper. These two types differ in how they convert available price information into a probability of being matched with a low price. A random shopper |$j$| does not observe the specific prices posted by retailers, so she randomly visits a location |$l\neq l^{*},$| goes to the store selling variety |$j$| in that location and picks a brand at random, i.e., she draws a brand priced at |$\widetilde{p}^{L}$| with probability |$\widetilde{\gamma}$| or at |$\widetilde{p}^{H}$| with probability |$1-\widetilde{\gamma}$|⁠. A bargain hunter visits the local shopping mall in |$l^{*}$|⁠, for which she knows the retailers’ prices. Equipped with price information, she generates a higher probability of drawing a brand with a low price |$p^{L}$|⁠, given by |$f\gamma$|⁠, where by assumption |$f>1$|⁠. Accordingly, she has a lower probability of finding a regular price |$p^{H}$|⁠, equal to |$1-f\gamma$|⁠. Bargain hunters yield to the household higher returns from shopping because they are more likely to be matched with a low-priced brand. They are also, as we see next, costlier. 5.2.2. Cost of shopping Each bargain hunter costs the household |$z$| units of time, where |$z$| is i.i.d. across shoppers and time, and distributed according to a smooth c.d.f. |$G\left(z\right)$|⁠, |$0\leq z\leq z_{\rm max}$|⁠. Under these assumptions, household |$i$|’s decision for assigning a type to the shopper of variety |$j$| will be in the form of a static cut-off rule: the household head chooses a value |$z^{\ast}(i)$| such that member |$j$| is designated as bargain hunter for low realizations of the shopping costs, |$z\leq z^{\ast}(i)$|⁠, and as random shopper when the shopping cost is high, |$z>z^{\ast}(i)$|⁠. The choice of |$z^{\ast}(i)$| determines the probability that variety |$j$| will be purchased by a bargain hunter, which we denote by |$\alpha(i)\equiv G\left(z^{\ast}(i)\right)$|⁠. The expected shopping cost for variety |$j$| is |$\int_{0}^{z^{\ast}(i)}zdG\left(z\right)$|⁠. Recall that this household knows the exact price menu |$\left\{ p_{j}^{H},p_{j}^{L},\gamma_{j}\right\} $| in a given location |$l^{*}$|⁠, and the distribution of prices everywhere else. Hence, the key decision of the household head is whether to pay the fixed cost |$z$| and have a higher probability of finding a discounted brand in the local shopping mall, or forego the cost and just shop randomly. Since households pick the shopper type after obtaining information about prices, firms know that their pricing decision will influence the fraction of bargain hunters that visit them. 5.2.3. Consumption outcomes For each variety |$j$|⁠, and for any cut-off value |$z^{\ast}(i)$|⁠, household |$i$| faces four random and mutually exclusive consumption outcomes:24 the shopper will be a bargain hunter and visit the local shopping mall in her location |$l^{*}$|⁠, matched with a discounted brand with probability |$\alpha(i)f\gamma$|⁠, or with a regularly priced brand with probability |$\alpha(i)\left(1-f\gamma\right)$|⁠; the shopper will be a random shopper in a random location |$l$|⁠, matched with a discounted brand with probability |$\left(1-\alpha(i)\right)\widetilde{\gamma}$|⁠, or with a regularly priced brand with probability |$\left(1-\alpha(i)\right)\left(1-\widetilde{\gamma}\right)$|⁠. Let |$x_{t}(i)$| denote the realization of one of these four consumption outcomes, and let |$\pi^{x}(x_{t}(i))$| be its respective probability, as specified above. Also, let |$c_{t}(x_{t}(i))$| denote a consumption plan—units of consumption of variety |$j$| purchased by shopper |$j$| and conditional on the realization of one of the four consumption outcomes |$x_{t}(i)$|⁠. 