TY - JOUR AU - Reynaert,, Mathias AB - Abstract This article studies the introduction of an EU-wide emission standard on the automobile market. Using panel data from 1998 to 2011, I find that firms decreased emission ratings by 14%. Firms use technology adoption and gaming of emission tests to decrease emissions, rather than shifting the sales mix or downsizing. I find that the standard missed its emission target, and from estimating a structural model, I find that the standard was not welfare improving. The political environment in the EU shaped the design and weak enforcement and resulted in firms’ choices for abatement by technology adoption and gaming. 1. Introduction Transportation accounts for 20% of global greenhouse gas emissions and policymakers are taking up the challenge to reduce the use of polluting petroleum liquids. Emission standards are one of the primary policy tools used to achieve this goal. This type of regulation sets mandatory limits on average emission rates (or fuel economy) across the fleet. These policies are simple to prescribe and do not explicitly tax consumers or producers. This article studies the introduction of the emission standard in the EU and tries to estimate the welfare effects of the EU policy. The EU regulation aimed to reduce CO|$_{2} $| emissions from passenger cars by 18%. The policy was announced in 2007 and became fully binding from 2015, after a phase-in period that started in 2012. The regulation targets CO|$_{2}$| emissions, which is equivalent to targeting fuel consumption or fuel-efficiency.1 The EU standard is interesting to study for three reasons. First, it is a very demanding standard with a target of 130 g CO|$_{2}$|/km. For comparison, the US standard required only 152 g CO|$_{2}$|/km in 2016. Second, before the standard, the EU had no regulation on CO|$_{2}$| emissions. The introduction of the standard thus allows me to study how the market equilibrium changes with the introduction of an emission standard. Third, the EU standard is an attribute-based regulation (ABR); the policy target not only depends on CO|$_{2}$| emission but also on the attribute vehicle weight. The attribute basing makes the policy target less stringent for firms producing heavier vehicles.2 Understanding the effects of the EU standard is helpful to guide the design of this type of regulation in the future and in other markets across the world. Evaluating the welfare impact of emission standards is not an easy task. Firms can choose between different abatement strategies to comply with a standard, and these strategies have different effects on market equilibrium. The first strategy is to change pricing to shift the sales mix to vehicles with CO|$_{2}$| emissions below the target. I define this strategy as mix-shifting. A second strategy is downsizing, i.e., releasing smaller but more fuel efficient vehicles. A third strategy is technology adoption, i.e., improving the fuel-efficiency of the vehicle fleet. A fourth strategy is gaming, i.e., improving the emissions as measured in official ratings without improving the actual emission on the road. Throughout the article, I refer to official CO|$_{2}$| emissions as the emission ratings that firms report from lab tests and actual CO|$_{2}$| emissions as the emissions that vehicles emit on the road. These strategies change the prices, product attributes, product sets, and market outcomes in different ways. Firms choose the abatement strategy that has the lowest cost while taking into account the strategy chosen by competing firms. Additionally, the design of the policy matters for the costs of different abatement strategies. This article presents a model that accounts for firms’ abatement strategies and the design of the policy to evaluate the EU standard. In the first step, I explain the trend in sales-weighted official CO|$_{2}$| emissions between 1998 and 2011 in the EU market. Knittel (2011) shows that vehicles sold on the US market change between 1980 and 2006 in terms of the amount of attributes that automakers offer relative to fuel economy and interprets this as technological progress. I follow his approach and estimate technological improvements in the trade-off that firms face between emissions and other vehicle characteristics. I find that official emissions reduce by 14% after the policy announcement. This reduction is explained by decreases in official emissions of vehicles, while the attributes and the product set offered by firms do not change, showing no downsizing. The results show that technological progress is twice as fast after the regulatory announcement, in line with the findings of Klier and Linn (2016). Firms respond to emission standards by increasing the speed of technology adoption, at least when we look at the official emission ratings. Reynaert and Sallee (2020) study the fuel-efficiency of thousands of vehicles on the road to find significant gaming in the market. Emission ratings improve on article, but these improvements do not translate to the road. Using these estimates of on-road fuel efficiency, I find that only 30% of the increased technology adoption is measurable on the road so that 70% is due to gaming. The observed decrease in the official emission ratings is so strong that almost all of the firms reached the emission target before it became partly binding in 2012. However, looking at market outcomes before and after the policy is insufficient to find the welfare effects of the policy as we cannot separate the policy from the effects of changes in local regulations and taxes. Many EU member states began changing vehicle taxation after 2007, clearly contributing to the downward trend in emissions.3 Demand, costs, and market fundamentals potentially change in the eight-year gap between the policy announcement and implementation. I resort to a structural model to simulate the impact of the emission standard. The model allows me to single out the impact of the policy and to study how that impact changes when I change the policy design. In the counterfactual, I assume that the product sets of the firms and the product attributes are fixed. I then model heterogeneous consumers making discrete choices between vehicles. The firms have three strategic choices: mix-shifting, technology adoption, and gaming. I study how equilibrium changes with each strategic choice. To simulate the model, I need estimates of the following primitives: preferences and price elasticities, marginal costs, changes in costs from technology adoption, and changes in costs from gaming. To estimate these primitives, I rely on the rich panel data from before the policy announcement when firms’ decisions are not affected. I estimate demand following the framework of Berry et al. (1995) and extend the model to allow for multiple endogenous characteristics: fuel economy, horsepower, and weight in addition to prices. I instrument the endogenous characteristics with variables that use exogenous variation in the competitive environment, the global sales of vehicles, and the manufacturing structure. Given the estimated demand, the first-order conditions of the profit function provide estimates of the marginal costs of vehicles as well as the marginal benefits and costs of supplying fuel consumption (and emissions). The regulation increases the marginal benefit of lowering fuel consumption, as vehicles with lower emissions help the firm attain the standard. To predict how marginal cost increases with technology adoption, I rely on two approaches. First, I use the observed correlation in the data between fuel consumption and marginal cost. Second, I use engineering predictions submitted with the policy proposal, see TNO (2011). In line with recent evidence presented by Whitefoot et al. (2017), these engineering predictions show that fuel consumption is relatively adjustable in the short term with available technology. Given this evidence, I choose to model improvements in fuel consumption as a continuous choice that is made simultaneously with pricing. Finally, I need an estimate for the costs of gaming. The costs of gaming consist of the expected litigation and the cost of emission test falsification. These costs are challenging to estimate, and I rely on the level of gaming from the emission decomposition. The estimated model with multiple strategic decisions on continuous variables is similar to the recent contributions of Fan (2013) and Crawford et al. (2019).4 Given the estimated primitives, I introduce the EU policy in the model and simulate how it impacts the market equilibrium. Increases in costs from technology adoption beyond the willingness to pay for fuel consumption imply that the regulation decreases consumer surplus and profits. Because of the gaming, the reductions in actual |${\rm CO}_2$| emissions are a mere 5% instead of the 18% target. The sum of the value of emission savings and consumer and profit losses is negative so that the regulation reduces welfare. However, when I consider two additional non-targeted welfare effects, I find the emission standard to have a small positive impact. The two additional welfare effects are reductions in other externalities (local pollution, congestion, and accident risk) and correction of consumer undervaluation of fuel economy. I estimate that consumers do not fully take into account future fuel expenses, so when the regulation provides consumers with more fuel-efficient vehicles, this increases their experience utility. The simulation also reveals that when I restrict firms to mix-shifting, the standard has different welfare effects. The total sales and actual emissions sharply decrease at a very high cost for consumers and firms. Next, I study how the design of the regulation induced firms to choose the combination of technology adoption and gaming. I first study the attribute basing which makes the emission target dependent on vehicle weight. Firms selling more lightweight vehicles face a more stringent attribute-based target. I find that attribute basing makes abatement with mix-shifting much more costly because firms have to distort prices more to reach the target. If the regulation has a flat target without attribute basing, firms would opt for mix-shifting and technology adoption. The flat target reaches actual |${\rm CO}_2$| emission reductions of 11%, much closer to the 18% target. Why, then, was the attribute basing introduced? The simulations show that the positions of the governments are in line with the interests of their firms. The attribute basing redistributes the incidence of the regulation between French, Italian, and German producers. Newspaper articles show that French and Italian governments were in favour of regulation without attribute basing, while Germany lobbied for a steep attribute design.5 Additionally, gaming is a product of the political environment. A recent evaluation by the European Parliament (Gieseke and Gerbandy, 2017) has placed responsibility for enforcement failures with the car producing member states. The countries failed to detect and respond to gaming timely. The attribute basing and enforcement failures show the importance of the political environment for the effectiveness of emission standards. The article makes several contributions. First, I show that emission standards can induce technology adoption and gaming by firms. Previous literature does not study the equilibrium effects of the abatement strategies in detail. The literature studying the CAFE standard in the US treats changes in the level of technology as a possible longer-run effect of emission standards and has not focused on the welfare effects of gaming. Second, by estimating a structural model of demand and supply, I show that the incidence and welfare effects of the regulation vary drastically between abatement strategies. Third, the model allows me to study how the design of the regulation affects the outcomes. Attribute basing increased the pressure on firms to adopt technology, and weak enforcement allowed for gaming so that the policy missed its emission reduction target. These contributions show that it is crucial to take the supply responses carefully into account when evaluating and designing emission standards. Finally, this is the first article providing a detailed study of the EU regulation and its impacts on market outcomes. 1.1. Related literature The framework in this article builds on the existing work of Knittel (2011), Jacobsen (2013), and Reynaert and Sallee (2020). The emission decomposition follows the estimation in Knittel (2011), but I find that the speed of technology adoption changes when the policy is announced. Jacobsen (2013) incorporates heterogeneous responses from both consumers and producers in a structural model to evaluate the US CAFE standard. In an extension Jacobsen (2013) also considers technology adoption using the framework of Austin and Dinan (2005) in which firms respond to an emission standard by changing both prices and technology. While Jacobsen (2013) finds that technology adoption limits the welfare losses of standards, I show that technology adoption could lead to welfare losses or gains depending on the cost-effectiveness of the technology relative to consumers willingness to pay for fuel consumption.6 My analysis contributes by considering an equilibrium model where firms choose between the compliance options of mix-shifting, technology adoption, and gaming. Reynaert and Sallee (2020) estimate the amount of gaming in the EU market. I use these on-road fuel efficiency estimates to disentangle official from actual emissions. I also use the framework to estimate the effects of gaming on consumer surplus which depend on consumer awareness of gaming. Here, I embed the interaction between choice and gaming in the full equilibrium model with other abatement strategies, and I focus on overall welfare rather than consumer welfare. This article adds to a body of literature that studies policies targeting vehicle emissions, reviewed in Anderson and Sallee (2016). Holland et al. (2009) show that none of the welfare effects of emission standards are theoretically determined. A standard might decrease or increase emissions from new vehicles, depending on the distribution of the price elasticities of products below and above the emission target. The welfare effects of standards become even more uncertain when we consider the variety of different abatement strategies. The empirical literature on emission standards has focused on the US CAFE standard. Goldberg (1998) was the first to consider the effect of standards on price setting and the composition of the vehicle fleet. Anderson and Sallee (2011) use a loophole in the regulation to show that the standard is hardly binding in recent years. Jacobsen (2013) finds that the US CAFE standard imposes a substantial shadow cost on domestic firms. Both Klier and Linn (2012) and Whitefoot et al. (2017) evaluate the welfare effects of emission standards while introducing endogenous product characteristics in the model and allowing firms to change vehicle characteristics. Both of these papers assume that the level of technology is fixed and consider the optimization of product offerings on a fixed trade-off function between emissions and attributes. I allow the trade-off relation to change but impose that improvements must reduce fuel consumption, in line with the empirical evidence in Europe. Ito and Sallee (2018) and Whitefoot and Skerlos (2012) discuss the economic effects of attribute-based regulations. The analysis here is complementary as I study different effects of attribute basing, i.e., the cost of different abatement strategies and the political economy behind the attribute basing. Recent work has considered additional margins of the policy. Jacobsen and van Benthem (2015) study the effect of emission standards on vehicle scrap rates. Durrmeyer and Samano (2018) compare a standard with a rebate policy that explicitly subsidizes and taxes emissions above and below the target. Bento et al. (2017) focus on the effect of the fuel standard on the dispersion in vehicle weight and its effect on accidents.7 The article is structured as follows. Section 2.1 describes the policy and available data. Section 3 decomposes the changes in emissions in the EU automobile market between 2007 and 2011. Section 4 presents the emission standard in a model of supply and demand and discusses the possible effects of the different abatement strategies. Section 5 presents the estimation results. Section 6 presents the results of policy simulations, and Section 7 concludes. 2. The EU emission standard and data 2.1. The EU emission standard The European regulation on emission standards for new passenger cars, Regulation (EC) No. 443/2009, sets a mandatory fleet average of |$\kappa =$|130 grams CO|$_{2}$| per kilometre. Denoting the sales of each product j by |$q_{j}$| and the emissions of each product by |$e_{j}$|⁠, the target for a firm is as follows: $$ \begin{eqnarray} \frac{\sum_{j\epsilon fleet}q_{j}(e_{j}-f(w_{j}))}{\sum_{j\epsilon fleet}q_{j}} &\leq &130. \end{eqnarray} $$(1) The target binds over each producer’s fleet of new vehicles sold in a calendar year. The trading of excess emissions between producers is not allowed.8 The attribute basing |$f(w_{jm})=a(w_{j}-w_{0})$| adjusts the emissions of each vehicle by the distance in the vehicle weight |$w_{j}$| from a shifting point |$w_{0}$| (the pivotal weight point). The shifting point |$w_{0}$| is a mass of 1370 kg and the difference in weight from that point is multiplied by |$a=0.046$|⁠.9Figure 1 plots the target and the distance from the target for each producer in 2007 and 2011. When producers exceed the standard, they have to pay premiums for excess emissions. The premium is € 5 per unit sold for the first excess g/km and increases to € 95 per unit above 134 g/km. A manufacturer obtaining a sales-weighted emission of 146 g/km, the average in 2007, would face a significant penalty of € 1,280 per vehicle (against an average sales price of € 22,250). The regulation was proposed by the European Commission in 2007 and became law in 2009. Deters (2010) gives an overview of the full legislative process and political background. In 2012, 65% of manufacturer’s sales had to comply with the emission standard. This share rose to 75% in 2013 and 80% in 2014, and the standard was fully binding from 2015 onward. I do not model the phase-in period. Every firm succeeded in reaching the full target by 2014. Figure 1 Open in new tabDownload slide Compliance of firms in 2007 and 2011 The starting point of each arrow gives the sales-weighted CO|$_{2}$| and mass for each producer in 2007. The end of each arrow gives the same point in 2011. The dashed diagonal line is the regulation, which binds in 2015. Figure 1 Open in new tabDownload slide Compliance of firms in 2007 and 2011 The starting point of each arrow gives the sales-weighted CO|$_{2}$| and mass for each producer in 2007. The end of each arrow gives the same point in 2011. The dashed diagonal line is the regulation, which binds in 2015. EU member states heavily debated the specifics of the regulation during the drafting of the law. Lobbying efforts by EU member states, firms, and environmental groups were covered by news outlets; see Footnote 5. France and Italy were strongly in favour of a flat standard. At the same time, Germany wanted an ABR with an upward sloping target function in either weight or footprint (the rectangular area in between the wheels of the vehicle). The German firms BMW, Daimler, and Volkswagen, on average, make heavier vehicles than Fiat (Italian), Renault, and PSA (French). The political agreement was to have an ABR with a slope of |$a=0.046$| that aimed at equalizing compliance efforts between firms. The production of each firm mostly takes place within the home country, and the automobile sector is an important source for employment.10 It is instructive to compare the EU policy with the US CAFE standard since this policy has been the subject of several studies. The CAFE standard came into place in 1978 and after a gradual phase-in has been constant at 27.5 mpg since 1990 (this corresponds to 198 g CO|$_{2}$|/km). From 2009 onward, the CAFE standards are tightened towards 36 mpg in 2016 (this corresponds to 152 g CO|$_{2}$|/km). Contrary to the EU standard, light trucks (SUVs) face a different, less demanding target than passenger cars. Additionally, firms are allowed to trade excess emissions over time and with other firms.11 From 2012 onward, the CAFE standard also has an attribute-based part, i.e., the target varies with the footprint. The EU Commission relied on several studies to support the design of the EU emission standard, see TNO (2011). The policy report only includes possible technology adoptions that should be readily available for the car makers at no fixed or development costs. In designing the regulation, the policymaker clearly had the channel of technology adoption in mind. The document lists which technologies are available and how adoption affects marginal cost.12 The New European Driving Cycle (NEDC) is the procedure to determine official |${\rm CO}_2$| emissions and fuel consumption.13 The procedure takes a single vehicle (the golden vehicle) and optimizes that vehicle for the test. Tape, non-resistant tires, and software referred to as defeat devices, make the engine run in a program specialized for the test. None of these features impact how the consumers experience vehicles on the road, nor do they impact the marginal cost of production. I define gaming as the firm efforts that decrease the official emission ratings but not the actual on-road emissions. The costs of gaming are installing the defeat devices and, more importantly, the potential legal costs and consumer blow-back when gaming is uncovered. When deciding to game, firms will trade off these costs against the benefits of cheap compliance. Since firms have opted to game the regulation, it reveals that firms did not expect these reputation costs to be higher than the costs of other compliance mechanisms. In the fallout of the VW diesel scandal, the EU parliament listed dozens of ongoing lawsuits (see: European Parliament Briefing PE 583.793). In recent years, several other firms have become defendants in claims as it became clear VW was not the only firm to have gamed the EU emission tests. 