5.2.4. Total consumption Household |$i$|’s ex post consumption—i.e., consumption conditional on realizations of |$x_{t}(i)$|—is the CES aggregate $$\begin{equation} C_{t}(i)=\left[\sum_{\mathcal{J}}c_{t}(x_{t}(i))^{1-\frac{1}{\theta}}\right]^{\frac{\theta}{\theta-1}},\label{eq: agg c} \end{equation}$$(2) where |$\theta$| is the elasticity of substitution across varieties. Since draws of |$x_{t}(i)$| are identically and independently distributed across households and varieties, by the law of large numbers, the summation in (2) does not depend on which outcomes |$x_{t}(i)$| are realized across specific households and varieties. This implies two convenient aggregation properties.25 First, since households are ex ante identical, total consumption |$C_{t}(i)$| and the price aggregate |$P_{t}(i)$| are equal for all households, i.e., |$C_{t}(i)=C_{t},\,P_{t}(i)=P_{t},\,\forall i$|⁠. This also implies that a household’s ex post consumption, |$C_{t}(i)$|⁠, is equal to its ex ante consumption, |$\sum_{x_{t}(i)}\pi^{x}(x_{t})C_{t}(i)$|⁠. Second, since realizations |$x_{t}(i)$| are independent across varieties, we can take probabilities |$\pi^{x}(x_{t})$| inside the summation in (2) and write $$\begin{eqnarray} & C_{t}(i) & =\left\{ \sum_{J}\left[G(z_{t}^{\ast}(i))\left(f\gamma_{t}\left(c_{t}^{L}(i)\right)^{1-\frac{1}{\theta}}+(1-f\gamma_{t})\left(c_{t}^{H}(i)\right)^{1-\frac{1}{\theta}}\right)\right.\right.\nonumber \\ & & \left.\left.+\left(1-G(z_{t}^{\ast}(i))\right)\sum_{\mathcal{L}\setminus l^{\ast}}\left(\widetilde{\gamma}_{t}\left(\widetilde{c}_{t}^{L}(i)\right)^{1-\frac{1}{\theta}}+(1-\widetilde{\gamma}_{t})\left(\widetilde{c}_{t}^{H}(i)\right)^{1-\frac{1}{\theta}}\right)\right]\right\} ^{\frac{\theta}{\theta-1}}.\label{eq: agg c again-1} \end{eqnarray}$$(3) where |$c_{t}^{L}(i)$|⁠, |$c_{t}^{H}(i)$|⁠, |$\widetilde{c}_{t}^{L}(i)$|⁠, |$\widetilde{c}_{t}^{H}(i)$| denote the four possible consumption outcomes for variety |$j$| in period |$t$|⁠, and |$\sum_{\mathcal{L}\setminus l^{\ast}}$| denotes the average over |$L-1$| locations the random shopper is uninformed about. From now on, we will omit the household index |$i$|⁠, unless necessary. 5.2.5. Dynamic optimization problem of the household Households are organized in labour unions over countably many differentiated labour services indexed by |$u=1,2,...,U$|⁠. Each union consists of all households with labour type |$u$| and supplies labour services of that type in a monopolistically competitive labour market. A household head who is a member of union |$u$| supplies all labour services |$L_{t}$| demanded by the union and receives wage |$W_{t}$| set by the union. For the remaining decisions, the household head chooses the sequences of total consumption |$C_{t}$|⁠, cash holdings |$M_{t}$|⁠, security holdings |$\mathbf{A}_{t+1}$|⁠, bond holdings |$B_{t}$|⁠, the cut-off search cost for each variety |$z_{t}^{*}$|⁠, and consumption plans for each variety |$c_{t}^{L}$|⁠, |$c_{t}^{H}$|⁠, |$c_{t}^{L}$|⁠, |$c_{t}^{H}$| to maximize: $$\begin{equation} E_{0}\sum_{t}\beta^{t}\left[u\left(C_{t}\right)-v\left(L_{t}\right)\right]\,,\label{eq: utility} \end{equation}$$(4) subject to the definition of aggregate consumption (3), the sequence of budget constraints $$\begin{eqnarray} & M_{t}+B_{t}+\sum_{t+1|t}\mathbf{Q}_{t+1|t}\mathbf{A}_{t+1}\leq W_{t}L_{t}+R_{t-1}B_{t-1}+A_{t}+\Pi_{t}+T_{t}\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\nonumber \\[6pt] & +M_{t-1}-W_{t-1}^{F}\sum_{j}\int_{0}^{z_{t-1}^{\ast}}zdG\left(z\right)\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\nonumber \\[6pt] & -\sum_{\mathcal{J}}\left[G(z_{t-1}^{\ast})\left(f\gamma_{t-1}p_{t-1}^{L}c_{t-1}^{L}+(1-f\gamma_{t-1})p_{t-1}^{H}c_{t-1}^{H}\right)\right.\nonumber \\[6pt] & \left.+\left(1-G(z_{t-1}^{\ast})\right)\sum_{\mathcal{L}\setminus l^{\ast}}\left(\widetilde{\gamma}_{t-1}\widetilde{p}_{t-1}^{L}\widetilde{c}_{t-1}^{L}+(1-\widetilde{\gamma}_{t-1})\widetilde{p}_{t-1}^{H}\widetilde{c}_{t-1}^{H}\right)\right]\label{eq: bc}, \end{eqnarray}$$(5) where the last three rows represent unspent cash carried over from period |$t-1$| to |$t$|⁠, |$W_{t}^{F}$| is aggregate wage, |$\Pi_{t}$| are dividends paid and |$T_{t}$| are lump-sum government transfers; and the sequence of cash-in-advance constraints for total consumption and shopping expenses26 $$\begin{eqnarray} M_{t} & \geq & W_{t}^{F}\sum_{j}\int_{0}^{z_{t}^{\ast}}zdG\left(z\right)+\sum_{\mathcal{J}}\left[G(z_{t}^{\ast})\left(f\gamma_{t}p_{t}^{L}c_{t}^{L}+(1-f\gamma_{t})p_{t}^{H}c_{t}^{H}\right)\right.\nonumber \\ & & \left.+\left(1-G(z_{t}^{\ast})\right)\sum_{\mathcal{L}\setminus l^{\ast}}\left(\widetilde{\gamma}_{t}\widetilde{p}_{t}^{L}\widetilde{c}_{t}^{L}+(1-\widetilde{\gamma}_{t})\widetilde{p}_{t}^{H}\widetilde{c}_{t}^{H}\right)\right]\,.\label{eq: cia} \end{eqnarray}$$(6) 5.2.6. Consumption decisions The first-order conditions for consumption varieties yield the consumption plan $$\begin{equation} \widetilde{c}_{t}^{k}=\left(\frac{\widetilde{p}_{t}^{k}}{P_{t}}\right)^{-\theta}C_{t}\,,\,\text{ and }\,c_{t}^{k}=\left(\frac{p_{t}^{k}}{P_{t}}\right)^{-\theta}C_{t}\,,\,\,\,k=\left\{ L,\,H\right\} ,\label{eq:ces demand} \end{equation}$$(7) where the aggregate price index is $$\begin{eqnarray*} & P_{t} & \equiv\left\{ \sum_{\mathcal{J}}\left[G(z_{t}^{\ast})\left(f\gamma_{t}\left(p_{jt}^{L}\right)^{1-\theta}+(1-f\gamma_{t})\left(p_{t}^{H}\right)^{1-\theta}\right)\right.\right.\\ & & \left.\left.+\left(1-G(z_{t}^{\ast})\right)\sum_{\mathcal{L}\setminus l^{\ast}}\left(\widetilde{\gamma}_{t}\left(\widetilde{p}_{t}^{L}\right)^{1-\theta}+(1-\widetilde{\gamma}_{t})\left(\widetilde{p}_{t}^{H}\right)^{1-\theta}\right)\right]\right\} ^{\frac{1}{1-\theta}}. \end{eqnarray*}$$ Since there is a single shopper per variety and no means of transferring consumption across shoppers or across time, a household cannot improve on these allocations after the realization of its consumption outcome |$x_{t}$|⁠. Note that the optimal consumption plan for purchasing variety |$j$| is represented by a CES demand function which is invariant to the type of shopper or the match with a specific retailer/location; the number of consumption units purchased by the shopper will depend only on the price draw (high or low). Finally, total consumption is characterized by the standard Euler equation |$1=\beta R_{t}E_{t}\left(\frac{u^{\prime}\left(c_{t+1}\right)}{u^{\prime}\left(c_{t}\right)}\frac{P_{t}}{P_{t+1}}\right)$|⁠. 5.2.7. Shopping-time decision The first-order condition for the cut-off |$z_{t}^{\ast}$| is: $$\begin{eqnarray} &&0= u^{\prime}(C_{t})\frac{\theta}{\theta-1}G^{\prime}(z_{t}^{\ast})\left(C_{t}\right)^{\frac{1}{\theta}}\nonumber\\ &&\qquad{}\left[f\gamma_{t}\left(c_{t}^{L}\right)^{1-\frac{1}{\theta}}+(1-f\gamma_{t})\left(c_{t}^{H}\right)^{1-\frac{1}{\theta}}-\sum_{\mathcal{L}\setminus l^{\ast}}\left(\widetilde{\gamma}_{t}\left(\widetilde{c}_{t}^{L}\right)^{1-\frac{1}{\theta}}+(1-\widetilde{\gamma}_{t})\left(\widetilde{c}_{t}^{H}\right)^{1-\frac{1}{\theta}}\right)\right]\nonumber \\ && - \frac{u^{\prime}(C_{t})}{P_{t}}\left\{ W_{t}^{F}z_{t}^{\ast}G^{\prime}(z_{t}^{\ast})+G^{\prime}(z_{t}^{\ast})\left[f\gamma_{t}p_{t}^{L}c_{t}^{L}+(1-f\gamma_{t})p_{t}^{H}c_{t}^{H}-\sum_{\mathcal{L}\setminus l^{\ast}}\left(\widetilde{\gamma}_{t}\widetilde{p}_{t}^{L}\widetilde{c}_{t}^{L}+(1-\widetilde{\gamma}_{t})\widetilde{p}_{t}^{H}\widetilde{c}_{t}^{H}\right)\right]\right\}.\nonumber\\ \label{eq: foc time} \end{eqnarray}$$(8) The first row gives the additional utility of consumption from marginally increasing the cut-off |$z_{t}^{\ast}$|⁠: a higher cut-off increases the probability that the shopper of variety |$j$| will be a bargain hunter and become matched with a lower-priced brand. On the other hand, a lower expected price implies higher nominal expenditures under standard values of the elasticity of substitution, and a higher cut-off implies higher expected costs from bargain hunting. These terms are captured by the second row of (8). We can simplify (8) by dividing it through by |$u^{\prime}(c_{t})G^{\prime}(z_{t}^{\ast})$|⁠, and applying demand equations (7); this simplified condition is $$\begin{equation} \frac{\Delta x_{t}}{z_{t}^{\ast}}=\frac{W_{t}^{F}}{P_{t}}\,,\label{eq:BH constraint 1} \end{equation}$$(9) where the real return on shopping is denoted by |$\Delta x_{t}\equiv\frac{1}{\theta-1}\left[\left(f\gamma_{t}p_{t}^{L}c_{t}^{L}+(1-f\gamma_{t})p_{t}^{H}c_{t}^{H}\right)\right.$||$\left.-\sum_{\mathcal{L}\setminus l^{\ast}}\left(\widetilde{\gamma}_{t}\widetilde{p}_{t}^{L}\widetilde{c}_{t}^{L}+(1-\widetilde{\gamma}_{t})\widetilde{p}_{t}^{H}\widetilde{c}_{t}^{H}\right)\right]/P_{t}$|⁠. According to condition (9), households choose their shopping time to equate the marginal rate of transformation of time for real consumption, |$\frac{\Delta x_{t}}{z_{t}^{\ast}}$|⁠, to the price of time, |$\frac{W_{t}^{F}}{P_{t}}$|⁠. The household’s optimal shopping time increases with real return on shopping, which depends on the use and magnitude of sales, and decreases with the real price of time.27 The endogeneity of the shopping effort is the crucial difference from Guimaraes and Sheedy (2011), who assume a constant fraction of bargain hunters. We demonstrate below that the interaction of households’ search for lower prices and retailers’ decisions for setting those prices underpins the mechanism that helps account for the behaviour of sales documented in the empirical part of the paper. 