2.2. Data The main data set is obtained from a market research firm JATO ANALYTICS (2012). It contains sales and product characteristics for each passenger car sold during 1998–2011 in seven European countries: Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Great Britain, The Netherlands, and Spain.14 The characteristics and sales are given for several engine variants of a car model at the country level with a yearly frequency. The country is the geographical market. A model is defined as a brand/model name/body type combination (e.g. Volkswagen Golf Hatchback).15 The engine variants differ in fuel type (gasoline or diesel) and engine performance. Accounting for fuel type is important in the EU market, as diesel variants have a considerable market share (56% in 2011) and the emissions of diesel variants are lower; a diesel engine emits approximately 20% less C0|$_{2}$|⁠.16 Sales are defined as new vehicle registrations in each of the countries. The prices are the suggested retail prices (including registration taxes and VAT, as obtained from the European Automobile Association). The product characteristics give information on the vehicle size (footprint defined as length by width, weight, and height) and engine performance (horsepower and displacement). The data also contains information on fuel consumption (litres per 100 km and CO|$_{2}$| emissions per km). These numbers are the official consumption ratings obtained from the New European Driving Cycle (NEDC), a standardized driving cycle to assess the emission levels of car engines. The cycle simulates both urban and highway driving patterns and excludes the use of auxiliary features, such as air conditioning. Real-world emissions thus differentiate from these test values. Reynaert and Sallee (2020), using data from TravelCardNV (2015), develop a measure of on-road emissions and show that reductions in the official CO|$_{2}$| ratings do not fully translate into actual savings. Carmakers can calibrate engines with defeat devices and specific software so that they perform much better on the test. Gaming is defined as improvements that do not translate to the road. I use the measure of on-road emissions in the analysis to disentangle technology adoption from gaming.17 This information is available for a limited sample of vehicles. Next, I use production data from PwC Autofacts (2012) that contain the country and plant of production for each model. I match this with a producer price index and a unit labour cost measure obtained from the OECD. Finally, I use the data on fuel prices, unit labour costs, GDP/capita, population (from Datastream International (2012)), and the number of households in each country (from Eurostat (2012)), to construct the fuel costs for consumers, real prices, and the number of potential buyers in each year. To reduce the size of the data, I leave out firms, brands, and models with very low sales. The analysis will focus on the largest producers and their bestselling brands on the EU market. The included firms are BMW, Daimler, Fiat, Ford, General Motors, PSA, Renault, and Volkswagen. I treat the largest Asian car makers, Honda, Hyundai, Mitsubishi, Nissan, Suzuki, and Toyota, as one decision-maker.18 The list of excluded brands and a detailed description of the data manipulations are in Supplementary Appendix A1. In total, I keep 40,239 market/year/model/engine variants in 98 year/countries, or approximately 400 model engine variants per market. The final data contains 80% of the total reported sales in the sample. Throughout the article, I split the dataset over time and markets in several ways. In Section 3, I collapse the data towards a unique model engine variant in each year and leave out the variation over markets. I use these data to make statements on the evolution of the supply of engine characteristics in response to the policy and contains 14,444 unique observations. To estimate the structural model, I rely only on data before the policy announcement and use the years 1998–2007. This exploits 30,000 year/market/model-engine observations. I use the data from the year 2007 as the benchmark for the simulations in Section 6. 2.3. Summary statistics Figure 1 plots each producer’s distance from the emission standard in 2007 and 2011. Each firm needs to move below the dotted line, which presents the attribute-based emission standard. In 2007, each firm was far above the target and had the following three options to reach the standard: reduce emissions, increase vehicle weight, or combine both. The Asian firms, BMW, Daimler, and Ford, decrease weight and reduce emissions. Volkswagen reduces emissions while keeping weight constant. Fiat, GM, PSA, and Renault all increase the average weight slightly while decreasing emissions sharply. I observe a sharp downward trend in emissions towards the standard for all firms. The decrease in emissions is so strong that most of the firms comply with the emission standard four years before it is fully binding.19Table 1 shows the change in the sales-weighted vehicle characteristics between 2007 and 2011. CO|$_{2}$| emissions decrease by 14% while other characteristics grow moderately. In Supplementary Appendix Figure A1, I plot the sales-weighted characteristics over time from 1998 to 2011 for the EU and the US. The most remarkable trend in the EU is the evolution of CO|$_{2}$| emissions. Sales-weighted emissions are constant until 2002, decline approximately 6% until 2007, and then plunge by 14% in the last four years of the sample. This shift coincides with the announcement of the emission standard by the European Commission. In the U.S., emissions decline 3% between 2007 and 2009, but then, in contrast to the EU, emissions remain constant at 90% of the 1998 level. Table 1. Sales-weighted vehicle characteristics in 2007 and 2011 Characteristics . 2007 . 2011 . % Change . CO|$_{2}$| (in g/km) 147 126 -14.3 Horsepower (in kW) 77 80 3.9 Footprint (in m|$^{2}$|⁠) 7.2 7.4 2.8 Weight (in kg) 1271 1280 0.7 Diesel 56% 56% 0.0 Characteristics . 2007 . 2011 . % Change . CO|$_{2}$| (in g/km) 147 126 -14.3 Horsepower (in kW) 77 80 3.9 Footprint (in m|$^{2}$|⁠) 7.2 7.4 2.8 Weight (in kg) 1271 1280 0.7 Diesel 56% 56% 0.0 The table presents the sales-weighted vehicle characteristics in the EU in 2007 and 2011. Open in new tab Table 1. Sales-weighted vehicle characteristics in 2007 and 2011 Characteristics . 2007 . 2011 . % Change . CO|$_{2}$| (in g/km) 147 126 -14.3 Horsepower (in kW) 77 80 3.9 Footprint (in m|$^{2}$|⁠) 7.2 7.4 2.8 Weight (in kg) 1271 1280 0.7 Diesel 56% 56% 0.0 Characteristics . 2007 . 2011 . % Change . CO|$_{2}$| (in g/km) 147 126 -14.3 Horsepower (in kW) 77 80 3.9 Footprint (in m|$^{2}$|⁠) 7.2 7.4 2.8 Weight (in kg) 1271 1280 0.7 Diesel 56% 56% 0.0 The table presents the sales-weighted vehicle characteristics in the EU in 2007 and 2011. Open in new tab 3. Market response to the EU emission standard In this section, I decompose the decrease in carbon emissions in the EU vehicle market. The goal of the decomposition is to measure the extent to which different abatement strategies can explain the drop in emissions after the policy announcement. To do this, I estimate a trade-off relation between emissions and other vehicle characteristics. I decompose the shifts over time in the correlation between characteristics and official emissions into changes in technology and changes in the composition of the vehicle fleet. I also investigate to what extent technological change translates to the road by comparing actual with official emissions. 3.1. Estimation of trade-off and technology parameters Following Knittel (2011), I estimate the following regression: $$ \begin{equation} \log (e_{jy})=\zeta_{y}+ \log (x_{jy})\eta+\epsilon_{jy}, \label{level} \end{equation} $$(2) where |$e_{jy}$| are emissions, the technology parameter |$\zeta _{y}$| is a year fixed effect, |$x_{jy}$| are characteristics, |$\eta$| trade off parameters denoting how emissions change with characteristics and |$\epsilon_{jy}$| is an error term.20 The technology parameter captures shifts over time in the trade-off between emissions and characteristics. When the trade-off parameters |$\eta $| are constant over time, technology |$\zeta_{y}$| is input neutral as it enters multiplicative in levels.21 I include vehicle model fixed effects such that the identifying variation comes from different engine options within the same model. I assume the remaining unobservable |$\epsilon_{jy}$| to be i.i.d. The unobserved error comes from variation in unobserved attributes of engine versions within a model name, such as torque or the valve mechanism. These unobserved engine attributes might correlate with explanatory variables, so that |$\eta$| cannot be interpreted as a causal relationship between the characteristics and emissions. The goal of estimating (2) is to see changes in emissions over time while controlling for the correlation between emissions and other characteristics. The estimation of (2) is useful because it reveals the abatement strategies that firms resort to without relying on a structural model. In Figure 1, I show how emissions starkly decreased after the regulatory announcement. If firms choose to alter the sales mix or to downsize, then the part of the emissions that is explained by characteristics |$x_{jy}$| should decrease over time. With mix-shifting and downsizing, firms would sell more small and low performing cars. In contrast, when firms choose to implement technology, we should see shifts in the technology parameters |$\zeta_{y}$| over time. As discussed above, firms gaming the test is a concern. This is a concern when estimating (2), as the left-hand-side variable is the official emission rating obtained from the regulator. To test the extent to which emissions on the road change, I also estimate (2) using a measure of actual emissions as the left-hand-side variable. I use the actual emissions constructed in Reynaert and Sallee (2020). Looking at actual emissions allows me to test if the technological improvements revealed in the official data translate to on-road measures. I now present estimates of the technology parameters in Table 2 and the decomposition of emissions over time in Table 3. I discuss the trade-off parameters and robustness in Supplementary Appendix A2, Table A2 and Table A3. Table 2. Technological progress estimates . Model 1 . Model 2 . Model 3 . Model 4 . Model 5 . . Official ratings . Actual ratings . . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . 1999 -0.5 0.8 -1.4 0.1 -1.7 1.4 -0.9 0.5 -1.2 0.1 2000 1.9 0.6 2.4 0.1 1.7 0.9 -1.5 0.2 -1.5 0.1 2001 -1.5 0.4 -2.2 0.2 -1.4 0.9 -1.2 0.2 -1.7 0.1 2002 -1.3 0.4 -1.5 0.2 -1.5 0.6 -0.9 0.3 -0.8 0.1 2003 -1.5 0.3 -1.9 0.2 -0.8 0.3 -0.5 0.2 -0.5 0.1 2004 -1.8 0.5 -2.1 0.2 -1.4 0.7 -0.7 0.3 -0.9 0.2 2005 -1.5 0.3 -1.9 0.2 -0.9 0.2 -0.2 0.2 -0.1 0.1 2006 -1.3 0.3 -1.7 0.1 -1.1 0.5 -0.4 0.2 -0.4 0.1 2007 -1.4 0.6 -2.2 0.1 -0.9 0.9 -0.2 0.5 -0.5 0.1 2008 -2.7 0.4 -3.1 0.1 -2.2 0.8 -0.9 0.4 -0.9 0.0 2009 -3.0 0.6 -3.6 0.1 -3.2 1.0 -1.4 0.5 -1.4 0.1 2010 -4.3 0.7 -4.7 0.1 -5.5 1.6 -2.5 0.5 -1.8 0.0 2011 -3.3 0.4 -4.5 0.1 -3.2 1.1 -1.3 0.6 -1.9 0.1 Difference in technology growth 2011–2007 and 2007–1998 Difference 2.3 0.5 2.42 0.07 2.6 0.9 0.8 0.3 0.65 0.08 . Model 1 . Model 2 . Model 3 . Model 4 . Model 5 . . Official ratings . Actual ratings . . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . 1999 -0.5 0.8 -1.4 0.1 -1.7 1.4 -0.9 0.5 -1.2 0.1 2000 1.9 0.6 2.4 0.1 1.7 0.9 -1.5 0.2 -1.5 0.1 2001 -1.5 0.4 -2.2 0.2 -1.4 0.9 -1.2 0.2 -1.7 0.1 2002 -1.3 0.4 -1.5 0.2 -1.5 0.6 -0.9 0.3 -0.8 0.1 2003 -1.5 0.3 -1.9 0.2 -0.8 0.3 -0.5 0.2 -0.5 0.1 2004 -1.8 0.5 -2.1 0.2 -1.4 0.7 -0.7 0.3 -0.9 0.2 2005 -1.5 0.3 -1.9 0.2 -0.9 0.2 -0.2 0.2 -0.1 0.1 2006 -1.3 0.3 -1.7 0.1 -1.1 0.5 -0.4 0.2 -0.4 0.1 2007 -1.4 0.6 -2.2 0.1 -0.9 0.9 -0.2 0.5 -0.5 0.1 2008 -2.7 0.4 -3.1 0.1 -2.2 0.8 -0.9 0.4 -0.9 0.0 2009 -3.0 0.6 -3.6 0.1 -3.2 1.0 -1.4 0.5 -1.4 0.1 2010 -4.3 0.7 -4.7 0.1 -5.5 1.6 -2.5 0.5 -1.8 0.0 2011 -3.3 0.4 -4.5 0.1 -3.2 1.1 -1.3 0.6 -1.9 0.1 Difference in technology growth 2011–2007 and 2007–1998 Difference 2.3 0.5 2.42 0.07 2.6 0.9 0.8 0.3 0.65 0.08 The table gives the yearly percentage change in emissions due to technological improvements obtained from differencing the year fixed effects in (2). The standard errors are computed with the Delta method. Years after the policy announcement are shaded. Model 2 and Model 5 report the average of firm-specific trends, Supplementary Appendix Table A4 reports firm-level estimates. Open in new tab Table 2. Technological progress estimates . Model 1 . Model 2 . Model 3 . Model 4 . Model 5 . . Official ratings . Actual ratings . . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . 1999 -0.5 0.8 -1.4 0.1 -1.7 1.4 -0.9 0.5 -1.2 0.1 2000 1.9 0.6 2.4 0.1 1.7 0.9 -1.5 0.2 -1.5 0.1 2001 -1.5 0.4 -2.2 0.2 -1.4 0.9 -1.2 0.2 -1.7 0.1 2002 -1.3 0.4 -1.5 0.2 -1.5 0.6 -0.9 0.3 -0.8 0.1 2003 -1.5 0.3 -1.9 0.2 -0.8 0.3 -0.5 0.2 -0.5 0.1 2004 -1.8 0.5 -2.1 0.2 -1.4 0.7 -0.7 0.3 -0.9 0.2 2005 -1.5 0.3 -1.9 0.2 -0.9 0.2 -0.2 0.2 -0.1 0.1 2006 -1.3 0.3 -1.7 0.1 -1.1 0.5 -0.4 0.2 -0.4 0.1 2007 -1.4 0.6 -2.2 0.1 -0.9 0.9 -0.2 0.5 -0.5 0.1 2008 -2.7 0.4 -3.1 0.1 -2.2 0.8 -0.9 0.4 -0.9 0.0 2009 -3.0 0.6 -3.6 0.1 -3.2 1.0 -1.4 0.5 -1.4 0.1 2010 -4.3 0.7 -4.7 0.1 -5.5 1.6 -2.5 0.5 -1.8 0.0 2011 -3.3 0.4 -4.5 0.1 -3.2 1.1 -1.3 0.6 -1.9 0.1 Difference in technology growth 2011–2007 and 2007–1998 Difference 2.3 0.5 2.42 0.07 2.6 0.9 0.8 0.3 0.65 0.08 . Model 1 . Model 2 . Model 3 . Model 4 . Model 5 . . Official ratings . Actual ratings . . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . Coef. . St.E. . 1999 -0.5 0.8 -1.4 0.1 -1.7 1.4 -0.9 0.5 -1.2 0.1 2000 1.9 0.6 2.4 0.1 1.7 0.9 -1.5 0.2 -1.5 0.1 2001 -1.5 0.4 -2.2 0.2 -1.4 0.9 -1.2 0.2 -1.7 0.1 2002 -1.3 0.4 -1.5 0.2 -1.5 0.6 -0.9 0.3 -0.8 0.1 2003 -1.5 0.3 -1.9 0.2 -0.8 0.3 -0.5 0.2 -0.5 0.1 2004 -1.8 0.5 -2.1 0.2 -1.4 0.7 -0.7 0.3 -0.9 0.2 2005 -1.5 0.3 -1.9 0.2 -0.9 0.2 -0.2 0.2 -0.1 0.1 2006 -1.3 0.3 -1.7 0.1 -1.1 0.5 -0.4 0.2 -0.4 0.1 2007 -1.4 0.6 -2.2 0.1 -0.9 0.9 -0.2 0.5 -0.5 0.1 2008 -2.7 0.4 -3.1 0.1 -2.2 0.8 -0.9 0.4 -0.9 0.0 2009 -3.0 0.6 -3.6 0.1 -3.2 1.0 -1.4 0.5 -1.4 0.1 2010 -4.3 0.7 -4.7 0.1 -5.5 1.6 -2.5 0.5 -1.8 0.0 2011 -3.3 0.4 -4.5 0.1 -3.2 1.1 -1.3 0.6 -1.9 0.1 Difference in technology growth 2011–2007 and 2007–1998 Difference 2.3 0.5 2.42 0.07 2.6 0.9 0.8 0.3 0.65 0.08 The table gives the yearly percentage change in emissions due to technological improvements obtained from differencing the year fixed effects in (2). The standard errors are computed with the Delta method. Years after the policy announcement are shaded. Model 2 and Model 5 report the average of firm-specific trends, Supplementary Appendix Table A4 reports firm-level estimates. Open in new tab Table 3. Decomposing the decrease in emissions . . All vehicles . Existing models(2007|$\leq )$| . New models (⁠|$>2007$|⁠) . . . No Tech. . Tech. . No Tech. . Tech. . No Tech. . Tech. . . True . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . 1998 169 156 172 156 172 1999 168 156 170 156 170 2000 169 155 171 155 171 2001 167 154 169 154 169 2002 164 154 166 154 166 2003 161 153 162 153 162 2004 158 152 159 152 159 2005 156 152 157 152 157 2006 154 152 155 152 155 2007 151 152 152 152 152 2008 147 152 147 151 147 157 152 2009 142 152 143 152 142 160 150 2010 135 152 136 152 136 154 137 2011 130 152 130 152 130 154 132 . . All vehicles . Existing models(2007|$\leq )$| . New models (⁠|$>2007$|⁠) . . . No Tech. . Tech. . No Tech. . Tech. . No Tech. . Tech. . . True . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . 1998 169 156 172 156 172 1999 168 156 170 156 170 2000 169 155 171 155 171 2001 167 154 169 154 169 2002 164 154 166 154 166 2003 161 153 162 153 162 2004 158 152 159 152 159 2005 156 152 157 152 157 2006 154 152 155 152 155 2007 151 152 152 152 152 2008 147 152 147 151 147 157 152 2009 142 152 143 152 142 160 150 2010 135 152 136 152 136 154 137 2011 130 152 130 152 130 154 132 The table reports the observed and predicted levels of the average sales-weighted CO|$_{2}$| emissions corrected with the attribute function |$f(w_{j})$| to represent the target values of the regulation. All predictions use the estimates from Table 2 Model 2. The columns |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| contain sales-weighted predicted emissions keeping technology constant at |$\zeta_{y}=\zeta_{2007}$|⁠. The columns |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| contain sales-weighted predicted values for emissions with estimated |$\zeta_{y}$|⁠. Open in new tab Table 3. Decomposing the decrease in emissions . . All vehicles . Existing models(2007|$\leq )$| . New models (⁠|$>2007$|⁠) . . . No Tech. . Tech. . No Tech. . Tech. . No Tech. . Tech. . . True . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . 1998 169 156 172 156 172 1999 168 156 170 156 170 2000 169 155 171 155 171 2001 167 154 169 154 169 2002 164 154 166 154 166 2003 161 153 162 153 162 2004 158 152 159 152 159 2005 156 152 157 152 157 2006 154 152 155 152 155 2007 151 152 152 152 152 2008 147 152 147 151 147 157 152 2009 142 152 143 152 142 160 150 2010 135 152 136 152 136 154 137 2011 130 152 130 152 130 154 132 . . All vehicles . Existing models(2007|$\leq )$| . New models (⁠|$>2007$|⁠) . . . No Tech. . Tech. . No Tech. . Tech. . No Tech. . Tech. . . True . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| . |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| . 1998 169 156 172 156 172 1999 168 156 170 156 170 2000 169 155 171 155 171 2001 167 154 169 154 169 2002 164 154 166 154 166 2003 161 153 162 153 162 2004 158 152 159 152 159 2005 156 152 157 152 157 2006 154 152 155 152 155 2007 151 152 152 152 152 2008 147 152 147 151 147 157 152 2009 142 152 143 152 142 160 150 2010 135 152 136 152 136 154 137 2011 130 152 130 152 130 154 132 The table reports the observed and predicted levels of the average sales-weighted CO|$_{2}$| emissions corrected with the attribute function |$f(w_{j})$| to represent the target values of the regulation. All predictions use the estimates from Table 2 Model 2. The columns |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| contain sales-weighted predicted emissions keeping technology constant at |$\zeta_{y}=\zeta_{2007}$|⁠. The columns |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| contain sales-weighted predicted values for emissions with estimated |$\zeta_{y}$|⁠. Open in new tab The technology parameters |$\zeta_{y}$| are derived from the time fixed effects in each regression and are plotted in Table 2 for Models 1 to 5. Model 1 is the baseline specification close to Knittel (2011), and includes trade-off parameters for horsepower, weight, footprint, and height. Model 2 allows for a firm-specific trend in technology. Next, I start introducing the on-road measures of emissions. These measures are available for a much smaller set of vehicles so that the sample shrinks from 14,444 observations to 3,766 observations. Model 3 replicates Model 1 with the smaller sample. Model 4 changes the dependent variable so that the relation between the actual emissions and characteristics is estimated. Model 5 introduces firm-specific trends. Models 2 and 5 report averages of firm-specific trends. The bottom panel of the table presents the difference in the mean of |$\zeta_{y}$| for 1999–2007 and 2008–11, corresponding to the pre- and post-policy announcement period. Models 1–3 all explain the official emission ratings, and I find that technology improves significantly faster in the later years of the sample. All estimates show that the technology shifts |$\zeta_{y}$| are more than 2% higher after 2007 than in the years before. The difference is statistically significant. After 2007, the estimates reveal a significant increase in the pace of technology improvement.22 In the official emission measures, I find evidence of rapid changes in technology adoption, but the emission reductions might not translate to the road. Once I look at changes in actual emissions in Models 4 and 5, I find that technology growth does not increase as rapidly in the post-policy period. Between 2008–11, the mean technology change shrinks from 3.9% in Model 2 to a mere 1.5% in Model 5. However, Models 4 and 5 reveal higher average technology growth in later years relative to prior years, but the difference shrinks from 2.4% to 0.7%. 23 Overall, this reveals that firms do engage in technology adoption after the policy announcement but that a large part of the technology aims at reducing official emission ratings rather than actual emissions. The estimates show that 70% of the additional reduction in official emissions comes from gaming, while 30% comes from actual technology improvements. I will use this 30/70 ratio in the structural model below.24 3.2. Decomposition of the changes in emissions I use the estimated relation (2) to decompose the decline in emissions over time. The decomposition is as follows: I predict emissions, |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$|⁠, as the fitted values of regression (2) with Model 2. I also predict |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| using (2) but fixing the technology level at |$\zeta_{y}=\zeta_{2007}$|⁠.25 The evolution in the sales-weighted values of |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| only changes when the composition of characteristics |$x_{jy}$| changes over time, while |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| changes both because of underlying characteristics and technology. The results in Table 3 show that between 1998 and 2007, sales-weighted emissions without technology |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| declined slightly from 156 to 152. Technology improvements are responsible for the remaining moderate decline in official emissions between 1998 and 2007. After 2007, the sales-weighted emissions without technology |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| remain constant. Because |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| is constant, mix-shifting or downsizing cannot explain the decline in official emissions. When I split up the average sales-weighted emissions into vehicle models released after and before 2007, the results show that the emissions |$\overline{e}_{jy}$| of vehicles released before 2007 remain constant.26 Vehicle models released after the policy announcement are, on average, more polluting than the existing vehicle models. The difference between the existing vehicles and the vehicles released after the policy decreases over time. The observed decline in emissions is not attributable to changes in the sales mix or the release of new downsized fuel-efficient vehicles. However, I cannot rule out that the vehicles would have grown in terms of weight, size, and horsepower without the policy. The sales-weighted emissions with technology |$\widehat{e}_{jy}$| are decreasing rapidly after 2007, and this shows that technology adoption is fully responsible for the observed drop in the official emission ratings. Strikingly, the decrease in sales-weighted emissions of older vehicles due to technology is as strong as the decrease in newly released vehicles and engine improvements are installed widely across the fleet. These results present two concerns so far. First, the Great Recession and the EU debt crisis took place just after the policy announcement. In general, an economic downturn would lead consumers to spend less on durables and would add to the likelihood of finding evidence for shifts in the composition of the fleet towards smaller vehicles. The fact that we do not see this strengthens the argument that firms respond with technology adoption. Technology adoption itself could be affected by the crisis, but the direction of that effect is unclear. A second concern is that the observed response is so strong that most firms already complied with the emission standard in 2011, four years before the regulation is fully binding. Individual member states do increase their emission-based taxation and regulation in response to the EU-wide policy.27 This combination of new local taxation and the standard can explain why the response is so strong and why compliance is attained early. It would be very interesting to study the interaction between national regulation and the EU-wide standard, but this is out of the scope of the current project. In the remaining analysis, I model firm behaviour in response to a standard to single out the effects of the EU emission standard. In summary, I present evidence that the observed decline in emissions is attributable to changes in the official |${\rm CO}_{2}$| ratings while the sales mix and characteristics of the fleet are unaffected. The estimates show that gaming explains 70% of the decline in official emissions, technology adaption explains the remaining 30%. These findings form the basis for developing an economic model in which firms can respond to the emission standard with technology adoption or gaming, keeping the other characteristics of their fleet unaffected. 4. Model This section introduces an emission standard in a structural model of consumer demand and firm behaviour. The supply-side model describes how firms can use different abatement strategies in response to a binding emission standard. This model will be the basis to simulate the welfare effects of the emission standard in Section 6. In the estimation, I use pre-policy data to estimate a standard supply model in which firms do not face the regulatory constraint. Finally, I discuss how the design choices of the regulator regarding attribute basing and enforcement affect abatement choices.28 4.1. Demand A market is defined as a country, indexed by |$m$|⁠, observed in a calendar year |$y$|⁠.29 In each market |$my$| there are |$A_{my}$| potential consumers. Consumers are assumed to purchase only in the market where they are located. Each consumer |$i$| chooses one alternative |$j$|⁠, which is either the outside good, |$j=0$|⁠, or one of the |$J$| differentiated products, |$j=1,\ldots ,J$|⁠. Consumer |$i$|’s conditional indirect utility for the outside good is |$u_{i0my}=\varepsilon _{i0my}$|⁠, and for products |$j=1,\ldots ,J$| it is: $$ \begin{equation} u_{ijmy}=x_{jmy}\beta _{i}^{x}-\beta _{i}^{e}d_{jmy} e_{jmy} k_j -\alpha p_{jmy}+\xi _{jmy}+\varepsilon _{ijmy}, \label{General utility} \end{equation} $$(3) where |$x_{jmy}$| is a vector of observed product characteristics, |$d_{jmy} e_{jmy} k_j$| are fuel costs (fuel prices |$d_{jmy}$| times emissions |$e_{jmy}$| times a fuel type specific factor |$k_j$| that translates emissions into fuel consumption as explained in footnote 1), |$p_{jmy}$| is the vehicle price and |$\xi _{jmy}$| is an unobserved characteristic of vehicle |$j$| in market |$my$|⁠, unobserved by the researcher but observed by consumers and firms. The parameter vector |$(\beta_{i}^{e},\beta _{i}^{x})$| consists of random coefficients, capturing individual-specific valuations for fuel costs and vehicle characteristics, |$\alpha$| is the marginal utility of income or price valuation and |$\varepsilon_{ijmy}$| is a remaining individual-specific valuation for product |$j$| (assumed to be i.i.d. type I extreme value). The random coefficient for characteristic |$k$| is given by |$\beta _{i}^{k}=\beta ^{k}+\sigma ^{k}\nu_{i}^{k}$|⁠, where |$\nu _{i}^{k}$| is a random draw from a standard normal distribution so that |$\beta ^{k}$| represents the mean valuation for characteristic |$k$| and |$\sigma ^{k}$| the standard deviation across consumers. The coefficient |$\beta _{i}^{e}$| measures the consumers’ valuation of fuel costs. Consumers use vehicles for several years and care about the expected fuel costs over the vehicle lifetime. I follow the literature on fuel cost valuation (see e.g.Allcott and Wozny (2014) and Grigolon et al. (2018)) and make the assumption that consumers expect fuel prices to follow a random walk. The random walk assumption is consistent with the survey evidence, as shown by Anderson et al. (2013). The fuel price at the time of purchase multiplied by the vehicle fuel consumption then captures the expected cost per kilometre of travel in each year of usage. The parameter |$\beta _{i}^{e}$| estimates the mean and heterogeneity in the value for fuel costs scaled by mileage and a capitalization factor.3031 I estimate the valuation for fuel costs with data from before the policy announcement where firms had no incentive to game.32 I assume that consumers know what the official rating signals about the actual fuel costs when estimating the model. When I introduce the policy in the simulation, firms can game the emission ratings and it becomes unclear if consumers can determine if decreases in fuel costs are due to gaming or technology adoption. I consider both the case where consumers are sophisticated and where they are fooled. Each consumer |$i$| in market |$my$| chooses the alternative |$j=0,\ldots ,J$| that maximizes her utility. The predicted market share of vehicle |$j$| in market |$my$| is the probability that product |$j$| yields the highest utility across all available products (including the outside good |$0$|⁠). This is given by the logit choice probabilities, integrated over the individual-specific valuations for the continuous characteristics: $$ \begin{equation} s_{jmy}(\delta _{my},\sigma )=\int \dfrac{\exp(\delta _{jmy}+\mu_{jmy}(\sigma,\nu )) }{1+\sum_{l=1}^{J} \exp( \delta _{lmy}+\mu_{lmy}(\sigma,\nu)) }dP_{\nu }(\nu ), \label{share} \end{equation} $$(4) where |$\delta _{my}$|⁠, the mean utility, which collects all terms in (3) that do not vary across individuals, and |$\mu _{jmy}$| is the term that captures the individual idiosyncratic deviations from the mean utility as follows: |$\mu _{jmy}$|=|$\sum_k \sigma ^{k}\nu_{i}^{k}x^{k}_{jmy}$|⁠. To complete the demand side, I set the observed market share |$s_{jmy}=q_{jmy}/A_{my}$| equal to the predicted market share (4). In vector notation, the demand side in market |$m$| can then be described by the market share system as follows: |$\mathbf{s}_{my}=\mathbf{s}_{my}(\delta_{my},\sigma ).$| 4.2. Firm behaviour To study firms’ responses to the emission standard, I model a game in which firms have the following three choices: price setting, technology adoption, and gaming. The timing of the game is assumed to be as follows. First, I assume that the vehicle fleet of firms is exogenous. Each firm sells hundreds of differentiated products and I do not model the decision regarding which vehicles firms choose to offer. Second, at the time of their strategic decision, firms have perfect information on all observable and unobservable characteristics. Third, given their vehicle fleet, firms have the option to change the prices and fuel consumption of each of the products simultaneously. The fuel consumption can be changed by adding technology or by gaming the test that determines the level of fuel consumption. Finally, when firms face regulation, the choices are altered to comply with the regulation that binds across total sales from all EU markets. The goal of this section is to understand how firms change decisions on pricing and fuel consumption levels when facing a binding regulation. The total profit in year |$y$| is the sum of the profits from each country |$m$|⁠, as follows: $$ \begin{align} \max_{p,t,g}\sum_{m}[\pi_{fm}(p,t,g)] \text{ }s.t.\text{ }\frac{\sum_{m}\sum_{j\epsilon F_{f}}q_{jm}((1-t_j-g_j)e_{j}-f(w_{j}))}{\sum_{m}\sum_{j\epsilon F_{f}}q_{jm}}\leq \kappa , \end{align}$$(5) where |$\pi_{fm}$| are variable profits for firm |$f$| in market |$m$|⁠, |$F_{f}$| is the set of products firm |$f$| sells, |$\kappa$| is the level of the standard and |$f(w_{j})$| is the attribute basing on weight |$w_{j}$|⁠. For a flat standard |$f(w_{j})=0$|⁠, when |$f(w_{j})\neq 0$| vehicles with different weights obtain reductions or penalties on their official emissions.33 I model technology adoption and gaming as percentage reductions in fuel consumption so that |$0\leq t \leq1$|⁠, |$0\leq g \leq1$|⁠, and |$0\leq t+g \leq1$|⁠. Firms adjusting |$t$| or |$g$| induce sunk costs |$C(t,g)$|⁠, which I discuss in Section 6.6. I model simultaneous joint choices of |$p, t$| and |$g$| and ignore dynamics.34 I follow Goldberg (1998) and Jacobsen (2013) and write the Lagrangian of firm |$f$| net of sunk costs in market |$m$| as: $$ \begin{align} \mathcal{L}=\sum_{m}\sum_{j\in F _{f}} [(p_{jm}-c_{jm}(t_j)-\lambda L_j(t_j,g_j))s_{jm}(p,t,g)A_{m}], \label{prof} \end{align}$$(6) where |$c_{jm}$| denotes marginal costs, |$\lambda$| is the shadow cost of the regulation per unit of sales. The shadow cost is multiplied by |$L_{j}=(1-t_j-g_j)e_{j}-f(w_{j})-\kappa$|⁠, the distance of each product from the target. When |$L_{j}<0$| (⁠|$>0$|⁠), an additional sale of vehicle |$j$| brings the average sales-weighted emissions closer to (further away from) the target. The shadow cost |$\lambda$| gives the cost per unit sold of deviating one unit from the standard. If the standard is non-binding, |$\lambda=0$| and (6) reduces to a standard multi-product profit function. The shadow cost |$\lambda$| takes the same value for each vehicle in the fleet |$F_{f}$| because, in equilibrium, firms equalize the shadow costs over their fleet to be cost-efficient. The shadow cost differs between firms because trading of excess emissions is not allowed. Three first-order derivatives of |$\mathcal{L}$| to |$p,t,g$|⁠, together with sunk cost, determine the optimal solution to the profit maximization problem. I introduce the following matrices to write the derivatives concisely: |$\Phi$| denotes a |$J\times J$| ownership matrix with each element |$(i,j)$| equal to one if |$i$| and |$j$| are owned by the same firm and zero otherwise; |$\triangle_{k}$| denotes the |$J \times J$| matrix of first-order derivatives of market shares with respect to |$k=p, t$| or |$g$|⁠. Define |$\circ$| as the Hadamard product. Bold vectors (⁠|$\mathbf{q},\mathbf{p},\mathbf{c}, \mathbf{\lambda \circ L}$| and |$\mathbf{e}$|⁠) have dimension |$J \times 1$|⁠, with |$\lambda$| now a vector with the firm-specific shadow cost when |$j \epsilon F_{f}$|⁠. Vector |$\mathbf{c'_{t}}$| is |$J \times 1$| with scalar derivatives |$\partial mc_j / \partial t_j$| as elements. The |$J$| first-order derivatives with respect to prices, technology, and gaming are: $$ \begin{eqnarray} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial p} &=&\mathbf{q}+ \mathbf{\Phi \circ \triangle_{p}(p-c-\lambda \circ L)} \label{FOC1}\\ \end{eqnarray} $$(7) $$ \begin{eqnarray} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L} }{\partial t} &=&(-\mathbf{c'_{t}}+\mathbf{\lambda} \circ \mathbf{e})\circ \mathbf{q}+\mathbf{\Phi \circ \triangle_{t} (p-c-\lambda \circ L)} \label{FOC2}\\ \end{eqnarray} $$(8) $$ \begin{eqnarray} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L} }{\partial g} &=&\mathbf{\lambda}\circ \mathbf{e}\circ \mathbf{q}+\mathbf{\Phi \circ \triangle_{g} (p-c-\lambda \circ L)} \label{FOC3} \end{eqnarray} $$(9) The first-order derivatives with respect to prices show the standard trade off between increases in mark up (first term on the right-hand side) and losses from reduced sales (second term on the right-hand side) when increasing the price. The first-order derivatives with respect to technology adoption show that firms trade-off marginal cost increases |$\mathbf{c'_{t}}$| with relaxing the regulatory constraint and the benefits of increased market share (we expect |$\triangle_{t}>0$|⁠). The first-order derivatives with respect to gaming are very similar but gaming induces no marginal cost changes. The system is defined at the product level for |$t$| and |$g$|⁠. In the counterfactual, I impose |$g$| because I lack cost data and I solve for firm level choices of |$t$| to shrink the dimensionality of (8) to the number of firms. 4.3. Externalities The regulation limits the sales-weighted emissions and not the total externalities from the new vehicle fleet. The amount of |${\rm CO}_{2}$| emitted depends on both the size and composition of the fleet. Given the fuel consumption of each vehicle, we can compute the total lifetime damages from |${\rm CO}_{2}$| emissions. The computation requires information on mileage and an estimate of the value of a ton of |${\rm CO}_{2}$|⁠. When consumers purchase vehicles with lower fuel consumption, emissions decrease. However, it might be that the standard results in more fuel-efficient vehicles but also in more purchases. It is not certain that total emissions will decline. In the welfare calculation, I also consider other externalities, such as traffic, accidents, and local pollutants. Next, I discuss how equilibrium outcomes change when we move from a market without a standard (or a non-binding standard), |$\lambda=0$| to a market with a binding standard, |$\lambda>0$|⁠. The changes in the market depend on the abatement strategy of firms, i.e., mix-shifting, technology adoption, or gaming. I discuss the effect of each strategy in turn, keeping the other strategies fixed. 4.4. Abatement by mix-shifting A first mechanism to abate emissions is to change the relative prices of high and low emission vehicles. Firms can decrease the prices of vehicles with emissions below the target (⁠|$L_{j}<0$|⁠) while increasing the prices of vehicles with emissions above the target (⁠|$L_{j}>0$|⁠). The first-order conditions with respect to prices (7) show that the shadow cost of the regulation, |$\lambda$|⁠, determines to what extent prices will be distorted from a no-policy equilibrium, as follows: $$ \begin{equation} \mathbf{p} =\mathbf{c}+\mathbf{\lambda \circ L}-(\mathbf{\Phi \circ \triangle_{p}})^{-1}\mathbf{q.} \end{equation} $$(10) The regulation implicitly taxes vehicles with |$L_{j}>0$|⁠, while it implicitly subsidizes vehicles with |$L_{j}<0$|⁠. This change in the relative prices of products shifts the sales mix towards vehicles with lower fuel consumption. It is important to stress that the abatement strategy of changing prices to shift the sales mix is driven by the term |$\mathbf{\lambda \circ L}$|⁠. This term captures the first-order effect of the regulation on prices and shows how the emission target constrains the pricing equilibrium. Abatement by technology adoption and gaming, as discussed immediately below, results in changes in attributes of different products. These changes also affect pricing, as firms face different marginal costs and competition. But, I do not interpret these price changes as mix-shifting. The incidence and effectiveness of this abatement strategy largely depend on the responsiveness of consumers to these price changes as captured in |$\triangle_{p}$|⁠. Holland et al. (2009) show that when the price elasticities of subsidized products differ from those of taxed products, total sales and emissions might increase or decrease. Without knowledge of the own and cross-price elasticities, we cannot make statements about the effect of the regulation on sales, emissions or consumer surplus. The effects on profits depend on consumers response to price changes but also depend on the position of the fleet relative to the target. Firms with a fleet that is better adapted to the standard might increase profits, as their prices need less distortion than their competitors. The empirical mode allows me to identify the own and cross-price elasticities for all products and to simulate the shifts in sales when I introduce a binding regulation. 