5.2.8. Union’s labour supply and wage-setting decisions Each union consists of all households with labour type |$u$|⁠. It supplies labour services |$L_{t}$| in a monopolistically competitive labour market.28 Labour services can be aggregated over the set of union types |$\mathcal{U}$| into a final labour service |$L_{t}^{F}$|⁠, according to |$L_{t}^{F}=\left\{ \sum_{\mathcal{U}}L_{t}^{1-\frac{1}{\vartheta}}\right\} ^{\frac{\vartheta}{\vartheta-1}}$|⁠, where |$\vartheta$| is the elasticity of substitution across labour services. Each union sets wages |$W_{t}$| for its services, and accordingly faces the demand |$L_{t}=\left(\frac{W_{t}}{W_{t}^{F}}\right)^{-\vartheta}N_{t}$| from firms, where |$N_{t}$| is the demand for final labour service and |$W_{t}^{F}=\left\{ \sum_{\mathcal{U}}W_{t}^{1-\vartheta}\right\} ^{\frac{1}{1-\vartheta}}$| is the aggregate wage. We assume unions set wages according to Taylor contracts, with wages fixed for |$N_{W}$| periods. Contracts are perfectly staggered across unions, i.e., in every period a fraction |$1/N_{W}$| of unions reset their wages. Union |$u$| supplies all services demanded at wage |$W_{t}$|⁠. The first-order condition for the union’s reset wage gives a standard expression elaborated in the Model Appendix. 5.3. Production and pricing There are two types of firms: intermediate good producers and retailers. 5.3.1. Intermediate input producers A continuum of competitive intermediate good firms own and invest in capital |$K_{t}$|⁠, acquire final labour service |$N_{t}$| and produce homogeneous good |$Y_{t}$| using a Cobb–Douglas technology $$\begin{equation} Y_{t}=a_{t}N_{t}^{1-\chi}K_{t}^{\chi}\,,\label{eq:technology inter} \end{equation}$$(10) where |$a_{t}$| is total factor productivity in period |$t$|⁠, following an AR(1) process in logs, |$\ln a_{t}=\rho_{a}\ln a_{t-1}+\epsilon_{at},$| with normal i.i.d. innovations |$\epsilon_{at}$| with mean |$0$| and standard deviation |$\sigma_{a}$|⁠. The homogeneous good is sold at the competitive price |$P_{t}^{I}$| to other intermediate good firms as investment good, and to retail firms as the sole input in their production of consumption varieties. 5.3.2. Retailers The retail firm selling brands of variety |$j$| in location |$l^{*}$| is endowed with a linear production technology that converts |$Y_{t}$| units of homogeneous intermediate input into |$y_{t}$| units of perfectly substitutable brands of variety |$j$|⁠: |$y_{t}=Y_{t}$|⁠. This technology implies that the retailer’s marginal cost of production is equal to the price of the intermediate input, |$P_{t}^{I}.$| Let us denote by |$\alpha_{t}^{B}$| the mass of bargain hunters visiting their local shopping mall in location |$l^{*}$|⁠. They belong to local households who are informed about the prices posted and draw a shopping cost below the cut-off level. Specifically, |$\alpha_{t}^{B}$| is defined as $$\begin{equation} \alpha_{t}^{B}=\int_{0}^{1}G(z_{t}^{\ast}(i))di\,.\label{eq: alphab} \end{equation}$$(11) We can substitute for the cut-off |$z_{t}^{\ast}(i)$| using the household’s first-order condition (9) and then plugging |$c_{t}^{L}(i)$| and |$c_{t}^{H}(i)$| from demand equations (7). This yields an expression for |$\alpha_{t}^{B}$| as a function of the prices posted by the retailer of the relevant variety in location |$l^{*}$| (⁠|$p_{t}^{L}$|⁠, |$p_{t}^{H}$|⁠, and |$\gamma_{t}$|⁠): $$\begin{eqnarray} \alpha_{t}^{B}= & & \int G\left(\frac{\left(W_{t}^{f}\right)^{-1}}{\theta-1}\left[\left(f\gamma_{t}p_{t}^{L}\left(\frac{p_{t}^{L}}{P_{t}}\right)^{-\theta}C_{t}+(1-f\gamma_{t})p_{t}^{H}\left(\frac{p_{t}^{H}}{P_{t}}\right)^{-\theta}C_{t}\right)\right.