4.5. Abatement by technology adoption Firms can reduce the emissions of existing vehicles by adapting the engines, the combustion process, or features that only affect fuel consumption. From (8), we see that the regulation gives incentives to firms to adopt more technology. The first term, |$(-c'_{t}+\lambda \circ e) \circ q$|⁠, specifies that increases in fuel efficiency change the marginal cost of each unit sold. But, the technology also relaxes the regulatory constraint, resulting in a marginal benefit of |$\lambda$|⁠. Without a regulation |$\lambda=0$| and the marginal benefits of technology adoption is lower. The second term captures the change in sales from technology, |$\Phi \circ \triangle_{t}$|⁠, multiplied by profits per unit, |$(p-c-\lambda \circ L)$|⁠. Finally, implementing technology can involve sunk costs |$C(t,g)$| related to making changes in the production. Each unit of technology adoption lowers |$L$|⁠. The fleet of the firm shifts closer to the regulatory target and the regulatory constraint is relaxed. Technology adoption reduces the shadow cost of the regulation |$\lambda$| as firms need less distortion away from the preferred price schedule to comply. When determining to what extent firms adopt technology or mix-shift in equilibrium, the shadow cost |$\lambda$| and the amount of technology is determined endogenously. The welfare effects of this strategy are again undetermined theoretically. Consumer face two offsetting effects. The standard puts upward pressure on prices as marginal costs increase with |$c'_{t}$|⁠. Increased prices reduce consumer surplus. However, offsetting this, firms offer vehicles with lower fuel consumption, decreasing the cost of operating a vehicle. The sum of the purchase price and operating costs might increase or decrease. Even though the resulting vehicle fleet has lower emissions, it is not clear that emissions decrease, i.e., if consumers benefit from technology, they might purchase more vehicles. The changes in marginal costs and the degree of pass-through determine the overall effect. Given that different vehicles have different fuel consumptions, the equilibrium prices also adjust, creating another welfare change for consumers. For firms, technology adoption is a preferred abatement strategy if the shadow cost of mix-shifting is high, and the marginal cost and sunk cost changes of technology adoption are low. 4.6. Abatement by gaming Gaming helps with compliance in a very similar way as technology adoption. The first part of (9) shows each unit of gaming reduces |$L$| and the shadow cost of the regulation |$\lambda$| until firms can price without regulatory constraints. The second term in (9) accounts for market share changes due to gaming. Gaming does not affect the on-road experience of consumers and does not reduce the actual fuel consumption. However, when purchasing a vehicle, consumers might be fooled by the advertised fuel consumption. The EU introduced the official ratings for advertising and windshield stickers to inform consumers about fuel costs and pollution. As such, gaming has demand effects that distort consumer choice. In the results, I discuss what happens when consumers are fooled or when they are aware of gaming. The effects on consumer welfare depend on this consumer sophistication. If consumers do not see through gaming, the information in the official ratings becomes a noisy signal of fuel costs and might distort consumer choices. This choice distortion reduces consumer surplus and might also lead to higher prices. Gaming might also have positive effects for consumers, as it allows firms to avoid costly compliance and high pricing. The effects on emissions from gaming can be pervasive. Each reduction in fuel consumption obtained with gaming does not reduce actual emissions. Consumers respond to the decreases in perceived fuel costs by substituting toward higher-performance cars. Because cars look cheaper on paper, the overall sales might increase. Both of these effects potentially increase emissions relative to honest compliance. The costs of gaming are very different than those of technology adoption. As summarized in Section 2.1, gaming is essentially a sunk cost that mainly consists of expected legal fees and consumer blow-back. This cost |$C(t,g)$| needs to be positive to prevent firms from choosing for gaming as the only abatement strategy. Both terms in (9) are benefits to the firm, and these benefits will be weighted against the expected costs. Without empirical information on |$C(t,g)$|⁠, I choose to pin down gaming using the evidence from Section 3. 4.7. Abatement by downsizing I assume the fleet of each firm as given. In previous work, Klier and Linn (2012) and Whitefoot et al. (2017) tried to relax this assumption by modelling not only improvements in fuel consumption but by allowing firms to optimize a broader set of attributes. This strategy is described as downsizing: firms reduce the size and power of vehicles to lower fuel consumption. Klier and Linn (2012) find that compliance costs decrease by approximately 40% per year when firms downsize instead of changing prices. Consumer loss is similar. Whitefoot et al. (2017) use an interesting engineering model. I do not model downsizing for two reasons. In Section 3, I find no evidence of downsizing in the EU. A model that allows strategic choices over several characteristics is computationally challenging for the detailed engine version level data used in this analysis, and it would introduce difficulties with multiple equilibria. 4.8. Design of emission standards One of the key contributions of this article is to show how political choices about the design features of emission standards interact with the firms’ abatement choices. In the counterfactual, I consider two regulation design choices. First, I study the EU’s choice to have a policy that is attribute-based and upward sloping, as depicted in Figure 1. Second, I study the implications of weak enforcement of the regulation. It is instructive to compare the attribute-based regulation with a flat standard. For a flat standard, |$L_{j}^{\prime }=\left[ e_{j}-\kappa^{\prime }\right] $|⁠, and |$f(w_{j})=0$|⁠. The target function is a horizontal line at |$\kappa ^{\prime }$| and all firms need to reach the same level of sales-weighted emissions. Each firm has a different set of vehicles with |$L_{j}<0 $| and |$L_{j}^{\prime }<0$|⁠. Because of the upward sloping ABR in the EU, the sales of many small, lightweight vehicles do not help with compliance, while they help with compliance under a flat standard. Attribute basing reduces the number of products that have |$L_{j}<0$|⁠. Price changes become much costlier because firms have can shift sales to fewer products. Reducing fuel consumption by technology adoption or gaming helps increase the number of products that have emissions underneath the target. In the empirical section, I show that the ABR increases the stringency for French and Italian firms but reduces the stringency for German firms. The difference between firms matches the lobbying efforts by the governments described at the time of the negotiations. I also show that price changes became so expensive for firms that they had to resort to lowering fuel consumption. The attribute-based regulation might have other economic consequences. Ito and Sallee (2018) point out that attribute-based standards distort the demand and supply of the attribute itself. If heavier cars help with attaining the target, weight is indirectly subsidized, and producers choose to add more weight to their vehicles.35 In this exercise, I keep the weight fixed and assume no distortions in the attribute itself. I keep weight fixed because I do not observe any changes in weight consistent with a distortion. Additionally, allowing for more choice variables for the firm is computationally costly. The EU’s political structure has also led to weak enforcement of the policy. Above, I discussed how failures in the delegation of enforcement have led to the gaming crisis in the EU market. Theoretically, the sunk cost of gaming |$C(g)$| captures enforcement. When enforcement is strict and legal punishment for gaming high, the sunk costs of gaming increases. A higher sunk cost means that gaming as an abatement strategy becomes less attractive so firms resort to mix-shifting or technology adoption. In the empirical section, I discuss what happens if firms do not game EU regulation. 5. Estimation I use a panel of seven countries over 10 years to estimate the taste and cost parameters. I restrict the sample to 1998–2007, the years before the policy announcement. This restriction allows me to estimate a model in which firms maximize unconstrained profits as given in (6) with |$\lambda =0$|⁠. It also allows me to estimate the consumer valuation of fuel costs before firms start to game emission ratings. I discuss the demand estimation that allows for the endogeneity of both prices and engine characteristics. Next, I discuss the supply-side and estimation of costs. I also discuss the functional form assumptions needed to project marginal costs out of sample to model technological improvements. With the estimates of consumer preferences, marginal costs, and the functional form assumption, I simulate the impact of the emission standard in the next section. 5.1. Demand estimation The vector of parameters |$\theta$| to be estimated consists of the taste parameters |$\beta _{i}^{e},\beta_{i}^{x}$| and |$\alpha _{i}$|⁠. I estimate both a mean and a standard deviation of the taste for fuel consumption, horsepower, and a dummy for foreign perceived cars (e.g. a BMW in France). I specify |$\alpha$| to be proportional to income |$y_{m}$| in market |$m$|⁠, so that |$\alpha=\alpha _{my}=\alpha/y_{my}$|⁠.36 I add a set of controls for which I only estimate the mean taste. These include weight, footprint, height, a dummy for 3 doors, market fixed effects, diesel by market interactions, months on market dummies (for vehicles introduced within a calendar year), and a market-specific time trend.37 Finally, I add 331 fixed effects on the vehicle model level so that all identifying variation for the taste parameters comes from different engine versions within the same vehicle model. The remaining unexplained variation in market shares is |$\xi _{jm}$|⁠. I obtain the parameters by minimizing the GMM criterion: $$ \begin{equation} \min_{\theta}\xi \left( \theta \right) ^{\prime }Z A Z^{\prime }\xi\left( \theta \right), \end{equation} $$(11) where |$\xi$| is a column vector of the |$J$| demand unobservables stacked over each market. I obtain |$\xi$| after inverting the system of market shares in (4). The matrix of instruments is |$Z$|⁠, and |$A$| is a weighting matrix. I use the two-step efficient GMM estimator so that the second step |$A$| is the estimate of the optimal weighting matrix. I follow the estimation algorithm described in Berry et al. (1995) and Nevo (2001). I take into account recent cautionary warnings and improvements and carefully check the properties of the obtained minimum.38 A common exclusion restriction in the literature is |$E[\xi|x]=0$|⁠, so that any function of observed characteristics is a valid candidate to form the unconditional moments. This exclusion restriction allows for the correlation between prices and |$\xi$| but assume that all the vehicle characteristic choices of firms are mean independent of |$\xi$|⁠. The counterfactual considers strategic choices in response to regulation. However, even before the regulation, firms design products to maximize profits. The concern when estimating demand is that firms know more about consumer tastes than the econometrician when designing the product. This information asymmetry potentially introduces omitted variable bias through correlation of the demand unobservable |$\xi$| and product characteristics, despite the rich set of fixed effects. To account for this, I introduce additional instrumental variables. The identification assumption is |$E[\xi|Z^k]=0$| so that the demand unobservables are mean independent from instruments |$z$|⁠. I construct instruments for three sets of parameters: the taste parameter for the price, the taste parameters for endogenous characteristics, and the nonlinear parameters. First, I consider instruments |$Z^1$| for the model with price endogeneity. Second, I consider instruments |$Z^2$| for the more general case with endogenous characteristics. 5.2. Instruments The instrument set |$Z^1$| contains all characteristics and demand shifters, except price, as included instruments. The excluded instruments are the sums of other product characteristics (both the sum across all competing firms’ products and the sum across products of the same firm). These are valid instruments for prices only when the characteristics are mean independent of the demand unobservable |$\xi_j$|⁠. Using the location where each vehicle is produced, I include the logarithm of local labour costs in the country of production as a cost shifter. For instrument set |$Z^2$|⁠, I follow the recent work by Whitefoot et al. (2017), who use engineering procedures to distinguish between fixed vehicle characteristics and more mutable characteristics. More mutable characteristics can be adjusted when information about the demand unobservable is revealed, while fixed characteristics are chosen before and cannot be adjusted. In the first engineering step, firms set the dimensions of the vehicle (footprint and height). In following steps, firms fit the engines in the design. I assume that the footprint and height are exogenous and remain in the set of included instruments. Fuel costs, horsepower, and weight are allowed to be endogenous so that I need excluded instruments for the following four variables: the three mutable characteristics and prices. Because the mutable characteristics potentially correlate with |$\xi$|⁠, their sums (across own or other firm products) are not valid instruments anymore. I form additional instruments that aim to capture variations in the engine design decisions of firms. Using global production data, I exploit changes in the exposure of each vehicle model to non-EU markets over time. I compute the share of each vehicle model produced in Africa, Asia, Eastern Europe, North America, and South America. Together with the EU production, the shares add up to one. These production shares evolve within a model over time as some models become popular in the U.S. (e.g. the BMW X5) or in China (e.g. the AUDI A8). A vehicle designed for the EU and the U.S. market is different than a model designed for the EU and China. Because of the vehicle fixed effects, the identifying variation of the IV’s comes from the trend in globalization within vehicle models. I assume that the differences in exposure to other markets impact the design choices but are orthogonal to the EU unobserved demand |$\xi _{jm}$|⁠. In the production data, I also observe a size variable, scaled from 1 to 10, for each vehicle produced. Using these observations, I compute a weighted sum of size for each model and brand. The weights are the production shares in the different continents, and the size is the production weighted average size of all vehicles produced in a region. These sums capture competition in product space in different production regions. Next, I follow Klier and Linn (2012) and include the average footprint and height of vehicles produced in different classes but on the same production platform. For example, the AUDI A5, which is in the luxury class, is produced on the same platform, named MLB, as the AUDI Q5, an SUV. I use the attributes of the Q5 as an instrument for the A5 and vice versa. The idea behind the instrument is that vehicles produced on the same platform share both fixed and mutable characteristics.39 Finally, fuel costs equal fuel prices times fuel consumption. Fuel prices are exogenous, so I interact with fuel prices the projection of fuel consumption on all instruments. To improve the efficiency of the estimates of the variances of the random coefficients, I compute approximate optimal instruments for the nonlinear parameters following the approach described in Berry et al. (1999) and Reynaert and Verboven (2014). These instruments are non-linear functions of the previously described included and excluded instruments and relate to the conditional expectation of the Jacobian of |$\xi _{jm}$|⁠: |$E[\frac{\partial \xi _{jm}} {\partial \sigma} \mid z_{jm}]$|⁠. To approximate the infeasible optimal instruments, I take a two-stage approach. In the first stage, I estimate the non-linear model and compute the approximate optimal instrument at a guess for the nonlinear parameters. In the second stage, I update the approximation of the optimal instruments at the first stage estimates.40 This procedure generates a number of additional instruments equal to the number of standard deviations of random coefficients. Supplementary Appendix A3 gives a detailed overview of all the instrumental variables. 5.3. Costs I do not observe marginal costs |$c_{jm}$| but obtain them from the first-order conditions of the firms’ profit maximization. From equation (7), the demand estimates, and the fact that |$\lambda=0$| in the estimation sample, I compute |$c_{jm}$|⁠. Similarly, we can use equation (8) to back out an estimate of the cost of changing technology |$c'_{t}$|⁠. The derivative gives an estimate of the slope of the marginal cost with respect to reductions in fuel consumption before the policy announcement. Information on |$c'_{t}$| is useful because it reveals the cost changes that firms are willing to incur to provide fuel consumption in their products. Lowering fuel consumption further would be more costly than what the firm gains from providing the improvement. If the supply model is correctly specified, any cost function for further reductions in emissions must start at |$c'_{t=0}$|⁠, otherwise, it is at odds with the revealed choices of firms and consumers. I interpret the pre-policy estimate of the slope as |$c'_{t=0}$| and use it as the intercept for the cost slope in the simulations.41 I also need an estimate of the cost changes when the regulation requires fuel consumption reductions above what we observe. I use two approaches for this problem. The first approach relies on cost estimates from TNO (2011) that specify convex cost functions for percentage reductions in emissions. I use these functions in the main results and I refer to them as the engineering cost curve. However, I shift the intercept of the engineering cost function from zero to the point where the slope of the engineering function equals |$c'_{t=0}$|⁠. Supplementary Appendix A5 discusses the engineering cost function in detail. The second approach relies on marginal cost estimates from the model. When marginal costs are log-linear: $$ \begin{equation} \log (c_{jm})=\gamma ^{e}e_{jm}+x_{jm}\gamma ^{d}+\omega _{jm}, \label{cost} \end{equation} $$(12) where |$x_{jm}$| is a |$1\times L$| vector of observed product characteristics, market controls, fixed effects on the vehicle model level, and cost shifters, and |$\omega _{jm}$| is unobserved. Fuel consumption enters the marginal cost, as all else equal, it is likely more expensive to produce engines with lower fuel consumption. The estimated parameter on emissions informs how marginal costs change with changes in |$e_{jm}$|⁠. The functional form allows me to predict the costs of further reductions in fuel consumption that I cannot observe within the sample. I estimate (12) by OLS when I derive costs from the RC Logit model with price endogeneity. When fuel consumption, horsepower, and weight are endogenous in the demand, |$\omega _{jm}$| is potentially correlated with these attributes. I instrument the attributes when estimating (12) using an instrument set |$Z^{2'}$| that includes the same instruments as |$Z^{2}$| except for the instruments based on platform as these might capture cost synergies between vehicles.42 5.4. Estimation results Table 4 reports the estimated parameters and standard errors for the demand model. The table presents four specifications. The first two specifications assume exogenous characteristics and use instrument set |$Z^1$| in both Logit and a RC Logit. The last two specifications allow for endogenous characteristics and use instrument set |$Z^2$|⁠. Supplementary Appendix Table A5 reports the first stage. When prices are the sole endogenous variable, the excluded IV’s are strong and have an F statistic of 67. The labour cost instrument has the expected positive sign. With multiple endogenous variables, the instruments are weaker with F stats that account for the multiple endogenous variables being between 5.7 and 21.2. Table 4. Estimation results . Demand estimates . . Price Endog. (⁠|$Z^1$|⁠) . Charact. Endog. (⁠|$Z^2$|⁠) . . Logit . RC Logit . Logit . RC Logit . . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Price/Inc. -6.709 0.365 -6.476 0.325 -8.074 0.569 -8.452 0.694 Fuel cost -2.649 0.120 -2.842 0.127 -1.291 0.192 -1.036 0.269 Horsepower 2.889 0.227 1.232 0.152 3.868 0.673 -1.546 0.760 Weight 0.666 0.181 1.248 0.156 -6.130 2.143 1.530 1.300 Base 0.580 0.056 0.526 0.051 1.499 0.229 0.878 0.179 Height 0.183 0.041 0.215 0.037 0.477 0.091 0.291 0.060 Foreign -0.848 0.023 -1.218 0.043 -0.698 0.042 -0.973 0.060 Standard deviations Fuel cost 0.000 0.033 1.196 0.484 Horsepower 1.604 0.272 2.878 2.445 Foreign 1.276 0.192 0.897 0.185 Marginal cost estimates Perf.Comp. Imp.Comp. Imp.Comp. Fuel Cons. -0.027 0.001 -0.047 0.001 -0.031 0.027 Horsepower 0.629 0.005 0.690 0.006 -0.390 0.174 Weight 0.742 0.009 0.682 0.011 4.051 0.408 Base 0.070 0.002 0.028 0.002 -0.326 0.056 Height -0.019 0.001 0.053 0.001 -0.101 0.018 Log labour cost 0.386 0.003 0.042 0.004 0.140 0.066 . Demand estimates . . Price Endog. (⁠|$Z^1$|⁠) . Charact. Endog. (⁠|$Z^2$|⁠) . . Logit . RC Logit . Logit . RC Logit . . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Price/Inc. -6.709 0.365 -6.476 0.325 -8.074 0.569 -8.452 0.694 Fuel cost -2.649 0.120 -2.842 0.127 -1.291 0.192 -1.036 0.269 Horsepower 2.889 0.227 1.232 0.152 3.868 0.673 -1.546 0.760 Weight 0.666 0.181 1.248 0.156 -6.130 2.143 1.530 1.300 Base 0.580 0.056 0.526 0.051 1.499 0.229 0.878 0.179 Height 0.183 0.041 0.215 0.037 0.477 0.091 0.291 0.060 Foreign -0.848 0.023 -1.218 0.043 -0.698 0.042 -0.973 0.060 Standard deviations Fuel cost 0.000 0.033 1.196 0.484 Horsepower 1.604 0.272 2.878 2.445 Foreign 1.276 0.192 0.897 0.185 Marginal cost estimates Perf.Comp. Imp.Comp. Imp.Comp. Fuel Cons. -0.027 0.001 -0.047 0.001 -0.031 0.027 Horsepower 0.629 0.005 0.690 0.006 -0.390 0.174 Weight 0.742 0.009 0.682 0.011 4.051 0.408 Base 0.070 0.002 0.028 0.002 -0.326 0.056 Height -0.019 0.001 0.053 0.001 -0.101 0.018 Log labour cost 0.386 0.003 0.042 0.004 0.140 0.066 The table reports the estimated parameters for the demand and marginal cost equations. The first two columns in the Demand Estimates give Logit and RC Logit estimates for the model with endogenous prices and instrument set |$Z^1$|⁠. The last two columns give the Logit and RC Logit for the model with endogenous prices and characteristics and instrument set |$Z^2$|⁠. The first column gives Marginal Cost estimates for perfect competition (regression of price on characteristics). Columns two and three give marginal cost estimates under the assumption of a Nash Bertrand game in prices (imperfect competition). Column three instruments fuel consumption, horsepower, and weight with |$Z^{2'}$|⁠. Open in new tab Table 4. Estimation results . Demand estimates . . Price Endog. (⁠|$Z^1$|⁠) . Charact. Endog. (⁠|$Z^2$|⁠) . . Logit . RC Logit . Logit . RC Logit . . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Price/Inc. -6.709 0.365 -6.476 0.325 -8.074 0.569 -8.452 0.694 Fuel cost -2.649 0.120 -2.842 0.127 -1.291 0.192 -1.036 0.269 Horsepower 2.889 0.227 1.232 0.152 3.868 0.673 -1.546 0.760 Weight 0.666 0.181 1.248 0.156 -6.130 2.143 1.530 1.300 Base 0.580 0.056 0.526 0.051 1.499 0.229 0.878 0.179 Height 0.183 0.041 0.215 0.037 0.477 0.091 0.291 0.060 Foreign -0.848 0.023 -1.218 0.043 -0.698 0.042 -0.973 0.060 Standard deviations Fuel cost 0.000 0.033 1.196 0.484 Horsepower 1.604 0.272 2.878 2.445 Foreign 1.276 0.192 0.897 0.185 Marginal cost estimates Perf.Comp. Imp.Comp. Imp.Comp. Fuel Cons. -0.027 0.001 -0.047 0.001 -0.031 0.027 Horsepower 0.629 0.005 0.690 0.006 -0.390 0.174 Weight 0.742 0.009 0.682 0.011 4.051 0.408 Base 0.070 0.002 0.028 0.002 -0.326 0.056 Height -0.019 0.001 0.053 0.001 -0.101 0.018 Log labour cost 0.386 0.003 0.042 0.004 0.140 0.066 . Demand estimates . . Price Endog. (⁠|$Z^1$|⁠) . Charact. Endog. (⁠|$Z^2$|⁠) . . Logit . RC Logit . Logit . RC Logit . . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Est. . St. Err. . Price/Inc. -6.709 0.365 -6.476 0.325 -8.074 0.569 -8.452 0.694 Fuel cost -2.649 0.120 -2.842 0.127 -1.291 0.192 -1.036 0.269 Horsepower 2.889 0.227 1.232 0.152 3.868 0.673 -1.546 0.760 Weight 0.666 0.181 1.248 0.156 -6.130 2.143 1.530 1.300 Base 0.580 0.056 0.526 0.051 1.499 0.229 0.878 0.179 Height 0.183 0.041 0.215 0.037 0.477 0.091 0.291 0.060 Foreign -0.848 0.023 -1.218 0.043 -0.698 0.042 -0.973 0.060 Standard deviations Fuel cost 0.000 0.033 1.196 0.484 Horsepower 1.604 0.272 2.878 2.445 Foreign 1.276 0.192 0.897 0.185 Marginal cost estimates Perf.Comp. Imp.Comp. Imp.Comp. Fuel Cons. -0.027 0.001 -0.047 0.001 -0.031 0.027 Horsepower 0.629 0.005 0.690 0.006 -0.390 0.174 Weight 0.742 0.009 0.682 0.011 4.051 0.408 Base 0.070 0.002 0.028 0.002 -0.326 0.056 Height -0.019 0.001 0.053 0.001 -0.101 0.018 Log labour cost 0.386 0.003 0.042 0.004 0.140 0.066 The table reports the estimated parameters for the demand and marginal cost equations. The first two columns in the Demand Estimates give Logit and RC Logit estimates for the model with endogenous prices and instrument set |$Z^1$|⁠. The last two columns give the Logit and RC Logit for the model with endogenous prices and characteristics and instrument set |$Z^2$|⁠. The first column gives Marginal Cost estimates for perfect competition (regression of price on characteristics). Columns two and three give marginal cost estimates under the assumption of a Nash Bertrand game in prices (imperfect competition). Column three instruments fuel consumption, horsepower, and weight with |$Z^{2'}$|⁠. Open in new tab The demand parameters for the model with endogenous prices show that consumers dislike higher prices, higher fuel costs, and cars perceived as foreign (BMW in France). Consumers prefer vehicles that are more powerful, heavier, and larger. In the RC Logit, the standard deviations on horsepower and foreign show considerable variation in the taste for horsepower and weight. The estimates change when I allow for multiple endogenous characteristics. The price coefficient decreases from |$-$|6.7 to |$-$|8.1, while the fuel cost parameter increases from |$-$|2.6 to |$-$|1.2. These coefficients matter for the welfare simulations, i.e., when consumers care less about fuel costs relative to price, they derive lower utility from technologies that drive up costs to decrease fuel costs. The remaining coefficients have larger standard errors than in the model with only price endogeneity, and the mean tastes for horsepower and weight switch sign between the Logit and RC Logit estimate. The standard deviations show considerable heterogeneity in the taste for fuel costs, horsepower, and foreign vehicles in this case. In Supplementary Appendix Table A6, I discuss the fit of the demand model. The second panel of Table 4 gives the results from a regression of marginal costs on product characteristics. I show the results under perfect competition (a regression of prices on characteristics) and imperfect competition for both the RC Logit models. These results show that cost shifters have the expected sign, i.e., increases in labour cost increase marginal costs, and larger, more powerful cars are also costlier. The final specification instruments for endogenous characteristics and this reduces the precision. All marginal cost regressions show that increasing the fuel efficiency of the vehicle is costly. A one-unit decrease in litres per 100 km increases the cost by 2.7% to 4.7%. In the counterfactuals, I base the main results on the engineering cost function. I favour the engineering costs for several reasons. Estimation of (12) relies on changes in fuel consumption observed in the pre-policy sample 1998–2007. The pre-policy period has limited variation in fuel consumption; see Supplementary Appendix Figure A1. The slope of the estimated cost function to fuel costs is not robust to changes in control variables.43 The specification with instrument set |$Z^{2'}$| has very large standard errors, pointing out that this parameter is difficult to estimate. The engineering estimates exclusively focus on technologies to decrease fuel consumption. In the estimated cost equation, multicollinearity makes it difficult to separate changes in fuel consumption from other attribute changes as carmakers redesign the whole vehicle when releasing a new version. Finally, I use the model to compute the cost slope that rationalizes the fuel consumption choices of firms before the policy. When consumers care less about fuel costs, it becomes less attractive for firms to provide fuel consumption reductions. Allowing for more endogenous variables in the RC Logit model lowers consumer valuation for fuel costs. The marginal benefit of fuel consumption reductions for firms decreases, so does the implied marginal cost slope in (8). The model with endogenous characteristics implies a pre-policy intercept of the cost slope that is five times less steep than what the price endogeneity model implies. Cost increases caused by the policy are lower when the initial intercept is lower, so it is more likely the emission standard increases welfare. In summary, emissions enter the model through two channels. First, all else equal, consumers dislike vehicles that have higher actual emissions because they are more costly to operate. Second, producing vehicles with lower emissions is costly for manufacturers. The first channel matters for all compliance strategies, while the second channel matters to evaluate the cost changes from technology adoption. 6. Welfare effects I use the estimated model to compare the welfare effects of emission standards with various compliance strategies. I start by describing the solution methods and computation of welfare. I describe the welfare impact of the EU emission standard, the role of the attribute basing, the role of enforcement, and the importance of the cost assumptions. These results show the main contribution of the article, i.e., the design of emission standards has an impact on the abatement choices of firms and the abatement choices matter for the welfare impact of the standard. 6.1. Simulation setup The goal of the welfare simulation is to find the welfare effects of the introduction of the EU emission standard, to test the robustness to the economic assumptions, and to compare its effects with alternative policy designs. Solving for the system of equations (7), (8), (9), |$C(t,g)$| and the policy target is computationally infeasible. Solving the full system would require a solution for j unknown prices, |$t$|’s and |$g$|’s in each country, information on sunk costs, as well as a |$\lambda$| for each firm. I make two simplifications. First, the first-order conditions for gaming (9) are satisfied only when the sunk cost of gaming is positive. This cost is challenging to determine as it depends on future legal fees, brand reputation, and hidden efforts. I use the reduced form results from Section 3 to fix the level of gaming. I assume that each percentage improvement in fuel consumption includes 70% gaming and 30% actual technology. I solve (7) and (8) for prices and technology while imposing that every 0.3 units of |$t$| imply 0.7 units of g. When discussing the role of gaming and enforcement, I vary this ratio so that, either each unit of technology translates fully to actual emission, or technology only affect official emissions and equals gaming. Second, I reduce the number of conditions to solve for by assuming that firms implement the same amount of technology fleet-wide. Firm-wide technology reduces the number of equations in (8) from j to the number of firms. I compute the counterfactual for a binding regulation with a target to reduce sales-weighted emissions to 130 g/km. I take the vehicle fleet of each firm in 2007 as given and improve the actual emissions by 6%. This adjusts for the reduction in emissions that would have happened without the regulation.44 The simulation keeps all vehicles and characteristics of this fleet fixed except for price, technology, and gaming. Finally, I solve for the equilibrium so that each firm complies exactly. In reality, this does not need to be the case, as firms may not comply with the standard and pay fines.45 Though I cannot show the computed equilibria are unique, I find no other solutions when varying starting values. Firms do not have an incentive to over-comply, as this would distort choices further from the pre-policy equilibrium. I run the following algorithm. Step 1 is to choose a value for the firm-level technology |$t$| and shadow cost |$\lambda$|⁠. Given these values, I compute the changes in the marginal costs from technology and the product price distortion implied by the shadow cost |$\lambda \circ L$| for each product. Step 2 solves for the Nash equilibrium in prices given the values chosen in Step 1 and solves for (7). Step 3 evaluates if (8) and the regulatory target is satisfied, given the guess from Step 1 and the prices from Step 2. I then update the guess and repeat Steps 1–3 until we are sufficiently close to (8) and the policy target. This final iteration gives the solutions for |$t$|⁠, |$\lambda$|⁠, prices and the implied amount of gaming. To update the guess between Step 3 and Step 1, I use the least square nonlinear equation solver provided by Knitro, with bounds on the parameters. The parameter space is bounded because the shadow costs must be positive, and the technology improvements must be between 0 and 1. Given the solution vectors of |$p$|⁠, |$t,$| and |$\lambda$|⁠, I compute the changes in outcomes between the initial equilibrium (no policy and |$6%$| reduction in emissions) and the new equilibrium (binding emission standard). All welfare changes give the total vehicle lifetime changes for one cohort of new vehicle sales; the changes represent the cost or benefit of having an emission standard for one calendar year. The direct effects of the regulation are the changes in consumer surplus, profits, and gains from correcting externalities. I calculate consumer surplus with the log sum formula of Small and Rosen (1981). I add a step when gaming fools consumers. Gaming creates a difference between the decision and experience utility. To compute consumer surplus for non-sophisticated consumers, I compute the size of the choice distortion created by the differences in decision and experience utility. The consumer surplus partly comes from reduced fuel expenses. Approximately 60% of these expenses are fuel taxes paid to the government.46 I obtain changes in profits from prices, marginal costs and quantities. Emission standards do not result in monetary transfers from firms to the government when every firm complies. To compute the changes in actual CO|$_{2}$| emissions, I assume a vehicle lifetime of 15 years, a yearly mileage of 14,000 km, and a discount rate of 6% to capitalize on the yearly gains/losses in externalities.47 The mileage is assumed to be constant, ignoring the possible rebound effects on the intensive margin. To compute the value of the CO|$_{2}$| reductions, I assume that each ton of CO|$_{2}$| has an external cost of € 28.48 Finally, I compute two additional welfare effects of the policy that were not explicit targets of the policymaker. The regulation changes the number of vehicles sold so that the size of the market changes. Parry et al. (2007) give an estimate for the total external cost from driving for the US market. These externalities include local pollution, accident risks, and congestion. Together, these are estimated to be more important than the |${\rm CO}_2$| externality. They report an externality of € 0.12 per kilometre. This number is probably not directly applicable to the EU market but at least gives a sense of the relative importance of emissions and other externalities.49 I report the gains from shrinking the size of the vehicle market using this € 0.12 per kilometre number. Note that this is very optimistic, as the emission standard only targets the sales of new vehicles, not when they drive or how much they drive. When the new vehicle fleet shrinks, it is very uncertain congestion will decrease, as existing vehicles might fill the gap. A second additional welfare effect is related to the behavioural biases of consumers. Emission standards can be a more actual tool to reduce pollution if consumers undervalue future fuel savings. Using the same data and a similar methodology, in Grigolon et al. (2018), we find that the consumer undervaluation of fuel costs in the EU is at most modest.50 For the model with endogenous characteristics, I find that consumers are more price-sensitive and value fuel costs less. At these estimates using the annual mileage and interest rate of 6%, I find that consumers only value a € 1 reduction in future fuel costs at € 0.42. The emission standard results in consumers purchasing vehicles with lower fuel costs, and I include the future gains consumers obtain. I compute this by changing the consumers’ experience utility from vehicles so that their valuation of net present fuel costs is equal to their valuation of price. The change in the consumer surplus is paternalistic in the sense that I take a stance on what consumer valuation should be, see Allcott (2016). 6.2. Welfare effects Table 5 Column I shows the central welfare estimates for the EU emission standard.51 The first panel gives changes in the size of the fleet and actual emissions. The second panel shows the direct welfare effects: consumer surplus, profits, and value of actual emissions. The third panel gives the indirect welfare effects of other externalities and undervaluation. The different scenarios I–VII change the design of the regulation or the abatement strategies. In Columns I–III, I assume that 70% of official emission reductions are due to gaming, the standard is attribute-based, consumers are sophisticated and do not respond to gaming, and technology increases the marginal costs through the engineering cost function starting at |$\hat{c}'_{t=0}$|⁠. Column I solves for optimal firm strategy so that firms can employ mix-shifting and technology (and gaming). Column II restricts the firm abatement strategy to technology adoption, and Column III restricts it to mix-shifting, both Columns solve for optimal prices, but only in Column III does the regulation enter the pricing first-order condition. Table 5. Simulation outcomes . I . II . III . IV . V . VI . VII . . Opt. . Tech . Mix shift . Flat . Fooled . Enforce . Engin. . Solve for: |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t, (\lambda=0)$| |$p,f, (t=0)$| |$p,t,\lambda$| |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t,\lambda $| Gaming: 70% 70% - 0% 70% 0% 0% Consumer Soph.: Yes Yes Yes Yes No - - Market size Total sales (%) |$-$|1.08 |$-$|1.30 |$-$|7.34 |$-$|0.98 |$-$|0.12 |$-$|1.73 0.20 [ |$-$|3.11,0.19] [|$-$|3.41,0.02] [ |$-$|8.74,|$-$|3.67] [ |$-$|3.46,0.30] [ |$-$|2.95,1.30] [ |$-$|5.00,|$-$|0.04] [ |$-$|33.69,0.74] Emissions (%) |$-$|4.85 |$-$|4.31 |$-$|19.16 |$-$|11.71 |$-$|3.81 |$-$|12.60 |$-$|5.47 [ |$-$|6.53,|$-$|3.63] [ |$-$|5.98,|$-$|3.33] [ |$-$|21.66,|$-$|12.92] [ |$-$|14.70,|$-$|7.19] [ |$-$|5.98,|$-$|2.55] [ |$-$|14.77,|$-$|10.59] [ |$-$|24.48,|$-$|4.43] Direct eelfare effects (⁠|$\Delta $| in billion € ’s) Consumer surplus |$-$|2.57 |$-$|2.51 |$-$|19.10 |$-$|7.62 |$-$|2.62 |$-$|4.45 |$-$|2.68 [ |$-$|6.17,|$-$|0.22] [ |$-$|6.12,|$-$|0.16] [ |$-$|20.74,|$-$|15.44] [ |$-$|13.82,|$-$|3.26] [ |$-$|6.22,|$-$|0.29] [ |$-$|8.90,|$-$|1.63] [ |$-$|104.5,|$-$|2.07] Profits |$-$|0.60 |$-$|0.65 |$-$|2.58 |$-$|0.96 |$-$|0.13 |$-$|0.95 |$-$|0.19 [ |$-$|1.71,0.05] [ |$-$|1.77,0.03] [ |$-$|3.60,|$-$|0.12] [ |$-$|2.45,|$-$|0.23] [ |$-$|1.56,0.59] [ |$-$|2.54,|$-$|0.11] [ |$-$|0.42,183.38] CO|$_2$| value 0.34 0.30 1.32 0.81 0.26 0.87 0.38 [ 0.21,0.44] [ 0.21,0.41] [ 0.62,1.60] [ 0.34,1.05] [ 0.20,0.40] [ 0.57,1.06] [ 0.25,1.85] Total |$-$|2.83 |$-$|2.86 |$-$|20.36 |$-$|7.76 |$-$|2.49 |$-$|4.53 |$-$|2.49 [ |$-$|7.45,0.12] [ |$-$|7.49,0.12] [ |$-$|22.83,|$-$|15.01] [ |$-$|15.77,|$-$|2.77] [ |$-$|7.08,0.49] [ |$-$|10.29,|$-$|0.87] [ |$-$|4.48,78.92] Implied value CO|$_{2}$| 265 297 458 296 292 173 212 [ 104,711] [ 114,821] [ 334,546] [ 57,571] [ 102,887] [ 67,362] [ 195,2414] Indirect welfare effects (⁠|$\Delta $| in billion € ’s) Other Ext. 2.19 2.65 14.94 2.00 0.24 3.52 |$-$|0.41 [ |$-$|0.20,6.42] [ 0.16,7.02] [ 5.19,18.13] [ |$-$|0.97,7.39] [ |$-$|2.52,6.60] [ 0.36,10.54] [ |$-$|1.60,76.38] Undervaluation 1.52 1.28 6.75 3.62 1.19 3.89 1.92 [ 1.21,2.02] [ 1.07,1.79] [ 3.89,8.03] [ 2.43,4.16] [ 0.84,1.82] [ 3.14,4.58] [ 1.44,6.87] Total: 0.88 1.07 1.33 |$-$|2.14 |$-$|1.07 2.87 |$-$|0.98 [ 0.57,1.53] [ 0.90,1.84] [ |$-$|5.78,4.71] [ |$-$|6.62,1.41] [ |$-$|2.04,1.34] [ 2.13,4.65] [ |$-$|2.99,163.19] . I . II . III . IV . V . VI . VII . . Opt. . Tech . Mix shift . Flat . Fooled . Enforce . Engin. . Solve for: |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t, (\lambda=0)$| |$p,f, (t=0)$| |$p,t,\lambda$| |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t,\lambda $| Gaming: 70% 70% - 0% 70% 0% 0% Consumer Soph.: Yes Yes Yes Yes No - - Market size Total sales (%) |$-$|1.08 |$-$|1.30 |$-$|7.34 |$-$|0.98 |$-$|0.12 |$-$|1.73 0.20 [ |$-$|3.11,0.19] [|$-$|3.41,0.02] [ |$-$|8.74,|$-$|3.67] [ |$-$|3.46,0.30] [ |$-$|2.95,1.30] [ |$-$|5.00,|$-$|0.04] [ |$-$|33.69,0.74] Emissions (%) |$-$|4.85 |$-$|4.31 |$-$|19.16 |$-$|11.71 |$-$|3.81 |$-$|12.60 |$-$|5.47 [ |$-$|6.53,|$-$|3.63] [ |$-$|5.98,|$-$|3.33] [ |$-$|21.66,|$-$|12.92] [ |$-$|14.70,|$-$|7.19] [ |$-$|5.98,|$-$|2.55] [ |$-$|14.77,|$-$|10.59] [ |$-$|24.48,|$-$|4.43] Direct eelfare effects (⁠|$\Delta $| in billion € ’s) Consumer surplus |$-$|2.57 |$-$|2.51 |$-$|19.10 |$-$|7.62 |$-$|2.62 |$-$|4.45 |$-$|2.68 [ |$-$|6.17,|$-$|0.22] [ |$-$|6.12,|$-$|0.16] [ |$-$|20.74,|$-$|15.44] [ |$-$|13.82,|$-$|3.26] [ |$-$|6.22,|$-$|0.29] [ |$-$|8.90,|$-$|1.63] [ |$-$|104.5,|$-$|2.07] Profits |$-$|0.60 |$-$|0.65 |$-$|2.58 |$-$|0.96 |$-$|0.13 |$-$|0.95 |$-$|0.19 [ |$-$|1.71,0.05] [ |$-$|1.77,0.03] [ |$-$|3.60,|$-$|0.12] [ |$-$|2.45,|$-$|0.23] [ |$-$|1.56,0.59] [ |$-$|2.54,|$-$|0.11] [ |$-$|0.42,183.38] CO|$_2$| value 0.34 0.30 1.32 0.81 0.26 0.87 0.38 [ 0.21,0.44] [ 0.21,0.41] [ 0.62,1.60] [ 0.34,1.05] [ 0.20,0.40] [ 0.57,1.06] [ 0.25,1.85] Total |$-$|2.83 |$-$|2.86 |$-$|20.36 |$-$|7.76 |$-$|2.49 |$-$|4.53 |$-$|2.49 [ |$-$|7.45,0.12] [ |$-$|7.49,0.12] [ |$-$|22.83,|$-$|15.01] [ |$-$|15.77,|$-$|2.77] [ |$-$|7.08,0.49] [ |$-$|10.29,|$-$|0.87] [ |$-$|4.48,78.92] Implied value CO|$_{2}$| 265 297 458 296 292 173 212 [ 104,711] [ 114,821] [ 334,546] [ 57,571] [ 102,887] [ 67,362] [ 195,2414] Indirect welfare effects (⁠|$\Delta $| in billion € ’s) Other Ext. 2.19 2.65 14.94 2.00 0.24 3.52 |$-$|0.41 [ |$-$|0.20,6.42] [ 0.16,7.02] [ 5.19,18.13] [ |$-$|0.97,7.39] [ |$-$|2.52,6.60] [ 0.36,10.54] [ |$-$|1.60,76.38] Undervaluation 1.52 1.28 6.75 3.62 1.19 3.89 1.92 [ 1.21,2.02] [ 1.07,1.79] [ 3.89,8.03] [ 2.43,4.16] [ 0.84,1.82] [ 3.14,4.58] [ 1.44,6.87] Total: 0.88 1.07 1.33 |$-$|2.14 |$-$|1.07 2.87 |$-$|0.98 [ 0.57,1.53] [ 0.90,1.84] [ |$-$|5.78,4.71] [ |$-$|6.62,1.41] [ |$-$|2.04,1.34] [ 2.13,4.65] [ |$-$|2.99,163.19] Table gives the welfare effects of policy simulations with 90% C.I. in brackets. Column I solves for the optimal abatement strategy given the following baseline assumptions: engineering cost function starts at |$\hat{c}'$|⁠, each emission reduction is 30% technology and 70% gaming, and consumers are sophisticated (gaming does not affect choice). Column II only allows for technology and gaming (prices are the solution of (7) with |$\lambda=0$|⁠). Column III only allows for price changes. Column IV introduces a flat standard with a target of 130g of CO|$_{2}$|/km. Column V allows gaming to affect consumer choice. Column VI sets gaming to zero. Column VII implements the engineering cost function without adjusting the intercept. Open in new tab Table 5. Simulation outcomes . I . II . III . IV . V . VI . VII . . Opt. . Tech . Mix shift . Flat . Fooled . Enforce . Engin. . Solve for: |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t, (\lambda=0)$| |$p,f, (t=0)$| |$p,t,\lambda$| |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t,\lambda $| Gaming: 70% 70% - 0% 70% 0% 0% Consumer Soph.: Yes Yes Yes Yes No - - Market size Total sales (%) |$-$|1.08 |$-$|1.30 |$-$|7.34 |$-$|0.98 |$-$|0.12 |$-$|1.73 0.20 [ |$-$|3.11,0.19] [|$-$|3.41,0.02] [ |$-$|8.74,|$-$|3.67] [ |$-$|3.46,0.30] [ |$-$|2.95,1.30] [ |$-$|5.00,|$-$|0.04] [ |$-$|33.69,0.74] Emissions (%) |$-$|4.85 |$-$|4.31 |$-$|19.16 |$-$|11.71 |$-$|3.81 |$-$|12.60 |$-$|5.47 [ |$-$|6.53,|$-$|3.63] [ |$-$|5.98,|$-$|3.33] [ |$-$|21.66,|$-$|12.92] [ |$-$|14.70,|$-$|7.19] [ |$-$|5.98,|$-$|2.55] [ |$-$|14.77,|$-$|10.59] [ |$-$|24.48,|$-$|4.43] Direct eelfare effects (⁠|$\Delta $| in billion € ’s) Consumer surplus |$-$|2.57 |$-$|2.51 |$-$|19.10 |$-$|7.62 |$-$|2.62 |$-$|4.45 |$-$|2.68 [ |$-$|6.17,|$-$|0.22] [ |$-$|6.12,|$-$|0.16] [ |$-$|20.74,|$-$|15.44] [ |$-$|13.82,|$-$|3.26] [ |$-$|6.22,|$-$|0.29] [ |$-$|8.90,|$-$|1.63] [ |$-$|104.5,|$-$|2.07] Profits |$-$|0.60 |$-$|0.65 |$-$|2.58 |$-$|0.96 |$-$|0.13 |$-$|0.95 |$-$|0.19 [ |$-$|1.71,0.05] [ |$-$|1.77,0.03] [ |$-$|3.60,|$-$|0.12] [ |$-$|2.45,|$-$|0.23] [ |$-$|1.56,0.59] [ |$-$|2.54,|$-$|0.11] [ |$-$|0.42,183.38] CO|$_2$| value 0.34 0.30 1.32 0.81 0.26 0.87 0.38 [ 0.21,0.44] [ 0.21,0.41] [ 0.62,1.60] [ 0.34,1.05] [ 0.20,0.40] [ 0.57,1.06] [ 0.25,1.85] Total |$-$|2.83 |$-$|2.86 |$-$|20.36 |$-$|7.76 |$-$|2.49 |$-$|4.53 |$-$|2.49 [ |$-$|7.45,0.12] [ |$-$|7.49,0.12] [ |$-$|22.83,|$-$|15.01] [ |$-$|15.77,|$-$|2.77] [ |$-$|7.08,0.49] [ |$-$|10.29,|$-$|0.87] [ |$-$|4.48,78.92] Implied value CO|$_{2}$| 265 297 458 296 292 173 212 [ 104,711] [ 114,821] [ 334,546] [ 57,571] [ 102,887] [ 67,362] [ 195,2414] Indirect welfare effects (⁠|$\Delta $| in billion € ’s) Other Ext. 2.19 2.65 14.94 2.00 0.24 3.52 |$-$|0.41 [ |$-$|0.20,6.42] [ 0.16,7.02] [ 5.19,18.13] [ |$-$|0.97,7.39] [ |$-$|2.52,6.60] [ 0.36,10.54] [ |$-$|1.60,76.38] Undervaluation 1.52 1.28 6.75 3.62 1.19 3.89 1.92 [ 1.21,2.02] [ 1.07,1.79] [ 3.89,8.03] [ 2.43,4.16] [ 0.84,1.82] [ 3.14,4.58] [ 1.44,6.87] Total: 0.88 1.07 1.33 |$-$|2.14 |$-$|1.07 2.87 |$-$|0.98 [ 0.57,1.53] [ 0.90,1.84] [ |$-$|5.78,4.71] [ |$-$|6.62,1.41] [ |$-$|2.04,1.34] [ 2.13,4.65] [ |$-$|2.99,163.19] . I . II . III . IV . V . VI . VII . . Opt. . Tech . Mix shift . Flat . Fooled . Enforce . Engin. . Solve for: |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t, (\lambda=0)$| |$p,f, (t=0)$| |$p,t,\lambda$| |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t,\lambda $| |$p,t,\lambda $| Gaming: 70% 70% - 0% 70% 0% 0% Consumer Soph.: Yes Yes Yes Yes No - - Market size Total sales (%) |$-$|1.08 |$-$|1.30 |$-$|7.34 |$-$|0.98 |$-$|0.12 |$-$|1.73 0.20 [ |$-$|3.11,0.19] [|$-$|3.41,0.02] [ |$-$|8.74,|$-$|3.67] [ |$-$|3.46,0.30] [ |$-$|2.95,1.30] [ |$-$|5.00,|$-$|0.04] [ |$-$|33.69,0.74] Emissions (%) |$-$|4.85 |$-$|4.31 |$-$|19.16 |$-$|11.71 |$-$|3.81 |$-$|12.60 |$-$|5.47 [ |$-$|6.53,|$-$|3.63] [ |$-$|5.98,|$-$|3.33] [ |$-$|21.66,|$-$|12.92] [ |$-$|14.70,|$-$|7.19] [ |$-$|5.98,|$-$|2.55] [ |$-$|14.77,|$-$|10.59] [ |$-$|24.48,|$-$|4.43] Direct eelfare effects (⁠|$\Delta $| in billion € ’s) Consumer surplus |$-$|2.57 |$-$|2.51 |$-$|19.10 |$-$|7.62 |$-$|2.62 |$-$|4.45 |$-$|2.68 [ |$-$|6.17,|$-$|0.22] [ |$-$|6.12,|$-$|0.16] [ |$-$|20.74,|$-$|15.44] [ |$-$|13.82,|$-$|3.26] [ |$-$|6.22,|$-$|0.29] [ |$-$|8.90,|$-$|1.63] [ |$-$|104.5,|$-$|2.07] Profits |$-$|0.60 |$-$|0.65 |$-$|2.58 |$-$|0.96 |$-$|0.13 |$-$|0.95 |$-$|0.19 [ |$-$|1.71,0.05] [ |$-$|1.77,0.03] [ |$-$|3.60,|$-$|0.12] [ |$-$|2.45,|$-$|0.23] [ |$-$|1.56,0.59] [ |$-$|2.54,|$-$|0.11] [ |$-$|0.42,183.38] CO|$_2$| value 0.34 0.30 1.32 0.81 0.26 0.87 0.38 [ 0.21,0.44] [ 0.21,0.41] [ 0.62,1.60] [ 0.34,1.05] [ 0.20,0.40] [ 0.57,1.06] [ 0.25,1.85] Total |$-$|2.83 |$-$|2.86 |$-$|20.36 |$-$|7.76 |$-$|2.49 |$-$|4.53 |$-$|2.49 [ |$-$|7.45,0.12] [ |$-$|7.49,0.12] [ |$-$|22.83,|$-$|15.01] [ |$-$|15.77,|$-$|2.77] [ |$-$|7.08,0.49] [ |$-$|10.29,|$-$|0.87] [ |$-$|4.48,78.92] Implied value CO|$_{2}$| 265 297 458 296 292 173 212 [ 104,711] [ 114,821] [ 334,546] [ 57,571] [ 102,887] [ 67,362] [ 195,2414] Indirect welfare effects (⁠|$\Delta $| in billion € ’s) Other Ext. 2.19 2.65 14.94 2.00 0.24 3.52 |$-$|0.41 [ |$-$|0.20,6.42] [ 0.16,7.02] [ 5.19,18.13] [ |$-$|0.97,7.39] [ |$-$|2.52,6.60] [ 0.36,10.54] [ |$-$|1.60,76.38] Undervaluation 1.52 1.28 6.75 3.62 1.19 3.89 1.92 [ 1.21,2.02] [ 1.07,1.79] [ 3.89,8.03] [ 2.43,4.16] [ 0.84,1.82] [ 3.14,4.58] [ 1.44,6.87] Total: 0.88 1.07 1.33 |$-$|2.14 |$-$|1.07 2.87 |$-$|0.98 [ 0.57,1.53] [ 0.90,1.84] [ |$-$|5.78,4.71] [ |$-$|6.62,1.41] [ |$-$|2.04,1.34] [ 2.13,4.65] [ |$-$|2.99,163.19] Table gives the welfare effects of policy simulations with 90% C.I. in brackets. Column I solves for the optimal abatement strategy given the following baseline assumptions: engineering cost function starts at |$\hat{c}'$|⁠, each emission reduction is 30% technology and 70% gaming, and consumers are sophisticated (gaming does not affect choice). Column II only allows for technology and gaming (prices are the solution of (7) with |$\lambda=0$|⁠). Column III only allows for price changes. Column IV introduces a flat standard with a target of 130g of CO|$_{2}$|/km. Column V allows gaming to affect consumer choice. Column VI sets gaming to zero. Column VII implements the engineering cost function without adjusting the intercept. Open in new tab Columns I and II are almost equivalent, showing that firms choose to abate almost entirely by technology adoption and gaming.52 In the baseline estimate of Column I, we see that the emission standard reduces sales by 1% and actual emissions by 4.9%. The standard did not change the share of small vehicles (defined as the compact and subcompact vehicle classes). If firms had responded by mix-shifting (Column III), we would see stark decreases in sales and actual emissions and a stark increase in the market share for small vehicles. The difference between Column II and III illustrates that the abatement strategy chosen by firms is crucial for the market outcomes of the standard. The second panel of Table 5 shows the welfare effects of the regulation. I find that the EU standard decreased both the consumer surplus and profits by € 2.6 billion and € 0.6 billion, respectively. Profit losses originate from firms taking up technology beyond the marginal benefit in the absence of the policy. In turn, this increases the prices for consumers above their willingness to pay for fuel consumption. The |${\rm CO}_{2}$| reduction of 5% is much lower than the policy target because of gaming. The actual emission savings are worth only € 0.3 billion, which is much less than the private losses. Dividing private losses by tons of |${\rm CO}_{2}$|⁠, I find an implied value of the government for a ton of |${\rm CO}_{2}$| of € 265. This number is much higher than the estimated levels of the social cost of carbon. The effect on consumer surplus and profits is even more negative with mix-shifting. Because fuel taxes are already correcting for more than the carbon externality in the EU, the policy overshoots and requires reductions in emissions that are very costly.53 However, the policy has two potential indirect benefits that I report in the final panel of Table 5. First, a decrease in sales reduces other externalities from traffic. Given the assumption of € 0.12 per km, the reduction in traffic increases welfare by € 2.2 billion. This number is substantial, and as explained above, is most likely an upper bound. Second, correcting undervaluation reduces consumer surplus losses significantly by € 1.5 billion. Because consumers undervalue fuel consumption in the RC Logit model with endogenous attributes, the reduced future fuel expenses of the new choices benefit consumers in the future more than they value today. Both these indirect welfare effects need to be added in full to find positive welfare effects.54 6.3. Attribute basing In the baseline result, I find that firms choose to abate almost exclusively by lowering the official emission rates. The reason for this choice is the attribute basing of the standard. Table 5 Column IV gives the welfare effects of compliance to a flat standard. This scenario leads to larger price changes and more actual emission savings. Why does a flat standard result in more mix-shifting? Because of the slope in the target, more low weight products are now above the target, as illustrated for Fiat in Figure 2. The Figure plots all the products in the fleet, scaled by sales, in the emission-vehicle weight space, and shows that many products in the lower left are below the red flat target but above the green sloped target. For all these products, the policy is an implicit subsidy under a flat standard but an implicit tax for the attribute-based standard. The attribute basing makes mix-shifting much more costly because the firm has much fewer products to which it can shift sales. Figure 2 Open in new tabDownload slide Position of the Fiat fleet relative to flat and attribute-based target Figure plots every vehicle sold by Fiat in 2007 as it appears in the base scenario in the counterfactual. Each blue circle is a product and circles scale with sales. The horizontal line (red) is the flat target at 130 grams of CO|$_{2}$| per km an the increasing line (green) is the attribute based target. Figure 2 Open in new tabDownload slide Position of the Fiat fleet relative to flat and attribute-based target Figure plots every vehicle sold by Fiat in 2007 as it appears in the base scenario in the counterfactual. Each blue circle is a product and circles scale with sales. The horizontal line (red) is the flat target at 130 grams of CO|$_{2}$| per km an the increasing line (green) is the attribute based target. Why was the EU emission standard attribute-based? Deters (2010) describes the legislation process in detail. He gives the following quote from French president Nicolas Sarkozy, favouring a flat regulation: “There is no legitimate reason to give the buyer of a heavy vehicle a right to more pollution than any other buyer.” While Romano Prodi, Italian Prime Minister, stated the following: “A steeper value curve would lead to a significant distortion of competition and an illegitimate hardship for the producers of small cars.” Both these statements contrast with Angela Merkel, Chancellor of Germany, who stated the following: “The proposed value curve is already a reduction duty far above average for larger cars.” Germany proposed a steeper target with a slope of |$a=0.06$| instead of |$0.04$| that would require lower compliance effort from German firms. The attribute basing was the result of a political agreement between car producing countries. In Table 6, I compare the effects of attribute-based and flat regulation. I compare the profits, technologies, and shadow costs for different firms averaged per production region, i.e., Asia, France, Germany, Italy, and the U.S. The left panel gives changes of compliance to the ABR when firms choose optimally or when I restrict the firms to mix-shift. The right panel does the same for the flat target. When I restrict firms to mix-shift, the shadow costs of the regulation increases with attribute basing. On average, the shadow cost of the regulation triples from 0.29 to 0.94 when introducing attribute basing. To see this, compare |$\lambda$| and |$\lambda'$| in II and IV. Fiat, the only Italian firm, would have automatically complied with a flat target, while they have the highest shadow cost under the attribute-based standard. Because mix-shifting in response to the ABR is so costly for Fiat (and for Asian firms), it abates emissions mostly by technology and gaming. The implications for market equilibrium are substantial because when some firms start improving emission ratings (and consumers benefit from lower fuel costs), other firms face competitive pressure to follow. This equilibrium behaviour explains why we see a shift from some technology and some mix-shifting in Column III to almost exclusively technology and gaming in Column I. Table 6. Profits and Stringency per Producing State . ABR . Flat . . I . II . III . IV . Solve for: . |$t,\lambda$| . |$\lambda$| . |$t,\lambda'$| . |$\lambda'$| . . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$t$| . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$t$| . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$\lambda$| . Asia |$-$|212 14 0.09 |$-$|1660 1.33 |$-$|380 2 0.33 |$-$|163 0.41 France 23 4 0.04 1527 0.45 382 0 0.04 1296 0.05 Germany |$-$|635 13 0.08 |$-$|1855 0.93 |$-$|1287 8 0.33 |$-$|3196 0.57 Italy |$-$|84 8 0.07 |$-$|682 1.12 28 0 0.00 281 0.00 US |$-$|44 8 0.06 86 0.85 299 3 0.21 578 0.43 . ABR . Flat . . I . II . III . IV . Solve for: . |$t,\lambda$| . |$\lambda$| . |$t,\lambda'$| . |$\lambda'$| . . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$t$| . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$t$| . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$\lambda$| . Asia |$-$|212 14 0.09 |$-$|1660 1.33 |$-$|380 2 0.33 |$-$|163 0.41 France 23 4 0.04 1527 0.45 382 0 0.04 1296 0.05 Germany |$-$|635 13 0.08 |$-$|1855 0.93 |$-$|1287 8 0.33 |$-$|3196 0.57 Italy |$-$|84 8 0.07 |$-$|682 1.12 28 0 0.00 281 0.00 US |$-$|44 8 0.06 86 0.85 299 3 0.21 578 0.43 The table gives the average shadow costs and changes in profits in millions of euros relative to no policy for German, Italian, French, Asian, and US firms from abatement in response to both the attribute-based Regulation and a Flat Regulation. In all solutions, there is no gaming. Solution I solves for equilibrium abatement to the ABR, II allows only for mix-shifting. Solution III solves for equilibrium abatement to the flat standard, IV allows only for mix-shifting. Open in new tab Table 6. Profits and Stringency per Producing State . ABR . Flat . . I . II . III . IV . Solve for: . |$t,\lambda$| . |$\lambda$| . |$t,\lambda'$| . |$\lambda'$| . . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$t$| . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$t$| . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$\lambda$| . Asia |$-$|212 14 0.09 |$-$|1660 1.33 |$-$|380 2 0.33 |$-$|163 0.41 France 23 4 0.04 1527 0.45 382 0 0.04 1296 0.05 Germany |$-$|635 13 0.08 |$-$|1855 0.93 |$-$|1287 8 0.33 |$-$|3196 0.57 Italy |$-$|84 8 0.07 |$-$|682 1.12 28 0 0.00 281 0.00 US |$-$|44 8 0.06 86 0.85 299 3 0.21 578 0.43 . ABR . Flat . . I . II . III . IV . Solve for: . |$t,\lambda$| . |$\lambda$| . |$t,\lambda'$| . |$\lambda'$| . . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$t$| . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$t$| . |$\lambda$| . |$\Delta$| Prof. . |$\lambda$| . Asia |$-$|212 14 0.09 |$-$|1660 1.33 |$-$|380 2 0.33 |$-$|163 0.41 France 23 4 0.04 1527 0.45 382 0 0.04 1296 0.05 Germany |$-$|635 13 0.08 |$-$|1855 0.93 |$-$|1287 8 0.33 |$-$|3196 0.57 Italy |$-$|84 8 0.07 |$-$|682 1.12 28 0 0.00 281 0.00 US |$-$|44 8 0.06 86 0.85 299 3 0.21 578 0.43 The table gives the average shadow costs and changes in profits in millions of euros relative to no policy for German, Italian, French, Asian, and US firms from abatement in response to both the attribute-based Regulation and a Flat Regulation. In all solutions, there is no gaming. Solution I solves for equilibrium abatement to the ABR, II allows only for mix-shifting. Solution III solves for equilibrium abatement to the flat standard, IV allows only for mix-shifting. Open in new tab The changes in profits in Table 6 show that French and Italian firms benefit from a flat standard, while all the compliance costs fall on German firms. This result is in line with positions the countries took when bargaining over regulation. The policy debate in 2007 focused mainly on these distributional issues and not on the effect of the slope on the likelihood of different abatement strategies and clearly shows the importance of the political economy of the regulation. The ABR was agreed such that all firms would have similar distances from the target and would face similar compliance efforts. However, this design made mix-shifting more expensive so that the industry needed to reduce the official emission numbers to be able to comply with the regulation. 