\right.\nonumber \\ & & \left.\left.-\sum_{\mathcal{L}\setminus l^{\ast}}\left(\widetilde{\gamma}_{t}\widetilde{p}_{t}^{L}\widetilde{c}_{t}^{L}(i)+(1-\widetilde{\gamma}_{t})\widetilde{p}_{t}^{H}\widetilde{c}_{t}^{H}(i)\right)\right]\right)di\,.\label{eq: fraction bh 2-1}\\ \equiv & & \alpha^{B}\left(p_{t}^{L},p_{t}^{H},\gamma_{t}\right).\nonumber \end{eqnarray}$$(12) where the function |$\alpha^{B}\left(p_{t}^{L},p_{t}^{H},\gamma_{t}\right)$| denotes the right-hand side of (12). Equation (12) implies that the mass of bargain hunters visiting the retailer of a specific variety in location |$l^{\ast}$| is increasing in |$\gamma_{t}$| and decreasing in |$p_{t}^{L}$| and |$p_{t}^{H}$|⁠. Through its pricing decision, the firm can attract local shoppers who are informed about its prices. All other shoppers are by definition random shoppers for whom |$l^{\ast}$| is the randomly assigned location. As a result, the retailer takes the mass of random shoppers coming to its location as given. We denote this mass by |$\alpha_{t}^{R}$|⁠. 5.3.3. Pricing decision Retailers face Taylor (1980) price adjustment constraints for the high price: each keeps its price fixed for |$N_{P}$| periods. Such price contracts are evenly staggered across varieties so that in every period a measure |$1/N_{P}$| of retailers resets their prices. Since firm’s price choices will vary with price duration, |$k=0,...N_{P},$| we will let |$p_{t-k,t}^{L}$|⁠, |$p_{t-k,t}^{H}$| , |$\gamma_{t-k,t}$| denote prices and the fraction of discounts in period |$t$| for the retailer that reset its regular prices in period |$t-k$|⁠. Discounted prices are flexible, and posting |$\gamma$| discounts entails a period cost of |$\kappa\gamma$| units of final labour service. We denote the measure of transactions at the sale price as |$n_{t-k,t}^{L}\equiv\left(\alpha_{t-k,t}^{R}+\alpha_{t-k,t}^{B}f\right)\gamma_{t-k,t}$|⁠, and the mass of transactions at the regular price as |$n_{t-k,t}^{H}\equiv\alpha_{t-k,t}^{R}\left(1-\gamma_{t-k,t}\right)+\alpha_{t-k,t}^{B}\left(1-f\gamma_{t-k,t}\right)$|⁠. A retail firm resetting its regular price in period |$t$| chooses the sequences of its two consumption price points |$p_{t,t+k}^{H}$| and |$p_{t,t+k}^{L}$|⁠; the fraction of price discounts |$\gamma_{t,t+k}$|⁠; the fraction of bargain hunters visiting its location, |$\alpha_{t,t+k}^{B}$|⁠; intermediate inputs |$Y_{t,t+k}$|⁠; and output levels |$y_{t,t+k}$| to maximize the discounted flow of profits over the duration of its regular price: $$\begin{eqnarray*} E_{t}\sum_{\tau=t}^{t+N_{P}-1}\left\{ \beta^{t}\frac{u^{\prime}\left(C_{\tau}\right)}{P_{\tau}}\cdot\left[n_{t,\tau}^{H}p_{t,\tau}^{H}c_{t,\tau}^{H}+n_{t,\tau}^{L}p_{t,\tau}^{L}c_{t,\tau}^{L}-P_{\tau}^{I}Y_{t,\tau}-\kappa W_{\tau}^{f}\gamma_{t,\tau}\right]\right\} \end{eqnarray*}$$ subject to the demand constraints (7), the constraint on the measure of bargain hunters in location |$l^{*}$| (12), the production technology $$n_{t,\tau}^{H}c_{t,\tau}^{H}+n_{t,\tau}^{L}c_{t,\tau}^{L}\leq Y_{t,\tau}\,,$$ and constraints on regular price adjustments, |$p_{t,t}^{H}=p_{t,t+1}^{H}=...=p_{t,t+N_{P}-1}^{H}.