6.4. Enforcement Interestingly, it is again national interests that led to the weak enforcement of emission testing and ultimately led to gaming. In a recent report, the European Parliament (Gieseke and Gerbandy (2017)) blamed both the European Commission and the member states for allowing firms to game emission tests. Member states contravened their legal obligation to monitor and enforce defeat devices. France, Germany, and Italy had evidence that emission control systems did not focus on actual emissions. The report states that these countries did not take steps to understand the performance gap between official and actual emission, indicating maladministration. The report also blames member states for under-funding testing facilities (in practice, carmakers funded the testing facilities themselves). Even after the Volkswagen scandal in the US, most member states did not start immediate and consistent investigations, nor did they adopt a dissuasive penalty system. Additionally, the European Commission failed to oversee the enforcement of member states. In summary, the car-producing countries were aware of the gaming but failed to enforce the regulation. The overseeing European Commission, in its turn, failed to follow up on the signals that downstream enforcement was failing. Columns I, V, and VI of Table 5 shed light on the economic consequences of weak enforcement. The difference between Columns I and V is the consumer’s awareness of gaming. In Column I, the gaming does not affect consumer choice, while it does in Column V. When gaming fools consumers, they perceive cars to have lower fuel consumption, and discover this to be wrong while driving. This choice distortion to consumers causes a further reduction in consumer surplus. Additionally, the firms increase prices because products are perceived to be of higher quality. The situation is worse for the environment as the standard causes almost no reductions in sales and actual emissions. Overall, the regulation now has a negative welfare effect, even when accounting for the indirect effects. Column VI shows the welfare effects under a standard with full enforcement. Enforcement increases private losses in consumer surplus and profits but leads to much higher |${\rm CO}_{2}$| and other externality savings. Column VI is the simulation that shows the highest welfare numbers when including the indirect welfare effects, but the EU failed to attain this. Finally, if abatement was 100% gaming, there would be no changes in the static equilibrium with sophisticated consumers. Carmakers would report different official emissions to the regulator, but prices and fuel costs would remain the same. The evidence presented here shows that the design of the regulation is responsible for the observed outcome. First, the political bargaining between France, Germany, and Italy led to an attribute-based standard with a steep slope. The attribute basing increased the cost of mix-shifting as an abatement strategy and increased the likelihood of compliance by gaming and technology adoption. Next, enforcement failures on the level of the member states enabled firms to resort to gaming. 6.5. Cost function and investment inefficiencies In the main simulation, the costs for technology adoption start at the point where the marginal benefits of emission reductions equal marginal costs. The engineering reports, however, present a cost function that starts with a lower slope than the estimated point concurring with the economic model. If the engineers are correct, this means that firms leave money on the table, i.e., they do not choose to adopt available cost-actual technology for which consumers have a willingness to pay.55 Additionally, Jaffe et al. (2005) point to market failures in the supply and adoption of technology such as spillovers in technology, spillovers in adoption, and incomplete information about future returns of the investment. The result of these market failures could be a socially sub-optimal equilibrium with no or too little investment and technology adoption. The regulation gives clear and binding efficiency targets for the whole industry. It might have succeeded in moving the industry out of a sub-optimal equilibrium by inducing technology adoption. The framework here allows to compute welfare effects of the emission standard when the supply-side undervalues technology.56 By comparing Column VI and VII in Table 5, I find that supply-side failures in technology adoption are not necessarily bad for welfare when externalities are at play. Because of the inexpensive technology, the regulation makes firms reduce fuel consumption for less than the consumers’ willingness to pay. Vehicles become cheaper, as consumers receive better characteristics for a price below their willingness to pay. As such, the market size increases rather than decreases. The regulation now has a rebound effect on the extensive margin.57 The inexpensive technology reduces consumer and profit losses but also wipes out the savings in other externalities so that, surprisingly, more technology adoption is not necessarily better for welfare. The regulation pushes firms beyond what could be explained by market failures, a policy that only requires cost-efficient technology has a less stringet target than existing policy. In general, I believe this scenario is not very credible. In line with Anderson and Sallee (2011), I expect carmakers to abate emissions with the least costly compliance strategies. If technology is so cheap and would have cost only € 190 million in variable profits, then why would firms have resorted to gaming? In Supplementary Appendix Table A7 Column II, I show the results with the estimated cost function specified in (12). The results are similar to the main scenario, but the estimated cost function is less convex than the engineering cost function and results in lower consumer and profit losses. 6.6. Sunk costs The profit changes reported in Table 5 are changes in variable profits. Both technology adoption and gaming potentially have sunk costs. I explain the underlying sources of sunk costs, and then I compute an upper bound on these costs by computing deviations in variable profits from optimal strategies. The fixed costs of technology adoption contain the development of technology, implementation of technology, and the redesign of the vehicle. Engineers stated that the technology to attain emission reductions was available at the time of the policy. The policy allowed for 8 years between announcement and enforcement. Vehicles typically go through faster redesign cycles, see Blonigen et al. (2017). The additional sunk costs of redesigning are thus likely to be small. Because of the availability of technology and no additional redesign cycles, I expect little additional sunk costs of technology except for the adoption itself. Gaming has expected sunk costs. The defeat devices used to game the emission tests have to be purchased or designed. Firms also face the risk of liability for non-compliance and class actions from consumers and shareholders. A complicating factor is that firms use similar defeat devices to avoid pollution standards so that the legal cases are both about misrepresenting pollutants and fuel economy. It is unclear if I should attribute all of these costs to the emission standard. Given the estimated static model, I can compute an implied upper bound of sunk costs from the changes in variable profits when firms deviate from the optimal strategy.58Supplementary Appendix A6 discusses the computation of the bounds. I find that the sum of the upper bounds for all firms equals € 70 billion. The findings show that firms are willing to sink high amounts to comply with gaming and technology adoption. It also means that the modest positive welfare numbers presented in Table 5 are not sufficient to claim that the regulation had any positive effect. Carmakers are currently defendants in multiple legal cases, the efforts and costs related to these cases are an additional welfare loss so that the regulation has at best zero effect on welfare. 7. Conclusion This article evaluates the response to the 2015 EU-wide emission standard. I find that between 2007 and 2011, official sales-weighted emissions from new sales decreased by 14%. A decomposition shows that two-thirds of the decrease in emissions is attributable to firms gaming emission tests. One-third of the decrease stems from actual technology adoption. The projected carbon savings did not materialize because of non-compliance. The reasons that firms chose gaming and technology adoption are attribute basing and a lack of enforcement. Both reasons are a product of the EU political environment. A structural model of demand and supply, allowing for endogenous abatement choices, reveals that the overall effect of the regulation has been negative for consumers and producers. For the regulation to be welfare-improving, non-targeted externalities, such as accidents and local pollution, and corrections in undervaluation need to be counted. This exercise provides important lessons for studying emission standards. First, the abatement strategy that firms use matters for policy outcomes. Policy design has large impacts on which strategies firms employ. I show that attribute basing made mix-shifting so costly that some firms had to decrease the emission ratings. Second, politics matter for the design, implementation, and enforcement of standards. Third, technology adoption is a crucial mechanism of compliance and needs consideration when evaluating emission standards. This is difficult because the evaluation depends on assumptions about the cost curve of technology adoption. The economic model in this article estimates technology adoption costs to be higher than projections of engineers, even after accounting for consumers’ undervaluation of fuel consumption reductions. It is crucial to further our understanding of why firms might face high costs when adopting greener technologies. Overall, I want to stress that emission standards are a risky and unpredictable policy instrument when the goal is to reduce carbon emissions. Standards rely on emission tests that are gameable when compliance costs become very high. It is uncertain that emissions reduce because of the policy. If the engineers are correct and cost-actual technology is available, then standards might increase the size of the market rather than decrease it, causing an increase in emissions. The EU could introduce the transport sector into the emission trading system so that the vehicle market contributes to the prices of carbon permits and abatement costs equalize across sectors. Since all EU countries have very high fuel taxes that cover more than the carbon externality, it is difficult to understand why the EU chose for emission standards. The EU has limited fiscal authority to raise taxes. The EU parliament recently approved more stringent emission standards for 2021 to 2030. These standards are so stringent that combustion engines are not capable of reaching the target, which implies an imposed shift to alternative fuels. The numbers derived in this article are obtained under various assumptions and limitations. First, I focus only on the sales of new vehicles and assume no effects on prices and vehicle lifetimes in the used car market. It would be interesting to study different effects of gaming, technology adoption, and pricing on this market. Second, all welfare numbers ignore possible rebound effects on driving behaviour. Third, I did not include dynamics in the analysis. Fixed costs from the standard on the firm side might have effects on the market structure, and rapid technology adoption might result in consumers strategically timing purchases. Even without these complications, the results presented here show that the welfare effects from emission standards are far from obvious and that the design of the regulation matters for which abatement strategies firms choose. The editor in charge of this paper was Aureo de Paula. Acknowledgments I am grateful to Frank Verboven, James Sallee, Bruno de Borger, Johannes Van Biesebroeck and Jan Bouckaert for their support and guidance. Reynaert acknowledges funding from ANR under grant ANR-17-EURE-0010 (Investissements d’Avenir program). Supplementary Data Supplementary data are available at Review of Economic Studies online. And the replication packages are available at https://dx.doi.org/10.52xx/zenodo.4013683. Footnotes 1. CO|$_{2}$| cannot be filtered during the combustion process. Fuel consumption translates proportionally into grams of CO|$_{2}$| per km, with a different CO|$_{2}$| content per litre for diesel and gasoline. Fuel consumption (litres per kilometre) and CO|$_{2}$| emissions per kilometre are the inverse of fuel economy (miles per gallon). 2. The International Council on Clean Transportation (2014) compares the different regulations between countries. The EU has the goal of decreasing emissions to 95 g/km by 2021, the U.S. has communicated a goal of 103 g/km by 2025, Japan has a goal 105 g/km by 2020, and China has a goal of 117 g/km by 2020. The U.S. and Japan have also introduced attribute basing in their regulations. 3. See for example, the French bonus malus discussed in Durrmeyer (2018) and the Swedish rebate discussed in Huse and Lucinda (2014). 4. Another option would have been to model technology adoption as a discrete choice for firms in a two-stage model, as in Eizenberg (2014) or Wollmann (2018). However, this approach is computationally less suited for a market with hundreds of products and a continuous characteristic, such as improvements in fuel consumption. 5. See “EU unveils tough emissions curbs for cars”—Financial Times, February 7, 2007, and “France battles Germany over car emissions”—Financial Times, 15 November 2007. 6. Other notable differences are the demand model where I estimate price elasticities on the engine level (more than 400 products per market) rather than the broad category level (including 12 products), and I allow for endogenous characteristics. The model of Jacobsen (2013) is richer in other dimensions as it incorporates effects on the second-hand market as well as changes in the vehicle miles travelled as modelled in Bento et al. (2009) 7. These margins play a role in the current policy debate in the U.S. as discussed in Bento et al. (2018). 8. Manufacturers can obtain lower average emissions by gathering super credits. These credits are given for vehicles that emit less than 50 g/km. Small manufacturers making less than 30,000 vehicles per year face separate standards. I ignore both of the exceptions as they count for a tiny share of the total market. 9. The average SUV in the data weighs 1650 kg, and the average compact car weighs 1,250 kg. The SUV’s emissions are scaled down while the compact car’s emissions are scaled up. 10. The car industry represents 6.1% of EU employment and 11.4% of manufacturing employment, see https://www.acea.be/statistics/tag/category/employment-trends, read on 4 March 2020. 11. Contrary to the CAFE standards in the U.S., the EU standard has no banking system for excess emissions. The penalties in the EU are lower for low excess emissions but increase to higher levels than the penalties for breaking the US CAFE standards. 12. The technologies are reduced friction, direct injection, variable valve timing and actuation, more efficient transmissions, engine start-stop, improved aerodynamics, low rolling resistance tires, and improvements in ancillary systems and auxiliaries can be used to reduce emissions. The document also considers engine downsizing, weight savings, and hybridization, which I do not consider to be technology adoption as they involve downsizing the vehicle. Knittel (2011) also gives several examples of specific technologies implemented in the U.S. The International Energy Agency reported a possible 40% improvement in fuel efficiency from available technologies in 2005. See http://www.iea.org/publications/freepublications/publication/technology-roadmap-fuel-economy-of-road-vehicles.html. 13. The NEDC is also used to determine compliance with the Euronorms that regulate local pollutants such as |${\rm NO}_{x}$|⁠, CO, and PM. The Volkswagen scandal was about |${\rm NO}_x$| emissions in diesel vehicles. The fallout of the scandal made clear that the majority of EU carmakers are not in compliance with Euronorms. 14. These markets represent approximately 90% of the total EU market. 15. The body types are as follows: hatchback, sedan, wagon, coupe, convertible, mini MPV, and SUV. 16. The combustion process and different energy content of the fuel make diesel engines more efficient per kilometre. Diesel cars emit less CO|$_{2}$| per kilometre, but increases emissions of other pollutants such as |$N_{OX}$|⁠. 17. Reynaert and Sallee (2020) construct on-road emissions from a panel of 12,000 drivers visiting a fuel station 22 million times. Odometer readings and fuel purchases are used to construct fuel consumption on the road. 18. I combine the fleet of the Asian carmakers because most of these firms do not have a broad product set. This makes finding a price equilibrium with solely price changes impossible in my algorithms. Alternatively, I could choose to only keep Toyota and Nissan, by far the largest Asian firms in the EU, but combining all Asian firms allows me to include more products. Note that the emission standard is sales-based; it does not matter where the vehicle is produced. This means that imports sold in the EU are counted, and exports are ignored. 19. This shows that the emission standard is probably not the only mechanism driving down the sales-weighted emissions. Below I comment on complementary explanations. 20. Knittel (2011) assumes that the marginal cost is additively separable in elements related to emissions and other cost elements not related to emissions. Then this estimation can be interpreted as an estimate of the level set or iso-marginal cost relation between emissions and its determinants. 21. The main specification has a constant |$\eta$|⁠, but I also show robustness when |$\eta$| changes over time. I estimate 2 using a wide range of robustness checks, which are specified below and reported in Supplementary Appendix Table A3. 22. Appendix Table A4 reports firm-specific trends with similar patterns except for BMW and Renault. All firms change the trend of technology adoption, but the magnitude of the change differs. BMW and Renault have the lowest difference in technology growth (0.9% and 0.8%), while Volkswagen has the highest difference (5.4%). 23. Appendix Table A3 presents further robustness checks with official emission decreases estimated to be between 2.1% and 3.3% more rapid after the policy announcement. 24. I use the market level estimate of gaming rather than the firm level in the structural model for two reasons. First, the firm-level estimates are not statistically precise, and introducing firm heterogeneity in gaming creates substantial differences in welfare outcomes between firms. The second reason is that Reynaert and Sallee (2020), based on a extended period of data until 2015, find that all firms game in large and similar amounts. 25. I re-scale each of the predicted emissions with the attribute-based target function, such that the numbers are actual distances from the regulation. Not re-scaling gives similar results. 26. An example of a newly released model is the “Citroen DS3 Hatchback,” released in 2009. 27. Examples are the bonus/malus system in France and low emission zones in Germany as well as various scrapping schemes. 28. The abatement strategies discussed do not need to occur mutually exclusively. Firms choose their abatement strategies such that the marginal abatement costs of each strategy are equal. When firms abate by choosing only one strategy, the marginal cost of that strategy must be lower than that of the other strategies. 29. The geographical market corresponds to a country in the empirical analysis because I observe prices and quantities at the country level. 30. The total expected fuel costs can be written as |$E[\sum^{S}_{s=1}(1+r)^{-s}m_i d_s e_j k_j]$| where s=1 is the time of purchase, S is the time of scrappage, r is the interest rate and m is mileage. Using the random walk assumption for g, we can write expected fuel costs as |$\rho m_i d_1 e_j k_j$|⁠, with |$\rho$| being the capitalization coefficient. See Grigolon et al. (2018) for a detailed discussion. In the utility specification in (3) |$\beta _{i}^{e}$| absorbs |$\rho m_i$|⁠. 31. The specification does not allow consumers to care about emissions (a “green glow” effect) separately. These preferences might be captured by the standard deviation in tastes for fuel costs as green consumers value fuel costs more than others. 32. In Reynaert and Sallee (2020), we show that the gap between the official and on-road ratings was constant up until 2007. We expect a gap between lab and on-road ratings because driving circumstances differ. 33. I specify the attribute basing as a simple additive penalty or reduction, but one could design a regulation where the target is any function |$g(e_{jm},w_{jm})$| of emissions and the attribute. 34. In reality, firms choose to incrementally adopt technology and gaming over several years between the policy announcement and enforcement. In ignoring this process, I miss how firms could make strategic abatement choices that take into account the path dependency of their choices. 35. This creates distortions, which might be significant if weight is associated with other external costs. See the analysis by Anderson and Auffhammer (2014) relating weight to accident risk. 36. This specification allows wealthier markets to be less price elastic. When prices are small relative to the household budget over the lifetime of the durable good, this approximates an indirect utility function with |$log(y-p_j)$| as an argument as in Berry et al. (1995). See Griffith et al. (2018) for a discussion on how the functional form of the indirect utility in price and income matters for distributional effects of price changes. 