$| 5.3.4. First-order conditions The retailer’s first-order conditions for prices in period |$t$|⁠, |$p_{t-k,t}^{H}$|⁠, |$p_{t-k,t}^{L}$| and |$\gamma_{t-k,t}$|⁠, will include partial derivatives of the function |$\alpha^{B}\left(p_{t-k,t}^{L},p_{t-k,t}^{H},\gamma_{t-k,t}\right)$| to reflect the influence of the retailer’s pricing on its fraction of bargain hunters. For the firm in period |$t$| that set its regular price |$k$| periods ago, where |$k=0,...,N_{P}-1,$| denote the semi-elasticity of the fraction of bargain hunters with respect to the discounted price by |$\varepsilon_{t-k,t}^{B,L}\equiv\frac{\partial\alpha^{B}\left(p_{t-k,t}^{L},p_{t-k,t}^{H},\gamma_{t-k,t}\right)}{\partial\ln p_{t-k,t}^{L}}$|⁠. The first-order condition for the discounted price can then be written as follows $$\begin{equation} p_{t-k,t}^{L}=\frac{\theta}{\theta-1}P_{t}^{I}\left(\frac{1}{1+|\varepsilon_{t-k,t}^{B,L}|\Delta_{t-k,t}^{L}}\right)\,,\label{eq: sm PL-1} \end{equation}$$(13) where the factor |$\Delta_{t-k,t}^{L}>0$| depends on the measure of transactions at a discounted price |$n_{t-k,t}^{L}$| and the profits from sales per bargain hunter. Intuitively, a lower (higher) discount price makes it more (less) worthwhile for households to pay the cost |$z$| and send more bargain hunters to this retailer, effectively making demand more elastic. A more elastic demand is captured by the term in parentheses in condition (13), and it implies that the discounted price is below the single-good monopoly price |$p_{t-k,t}^{L}<\frac{\theta}{\theta-1}P_{t}^{I}.$| Note that the retailer’s cost may depend on the number of periods until the next regular price reset, which will have an effect on both |$p_{t-k,t}^{L}$| and |$\gamma_{t-k,t}$|⁠, while |$p_{t-k,t}^{H}$| is constrained. Hence, discounts provide retailers with an additional margin of price adjustment that they can use to partially offset sticky regular prices. The first-order condition for the reset regular price |$p_{t,t}^{H}$| is different from (13) in two respects. First, it reflects the effects of price-adjustment constraints by including the summations over periods |$t$| to |$t+N_{P}-1$|⁠: $$\begin{equation} p_{t,t}^{H}=\frac{\theta}{\theta-1}\frac{E_{t}\sum_{\tau=t}^{t+N_{P}-1}\beta^{\tau}\left(u^{\prime}\left(C_{\tau}\right)/P_{\tau}\right)P_{\tau}^{\theta}C_{\tau}\cdot n_{t,\tau}^{H}P_{\tau}^{I}}{E_{t}\sum_{\tau=t}^{t+N_{P}-1}\beta^{\tau}\left(u^{\prime}\left(C_{\tau}\right)/P_{\tau}\right)P_{\tau}^{\theta}C_{\tau}\cdot n_{t,\tau}^{H}\left(1+|\varepsilon_{t,\tau}^{B,H}|\Delta_{t,\tau}^{H}\right)}\,,\label{eq: PH0} \end{equation}$$(14) where |$\varepsilon_{t,\tau}^{B,H}\equiv\frac{\partial\alpha^{B}\left(p_{t,\tau}^{L},p_{t,\tau}^{H},\gamma_{t,\tau}\right)}{\partial\ln p_{t,\tau}^{H}}$| is the semi-elasticity of the fraction of bargain hunters with respect to the regular price, and the factor |$\Delta_{t,\tau}^{H}>0$| depends on the measure of transactions at the regular price |$n_{t,\tau}^{H}$|⁠. Second, like the discounted price, the regular price also attracts bargain hunters and increases demand elasticity, but to a smaller degree: a 1|${\$}$| lower discounted price is worth more to households than a 1|${\$}$| lower regular price, since a bargain hunter is |$f$| times more likely to draw a discounted price than a random shopper. We can show that the resulting regular price is above the discount price, but below the single-good monopoly price: |$p_{t-k,t}^{L}