37. I introduce random coefficients on 3 variables that capture important margins on which I expect consumer heterogeneity to matter. Height, weight, and footprint do not have a random coefficient because the identification of multiple random coefficients proved impossible with multiple endogenous characteristics. The remaining variables try to control for market or time level shifts and seem less fit to be candidates to model individual heterogeneity. 38. More specifically: (i) I use a nested-fixed point algorithm, BLP’s contraction mapping with a tight convergence criterion (1e|$-$|12) to solve for |$\xi _{jm}$|⁠. I compute the contraction mapping in parallel per market, (ii) I re-estimate the model with 25 different starting values for the nonlinear parameters, (iii) I check first and second-order conditions at the obtained minimum, (iv) I use the Interior/Direct algorithm of Knitro, (v) I compute the integral over individual market shares using sparse grids, see Heiss and Winschel (2008), (vi) I estimate the variances of the random coefficients rather than the standard deviations, see Ketz (2019). 39. Klier and Linn (2012) include all the characteristics of different class vehicles on the same platform. Their exclusion restriction related to characteristics is specific to vehicle classes. I allow the exclusion restriction to be more general and include only the footprint and height in the computation of this instrument. 40. The initial point for nonlinear parameters in the first stage approximate optimal instrument is the Logit taste parameter divided by 10. I compute the approximated optimal IV at |$\xi=0$| and use projections of the endogenous variables on the included and excluded instruments in the computation, see Reynaert and Verboven (2014). 41. The counterfactual results also consider a case where we start from another intercept below the estimated one. Market failures in technology adoption are a reason for the actual slope to be smaller than the estimated |$c'_{t=0}$|⁠. 42. The cost shifter is an included variable in (12) and not an excluded instrument when estimating the supply. See Supplementary Appendix A3 for an overview of the instruments. 43. The regression of the predicted marginal costs on fuel costs results in a positive sign when I change time and market controls, so that fuel economy lowers the marginal costs. These issues could be due to multicollinearity as well as changes in markups that are correlated with fuel costs but not captured in the first-order condition, see Langer and Miller (2013). 44. The different models estimated in Section 3 show a |$0.7%$| to |$1%$| annual decrease in emissions in the pre-policy period. To adjust for the fact that the vehicle fleet would have improved without the policy, I endow the 2007 fleet with a |$6%$| reduction in emissions. This |$6%$| equals 8 years (between 2007 and 2015) of |$0.7%$| technology growth. The hypothetical fleet is the baseline for the welfare computations. 45. In equilibrium, this is not a constraint on the solution as all firms prefer compliance over paying fines in the main scenario. In a scenario where I restrict firms to mix-shifting, the fines matter. I discuss this in Supplementary Appendix A4. 46. Avoided fuel taxes are a transfer from the government to consumers of which the welfare change depends on the marginal cost of public funds. I count reduced fuel expenses as a welfare gain. 47. Yearly mileage and vehicle lifetime match statistics reported by Eurostat. 48. This number comes from the Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Greenhouse Gases (2016). 49. This number is probably an upper bound for the EU since taxes on fuel and driving are, on average, higher than in the U.S. 50. Additionally, recent work in the U.S. has found limited to no undervaluation for fuel costs. See Busse et al. (2013), Allcott and Wozny (2014), and Sallee et al. (2016) 51. The table presents the simulation outcomes at the estimated parameters and a 90% confidence interval. The C.I. is computed by taking 50 draws from the estimated parameter variance–covariance matrix (assuming a joint normal distribution). For each draw of parameters, the supply side is re-estimated and new simulation outcomes computed. I compute the bootstrap from the differences between these 50 outcomes and the outcome at the mean parameters. 52. The percentage improvements in technology in both scenarios are almost equal with differences of 0.1% points while the shadow costs are very close to zero. On the margin, a minimal amount of mix-shifting will always be efficient. 53. See Parry et al. (2014) for a comparison between EU fuel taxes and externalities. In Supplementary Appendix Table A7, I show that a tax on carbon emissions of vehicles, chosen so that it reduces emissions with the same amount as the standard, would also cost € 344 per ton of |${\rm CO}_{2}$|⁠. However, the tax would increase overall welfare by € 5 billion because of savings in other externalities. The costs per ton of carbon across scenarios are among the highest of alternative policies studied in the U.S., see Gillingham and Stock (2018). 54. Supplementary Appendix Table A7 shows the simulation results with the estimates of the RC Logit with only price endogeneity. The results imply a higher consumer valuation for fuel costs so that the simulation starts from a steeper point on the convex cost curve. Decreases in sales, emissions, consumer surplus, profits, and other externalities are much larger because the compliance costs are higher. The estimated overvaluation causes an additional loss for consumers. 55. Notice that the main results already account for the welfare effects of potential undervaluation by consumers; here, I consider the suboptimal technology adoption of firms. 56. Recent work, such as Hashmi and Van Biesebroeck (2016) and Aghion et al. (2016), has looked at R&D patterns in the automobile industry through patents. 57. See Gillingham, Kotchen, Rapson, and Wagner (2013) for an overview of the possible sources of rebound effects. A second rebound effect is an increase in vehicle usage, a rebound effect on the intensive margin. A further rebound effect could come from the use of savings on vehicle expenses on other energy-intensive activities. Lastly, a decrease in the demand for fuels might lower the price of oil, causing a macro-economic rebound effect. Here, I only focus on the rebound effect on the extensive margin. The reported emission savings are an upper bound on the total savings. 58. In this setting, I can compute deviations from the single equilibrium with optimal compliance strategies. From observing multiple compliance choices in multiple markets, I could use a moment inequality estimator to estimate the sunk costs, see Pakes et al. (2015). Here, I can only compute a single deviation profit for each firm implied by the simultaneous game. References AGHION, P. , DECHEZLEPRETRE, A., HEMOUS, D., et al. ( 2016 ), “ Carbon Taxes, Path Dependency, and Directed Technical Change: Evidence from the Auto Industry ” Journal of Political Economy, 124 , 1 – 51 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat ALLCOTT, H. ( 2016 ), “ Paternalism and Energy Efficiency: An Overview ” Annual Review of Economics, 8 , 145 – 176 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat ALLCOTT, H. and WOZNY, N. ( 2014 ), “ Gasoline Prices, Fuel Economy, and the Energy Paradox ” Review of Economics and Statistics, 96 , 779 – 795 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat ANDERSON, M. and AUFFHAMMER, M. ( 2014 ), “ Pounds that Kill: The External Costs of Vehicle Weight ” Review of Economic Studies, 81 , 535 – 571 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat ANDERSON, S. T. , KELLOGG, R. and SALLEE, J. M. ( 2013 ), “ What Do Consumers Believe About Future Gasoline Prices? ” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 66 , 383 – 403 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat ANDERSON, S. T. and SALLEE, J. M. ( 2011 ), “ Using Loopholes to Reveal the Marginal Cost of Regulation: The Case of Fuel-Economy Standards ” American Economic Review, 101 , 1375 – 1409 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat ANDERSON, S. T. and SALLEE, J. M. ( 2016 ), “ Designing Policies to Make Cars Greener: A Review of the Literature ” Annual Review of Resource Economics, 8 , 157 – 180 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat AUSTIN, D. and DINAN, T. ( 2005 ), “ Clearing the Air: The Costs and Consequences of Higher CAFE Standards and Increased Gasoline Taxes ” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 50 , 562 – 582 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat BENTO, A. , GILLINGHAM, K. and ROTH, K. ( 2017 ), “ The Effect of Fuel Economy Standards on Vehicle Weight Dispersion and Accident Fatalities ” ( Working Paper 23340, National Bureau of Economic Research ). OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat BENTO, A. M. , GILLINGHAM, K., JACOBSEN, M. R., et al. ( 2018 ), “ Flawed Analyses of U.S. Auto Fuel Economy Standards ” Science, 362 , 1119 – 1121 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat BENTO, A. M. , GOULDER, L. H., JACOBSEN, M. R., et al. ( 2009 ), “ Distributional and Efficiency Impacts of Increased US Gasoline Taxes ” American Economic Review, 99 , 667 – 699 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat BERRY, S. T. , LEVINSOHN, J. and PAKES, A. ( 1995 ), “ Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium ” Econometrica, 63 , 841 – 890 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat BERRY, S. T. , LEVINSOHN, J. and PAKES, A. ( 1999 ), “ Voluntary Export Restraints on Automobiles: Evaluating a Trade Policy ” American Economic Review, 89 , 400 – 430 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat BLONIGEN, B. A. , KNITTEL, C. R. and SODERBERY, A. 2017 . “ Keeping it Fresh: Strategic Product Redesigns and Welfare ” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 53 , 170 – 214 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat BUSSE, M. R. , KNITTEL, C. R. and ZETTELMEYER, F. 2013 . “ Are Consumers Myopic? Evidence from New and Used Car Purchases ” American Economic Review, 103 , 220 – 256 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat CRAWFORD, G. S. , SHCHERBAKOV, O. and SHUM, M. ( 2019 ), “ Quality Overprovision in Cable Television Markets ” American Economic Review, 109 , 956 – 995 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat DATASTREAM INTERNATIONAL ( 2012 ), “ Available: Datastream International ” URL https://eikon.thomsonreuters.com/index.html. OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat DETERS, H. ( 2010 ), “ Legislating on Car Emissions. What Drives Standards in EU Environmental Policy ” ( Technical Report ). OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat DURRMEYER, I. ( 2018 ), “ Winners and Losers: The Distributional Effects of the French Feebate on the Automobile Market ” ( TSE Working Papers 18-950, Toulouse School of Economics (TSE) ). OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat DURRMEYER, I. and SAMANO, M. ( 2018 ), “ To Rebate or Not to Rebate: Fuel Economy Standards Versus Feebates ” The Economic Journal, 128 , 3076 – 3116 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat EIZENBERG, A. ( 2014 ) “ Upstream Innovation and Product Variety in the U.S. Home PC Market ” The Review of Economic Studies, 813 , 1003 – 1045 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat EUROSTAT ( 2012 ), “ Average Number of Persons per Household by Household Composition, Number of Children and Working Status within Households ” URL https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/products-datasets/product?code=lfst_hhanwhtc. OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat FAN, Y. ( 2013 ), “ Ownership Consolidation and Product Characteristics: A Study of the US Daily Newspaper Market ” American Economic Review, 103 , 1598 – 1628 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat GIESEKE, J. and GERBANDY, G.-J. ( 2017 ), “ Report on the Inquiry into Emission Measurements in the Automotive Sector ” ( Technical Report 2016/2215(INI), European Parliament ). OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat GILLINGHAM, K. , KOTCHEN, M., RAPSON, D. ( 2013 ), “ The Rebound Effect is Over-played ” Nature, 493 , 475 – 476 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat GILLINGHAM, K. and STOCK, J. H. ( 2018 ), “ The Cost of Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions ” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32 , 53 – 72 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat GOLDBERG, P. K. ( 1998 ), “ The Effects of the Corporate Average Fuel Efficiency Standards in the US ” Journal of Industrial Economics, 46 , 1 – 33 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat GRIFFITH, R. , NESHEIM, L. and O’CONNELL, M. ( 2018 ), “ Income effects and the welfare consequences of tax in differentiated product oligopoly ” Quantitative Economics, 9 , 305 – 341 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat GRIGOLON, L. , REYNAERT, M. and VERBOVEN, F. ( 2018 ), “ Consumer Valuation of Fuel Costs and Tax Policy: Evidence from the European Car Market ” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 10 , 193 – 225 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat HASHMI, A. and VAN BIESEBROECK, J. ( 2016 ), “ The Relationship between Market Structure and Innovation in Industry Equilibrium: A Case Study of the Global Automobile Industry ” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 98 , 192 – 208 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat HEISS, F. and WINSCHEL, V. ( 2008 ), “ Likelihood Approximation by Numerical Integration on Sparse Grids ” Journal of Econometrics, 144 , 62 – 80. Google Scholar OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat HOLLAND, S. P. , HUGHES, J. E. and KNITTEL, C. R. ( 2009 ), “ Greenhouse Gas Reductions under Low Carbon Fuel Standards? ” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1 , 106 – 46 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat HUSE, C. and LUCINDA, C. ( 2014 ), “ The Market Impact and the Cost of Environmental Policy: Evidence from the Swedish Green Car Rebate ” The Economic Journal, 124 , F393 – F419 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat INTERAGENCY WORKING GROUP ON SOCIAL COST OF GREENHOUSE GASES (IWG). ( 2016 ), “ Technical Support Document: Technical Update of the Social Cost of Carbon for Regulatory Impact Analysis Under Executive Order 12866 ” ( Technical Report, United States Government ). OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat ITO, K. and SALLEE, J. M. ( 2018 ), “ The Economics of Attribute-Based Regulation: Theory and Evidence from Fuel Economy Standards ” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 100 , 319 – 336 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat JACOBSEN, M. R. ( 2013 ), “ Evaluating US Fuel Economy Standards in a Model with Producer and Household Heterogeneity ” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 5 , 148 – 87 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat JACOBSEN, M. R. and VAN BENTHEM, A. ( 2015 ), “ Vehicle Scrappage and Gasoline Policy ” American Economic Review, 105 , 1312 – 1338 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat JAFFE, A. B. , NEWELL, R. G. and STAVINS, R. N. ( 2005 ), “ A Tale of Two Market Failures: Technology and Environmental Policy ” Ecological Economics, 54 , 164 – 174 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat JATO ANALYTICS. ( 2012 ), “ Data on Vehicle Sales, Prices and Characteristics for EU Countries 1998-2011 ” (https://www.jato.com). OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat KETZ, P. ( 2019 ), “ On Asymptotic Size Distortions in the Random Coefficients Logit Model ” Journal of Econometrics , 212 , 413 – 432 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat KLIER, T. and LINN, J. ( 2012 ), “ New-Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard ” The RAND Journal of Economics, 43 , 186 – 213 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat KLIER, T. and LINN, J.. ( 2016 ), “ The Effect of Vehicle Fuel Economy Standards on Technology Adoption ” Journal of Public Economics, 133 , 41 – 63 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat KNITTEL, C. R. ( 2011 ), “ Automobiles on Steroids: Product Attribute Trade-Offs and Technological Progress in the Automobile Sector ” American Economic Review, 101 , 3368 – 3399 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat LANGER, A. and MILLER, N. ( 2013 ), “ Automakers’ Short-Run Responses to Changing Gasoline Prices ” Review of Economics and Statistics, 95 , 1198 – 1211 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat NEVO, A. ( 2001 ), “ Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry ” Econometrica, 69 , 307 – 342 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat PAKES, A. , PORTER, J., HO, K., et al. ( 2015 ). “ Moment Inequalities and Their Application ” Econometrica, 83 , 315 – 334 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat PARRY, I. W. H. , WALLS, M. and HARRINGTON, W. ( 2007 ). “ Automobile Externalities and Policies ” Journal of Economic Literature, 45 , 373 – 399 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat PARRY, I. W. H. , HEINE, D., LIS, E., et al. ( 2014 ), “ Getting Energy Prices Right: From Principle to Practice ” ( International Monetary Fund ). OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat PWC AUTOFACTS. ( 2012 ), “ Data on Global Production Sites, Quantities and Capacities ”. OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat REGULATION (EC) NO. 443/2009. ( 2009 ), “ Setting Emission Performance Standards for New Passenger Cars as Part of the Community’s Integrated Approach to Reduce CO|$_2$| Emissions from Light-Duty Vehicles ” Official Journal of the European Union, L 140/1 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat REYNAERT, M. and SALLEE, J. M. ( 2020 ), “ Who Benefits When Firms Game Corrective Policies? ” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy , forthcoming. Google Scholar OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat REYNAERT, M. and VERBOVEN, F. ( 2014 ), “ Improving the Performance of Random Coefficients Demand Models: The Role of Optimal Instruments ” Journal of Econometrics, 179 , 83 – 98 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat SALLEE, J. M. , WEST, S. E. and FAN, W. ( 2016 ), “ Do Consumers Recognize the Value of Fuel Economy? Evidence from Used Car Prices and Gasoline Price Fluctuations ” Journal of Public Economics, 135 , 61 – 73 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat SMALL, K. A. and ROSEN, H. S. ( 1981 ), “ Applied Welfare Economics with Discrete Choice Models ” Econometrica, 49 , 105 – 130 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat TNO. ( 2011 ), “ Support for the Revision of Regulation (EC) No 443/2009 on CO|$_2$| Emissions from Cars ” URL https://ec.europa.eu/clima/sites/clima/files/transport/vehicles/cars/docs/study_car_2011_en.pdf. Framework Contract No ENV.C.3./FRA/2009/0043 . OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat TRAVELCARDNV. ( 2015 ), “ Data on Fuel Station Visits Travelcard Holders 2004-2015 ” (https://travelcard.nl). OpenURL Placeholder Text WorldCat WHITEFOOT, K. S. and SKERLOS, S. J. ( 2012 ), “ Design Incentives to Increase Vehicle Size Created from the U.S. Footprint-based Fuel Economy Standards ” Energy Policy, 41 , 402 – 411 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat WHITEFOOT, K. S. , FOWLIE, M. L. and SKERLOS, S. J. ( 2017 ), “ Compliance by Design: Influence of Acceleration Trade-offs on CO|$_2$| Emissions and Costs of Fuel Economy and Greenhouse Gas Regulations ” Environmental Science & Technology, 51 , 10307 – 10315 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat WOLLMANN, THOMAS G. 2018 . “ Trucks without Bailouts: Equilibrium Product Characteristics for Commercial Vehicles ” American Economic Review, 108 , 1364 – 1406 . Google Scholar Crossref Search ADS WorldCat © The Author(s) 2020. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Review of Economic Studies Limited. This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic.oup.com/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model) TI - Abatement Strategies and the Cost of Environmental Regulation: Emission Standards on the European Car Market JO - The Review of Economic Studies DO - 10.1093/restud/rdaa058 DA - 0007-04-12 UR - https://www.deepdyve.com/lp/oxford-university-press/abatement-strategies-and-the-cost-of-environmental-regulation-emission-Pn8KV4zFb8 SP - 1 EP - 1 VL - Advance Article IS - DP - DeepDyve ER -